Advertisement

Socioeconomics and the New “Battle of Methods”: Toward a Paradigm Shift?

Originally published in Journal of Behavioral Economics 19 (2), 1990
  • Richard Swedberg
Chapter

Abstract

Swedberg traces the history of conflict between “economic man” analysis (largely neoclassical economics) and cultural analysis (largely in sociology) in the social sciences. He focuses particularly on two relatively recent developments: 1) the growing introduction of “economic man” analysis into other social sciences, particularly political science and sociology over the last three decades (a process he labels “economic imperialism”); and 2) Etzioni’s (1988) renewed call for socioeconomics, that is, an orientation toward social science analysis recognizing not only egoistic material motives, but as well motivation arising from recognition of duties toward and/or love of others. Etizoni’s objectives in this regard are similar to those we associated in the introduction of this section with Thompson, Ellis, and Wildavsky (1990) in that he sees rationality employed instrumentally to achieve a range of ends broader than those involving material self-interest.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Arndt, P. 1935. Heinrich Dietzel (1857–1935). Economic Journal 45: 797–794.Google Scholar
  2. Becker, G. 1957. The economics of discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  3. Becker, G. 1960. An economic analysis of fertility. In The economics of discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  4. Becker, G. 1964. Human capital: A theoretical and empirical approach. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  5. Becker, G. 1976. The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  6. Bostaph, S. 1976. Epistemological foundations of methodological conflict in economics: The case of the nineteenth-century “methodenstreit.” Ph.D. thesis, Southern Illinois University.Google Scholar
  7. Boulding, K. 1969. Economics as a moral science. American Economic Review 59: 1–12.Google Scholar
  8. Buchanan, J., and G. Tullock. 1962. The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  9. Calabresi, G. 1961. Some thoughts on risk distribution and the law of torts. Yale Law Journal 70: 499–533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Coase, R. 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Conrad, A. H., and J. R. Meyer. 1958. The economics of slavery in the Antebellum South. Journal of Political Economy 66: 95–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Dahrendorf, R. 1958. Homo Sociologicus. In Essays in the theory of society. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1958–1968.Google Scholar
  13. Dietzel, H. 1883. Der ausgangspunkt der sozialwirtschaftsiehre und ihr grundbegriff. Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 39: 1–80.Google Scholar
  14. Dietzel, H. 1895. Theoretische Sozialökonomik. Leipzig: C. F. Wintersche Verlagshandlung.Google Scholar
  15. Downs, A. 1957. An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  16. Ehrlich, I. 1975. Capital punishment: A case of life and death. American Economic Review 65: 397–417.Google Scholar
  17. Elster, J., ed. 1986. Rational choice. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
  18. Etzioni, A. 1985. Making policy for complex systems: A medical model for economics. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 4: 383–395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Etzioni, A. 1986. Founding a new socio-economics. Challenge 29(5): 13–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Etzioni, A. 1987a. How rational are we? Sociological Forum 2: 1–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Etzioni, A. 1987b. On thoughtless rationality (rules-of-thumb). Kyklos 40: 496–514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Etzioni, A. 1988. The moral dimension: Toward a new economics. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  23. Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology 91: 481–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hansen, R. 1968. Der methodenstreit in den Sozialwissenschaften zwischen Gustav Schmoller und Karl Menger. Seine wissenschaftshistorische und wissenschaftstheoretische bedeutung. In Beitrdge zur Entwicklung der Wissenschaftstheorie im 19. Jahrhundert, edited by A. Diemer. Melsenhweim am Glan: Veriag Anton Hain.Google Scholar
  25. Hernes, G. 1978. Mot en institutionell oekonomi. In Forhandlingsoekonomi og blandingsadministrasjon. Bergen: Universitetsforlaget.Google Scholar
  26. Hindess, B. 1984. Rational choice theory and the analysis of political action. Economy and Society 13: 255–277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Hirsch, P., S. Michaels, and R. Friedman. 1987. “Dirty hands” versus “clean models”: Is sociology in danger of being seduced by economics?” Theory and Society 16: 317–336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Hirschleifer, J. 1985. The expanding domain of economics. American Economic Review 75(6): 53–68.Google Scholar
  29. Lewin, L. 1988. Det gemensamma b’asta: om egenintresset och allmänintresset i västerländsk politik (The common good: On private interests and the common good in western politics). Boras, Sweden: Carlssons.Google Scholar
  30. Marshall, A. 1891. Principles of economics. London: Macmillan and Company.Google Scholar
  31. Mill, J. S. 1838. On the definition of political economy: And on the method of investigation proper to it. In Essays on some unsettled questions of political economy. London: John W. Parker.Google Scholar
  32. Mongiovi, G. 1988. The American methodenstreit. History of Economic Society Bulletin, 10(1): 57–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Parsons, T. 1934. Sociological elements in economic thought, I–II. Quarterly Journal of Economics 49: 414–453, 645–667.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Parsons, T., and N. Smelser. 1956. Economy and society: A study in the integration of economic and social theory. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
  35. Posner, R. 1973. Economic analysis of law. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
  36. Roemer, J. 1982. A general theory of exploitation and class. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Samuelson, P. 1947. Foundations of economic analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  38. Schön, M. 1989. Gustav Schmoller and Max Weber. In Max Weber and his contemporaries, edited by W. J. Mommsen and J. Osterhammel. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  39. Schumpeter, J. A. 1954. History of economic analysis, London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  40. Souter, R. 1933. Prolegomena to relativity economics: An elementary study in the mechanics and organics of an expanding economic universe. New York: Columbia University Press, 1933.Google Scholar
  41. Stigler, G. 1984. Economics—the imperial science? Scandinavian Journal of Economics 96: 301–313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Swedberg, R. 1987. Economic sociology: Past and present. Current Sociology 35(1): 1–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Swedberg, R. 1990. Economics and sociology: Redefining their boundaries. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
  44. Tullock, G. 1972. Economic imperialism. In Theory of political choice, edited by J. M. Buchanan and R. D. Tollison. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  45. Tullock, G., and R. McKenzie. 1975. The new world of economics: Explorations into the human experience. 4th ed. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.Google Scholar
  46. Weber, Max. 1949. The methodology of the social sciences. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  47. Weber, Max. 1975. Marginal utility theory and the fundamental law of psychophysics. Social Science Quarterly, 56: 21–36.Google Scholar
  48. Wegener, W. 1962. Die quellen der wissenschaftsauffassung Max Webers und die problematik der wertuheilsfreiheit der nationalökonomie. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
  49. Wicksell, K. 1904. Måi och medel i nationalekonomien (Ends and means in economic theory). Ekonomisk tidskrift (Sweden) 6: 457–474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Williamson, O. 1976. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
  51. Winkelmann, J. 1986. Max Webers hinterlassenes hauptwerk: Die Wirtschaft und die gesellschaftlichen Ordnungen und Mächte. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr.Google Scholar
  52. Wrong, D. 1961. The oversocialized conception of man in modern sociology. American Sociological Review 26: 183–193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Lane Crothers and Charles Lockhart 2000

Authors and Affiliations

  • Richard Swedberg

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations