Skip to main content

Transactions and Cities

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 138 Accesses

Abstract

The main objectives of this chapter are to explain the origination, development, density, scale determination, and industry positioning of cities using the concept of transactions and to discuss the impacts of institutional changes and policy improvements on cities. Statistically, transactions can bring about transaction benefits. Pursuing transaction benefits leads people to congregate, which may yield congestion externalities and market-net externalities, and their differences form the congregation rent. Population density may reach the optimal equilibrium when the congregation rent corresponding to the population density is at its maximum, which determines the economic density and scale of the city. The time distribution of the city’s growth process is similar to the economic income change corresponding to the change in population density because the people’s incentive to swarm into cities is proportional to the benefits that they may receive from cities. A larger economic scale results in a stronger congregative effect. Different industries may position from the center of the city to the outside according to their congregative effects from higher to lower that depend on the different optimal economic scales of different industries. Finally, the decrease in non-market transaction costs brought about by institutional changes may affect the density and scale of cities through an impact on the volume of transactions; policy changes may also affect transaction costs and the density and scale of cities. However, such effects may not be as obvious and sustainable as institutional changes.

This chapter reflects the author when taking charge of an urban planning project under the auspices of the Unirule Institute.

Translated from Research of Institutional Economics (《制度经济学研究》), Volume 41, Issue 3, 2013

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Basically, it corresponds to Commons’ “Bargaining transaction,” “Managerial transaction</Superscript>,<Superscript>” and “Rationing transaction” (1983).

References

  • 笪凤媛和张卫东, “我国 1978–2007 年间非市场交易费用的变化及其估算”, 《数量经济技术经济研究》2009 年第 8 期 (Da Fengyuan and Zhang Weidong, Changes of Non-market Transaction Costs and its Estimation in China from 1978 to 2007, the Journal of Quantitative and Technical Economics, 2009 (8)).

    Google Scholar 

  • 国家统计局国民经济核算司, 《中国投入产出表(2007年)》, 中国统计出版社, 2009. (Department of National Accounts of the National Bureau of Statistics, China Input-Output Table (2007), China Statistics Press, 2009).

    Google Scholar 

  • 金玉国, “中国交易费用变动的动态机制和传导路径——一个基于VAR方法的实证研究”, 《财经研究》, 2006 年第12期。(Jin Yuguo, Dynamic Mechanism and Pathway of Change of Transaction Costs in China--an Empirical study based on VAR method, Journal of Finance and Economics, 2006(12)).

    Google Scholar 

  • 康芒斯, 《制度经济学》, 商务印书馆, 1983. (Translated from: Commons, Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy, Macmillan Company, 1934).

    Google Scholar 

  • 盛洪, 《分工与交易》, 上海三联书店, 1992. (Sheng Hong, Division of Labor and Transactions, Shanghai Sanlian Publishing Company, 1992).

    Google Scholar 

  • 藤田昌久, 克鲁格曼和维纳布尔斯, 《空间经济学——城市、区域与国际贸易》, 中国人民大学出版社, 2005. (Translated from: Masahisa Fujita, Krugman, Paul and Venables, Anthony J., The Spatial Economy—Cities, Regions and International Trade, The MIT Press, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, John and North, Douglass, Measuring the Transaction Sector in the American Economy, Chapter 3 in Long-Term Factors in American Economic Growth, edited by Stanley L. Engerman and Robert E. Gallman, University of Chicago Press, 1986.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sheng Hong .

Appendices

Appendix 1: Derivation of Market-Network Externalities Considering Diminishing Marginal Transaction Benefits

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{The}\ \mathrm{aggregate}\ \mathrm{demand}\ \mathrm{function}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{the}\ \mathrm{entire}\ \mathrm{society}\ \\ {}\mathrm{relative}\ \mathrm{to}\ \mathrm{the}\ \mathrm{population}\ \mathrm{density}:\mathrm{Marginal}\ \mathrm{Utility}=a-b\ast n\end{array}} $$
$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{The}\ \mathrm{aggregate}\ \mathrm{supply}\ \mathrm{function}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{the}\ \mathrm{entire}\ \mathrm{society}\ \\ {}\mathrm{relative}\ \mathrm{to}\ \mathrm{the}\ \mathrm{population}\ \mathrm{density}:\mathrm{Marginal}\ \mathrm{Costs}=c+d\ast n\end{array}} $$
$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{Marginal}\ \mathrm{Transaction}\ \mathrm{Dividends}=\mathrm{Marginal}\ \mathrm{Utility}\hbox{--} \mathrm{Marginal}\ \mathrm{Costs}\\ {}\kern19.75em =\left(a\hbox{--} b\ast n\right)\hbox{--} \left(c+d\ast n\right)=\left(a\hbox{--} c\right)\hbox{--} \left(b+d\right)\ast n\end{array}} $$
$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{Network}\ \mathrm{Externalities}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{Marginal}\ \mathrm{Transaction}\ \mathrm{Benefits}\ \left(\mathrm{CE}\right)\\ {}=\sum \mathrm{Marginal}\ \mathrm{Transaction}\ \mathrm{Benefits}\ast \left(\mathrm{ME}(n)\hbox{--} \mathrm{ME}\left(n\hbox{--} 1\right)\right)\\ {}=\sum \left(\left(a\hbox{--} c\right)\hbox{--} \left(b+d\right)\ast n\right)\ast \left[n\left(n\hbox{--} 1\right)/2\hbox{--} \left(n\hbox{--} 1\right)\left(n\hbox{--} 2\right)/2\right]\\ {}=\sum \left(\left(a\hbox{--} c\right)\hbox{--} \left(b+d\right)\ast n\right)\ast \left(n\hbox{--} 1\right)\approx \sum \left(\left(a\hbox{--} c\right)\hbox{--} \left(b+d\right)\ast n\right)\ast n\\ {}=\sum \left(\left(a\hbox{--} c\right)\ n\hbox{--} \left(b+d\right)\ast {n}^2\right)n=1,2,3,\dots \end{array}} $$

Appendix 2: Derivation of Congestion Externalities Formula

Assume that the city is a circle, and the commuting population lives outside the city and enters the city when going to work or shopping. According to the city’s highest population density per square kilometer and considering the proportion of people living in and outside the city, we assume that Nin (100 people) enter the city center from outside. The transport resources are the areas covered by roads, and transport resources are assumed to be the circumference of the circle of any radius from the center of the city. When people move from outside to the city center, the radius to the center is smaller, and the circumference (transport resources) is decreasing, but the number of people is not reduced, which leads to congestion. See the following figure.

figure a

Assume that the number of people entering the city to the total number of people in a square kilometer of the city center is a ratio (Nt); then, the number of commuting people entering the city is as follows:

$$ {\mathrm{N}}_{\mathrm{in}}={\mathrm{N}}_t\ast \mathrm{N}\ \left(\mathrm{per}\ \mathrm{square}\ \mathrm{kilometer}\right) $$
$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{Unit}\ \mathrm{Transport}\ \mathrm{Resources}\ \mathrm{Capacity}\\ {}={\mathrm{N}}_{\mathrm{in}}/\left[2\pi\ {\left(\mathrm{N}/\pi n\right)}^{0.5}\right]={\mathrm{N}}_{\mathrm{in}}/\left[2{\left( N\pi /n\right)}^{0.5}\right]\end{array}} $$

In fact, obtaining the population per square meter in a downtown area is very difficult because, in the absence of data for congestion externalities, we cannot determine the city center at equilibrium and its population density. Nonetheless, in the end, multiple iterations can achieve this information.

However, the congestion has not only linear proportional relations to the reduction in the number of transport resources per capita but also non-linear reduction relations. Therefore, we need to add an index associated with population density, which we call the congestion coefficient, and it is represented by h:

$$ \mathrm{Congestion}\ \mathrm{Externalities}={\mathrm{N}}_{\mathrm{in}}/\left[2{\left( N\pi /n\right)}^{0.5}\right]\ast {\mathrm{n}}^h $$

Appendix 3: Formula for Congregation Rent

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{Congregation}\ \mathrm{Rent}\ \left(\mathrm{CR}\right)=\mathrm{CE}\hbox{--} \mathrm{JE}\\ {}=\left[\left(a\hbox{--} c\right)\hbox{--} \left(b+d\right)\ast n/2\right]\left(n\ast \left(n\hbox{--} 1\right)/2\right)\hbox{--} {\mathrm{N}}_{\mathrm{in}}/\left[2{\left( N\pi /n\right)}^{0.5}\right]\ast {n}^h\end{array}} $$

Appendix 4: Analyses of Policy Effects

6.1.1 Policy Promotion at Startup

As previously mentioned, when the economic density is low, the market-led congregation speed is slow; only when the density reaches a certain point will the effects of the market increase. Therefore, if during the startup stage the government promotes urban districts to cross the tipping point earlier through policy and other operations, such as utilizing its influence to attract direct investments and to move in public institutions, doing so would also develop the city. However, this governmental role should not be overestimated. Table 6.4 assumes that, through government policies and operations, an urban district reaches 3000 people per square kilometer at the outset of economic development, and the contrast situation is one without these promotional procedures (Fig. 6.22).

Table 6.4 Policy effects by the government’s initial promotion (unit: 100 million yuan)
Fig. 6.22
figure 22

Policy effects by the government’s initial promotion (unit: 100 million yuan)

This chart shows that the government’s initial push has an obvious impact in the first years, reaching up to a maximum of 55% of the GDP (2013). However, it decreases later and has almost no effect after ten years. Additionally, in this model, we do not count the cost of government promotion in industrial congregation policy.

6.1.2 Housing Rent Subsidy Policy

To facilitate the industrial congregation planned, the government can adopt policies to subsidize housing rents or prices. Beijing Financial Street subsidizes 1000 yuan/square meter to attract financial firms.

We will consider a 10% subsidy of the housing rates, which is also equivalent to a permanent 10% rental subsidy. Table 6.5 and Fig. 6.23 represent the effect of the housing rent subsidy policy.

Table 6.5 Effects of housing rent subsidy policy (unit: 100 million yuan)
Fig. 6.23
figure 23

Effects of housing rent subsidy policy (unit: 100 million yuan)

Figure 6.23 shows that, although the impact of subsidizing rent is not very significant—usually at approximately 4%–5%—its effects last long and eventually bring a certain increase in total GDP.

6.1.3 Policies Subsidizing Transaction Costs

Administrative departments may establish related funds to subsidize transaction costs, namely, by providing subsidies to each transaction procedures, including the following:

  • Applications for intellectual property rights;

  • Technical standards;

  • Venture capital investment;

  • Open of the laboratory;

  • Incubation;

  • Credit rating;

  • Loan;

  • Mediation services;

  • Public offerings;

  • Purchasing information products;

  • Bringing up intellectual property litigation;

  • Establishment of information system; and

  • Others.

We assume that the policy on subsidizing transaction costs is implemented for ten years. The government stops the policy’s implementation after the incubation of mature intermediary service institutions and intermediary service markets have grown up. The effect of the policy is as follows (Table 6.6).

Table 6.6 Effects of policy subsidizing transaction costs (unit: 100 million yuan)

Figure 6.24 shows that, during the first few years, the effect of policies subsidizing transaction costs is significant, at up to 57% in 2013 and 30% in 2014. It then gradually decreases but still maintains a relatively significant influence. The effect is significantly higher than the government inputs of subsidies for transaction costs (2% of the GDP). Until 2021, the effect undergoes minor fluctuations after the subsidy policy is stopped.

Fig. 6.24
figure 24

Effects of policy subsidizing transaction costs (unit: 100 million yuan)

6.1.4 Policies Promoting Industrial Alliance and Association Development

The administrative departments may lead or support enterprises or civil organizations to establish industrial alliances or associations or to support these industries by purchasing their products. The supporting policy can be implemented for ten years. After that, industry alliances and associations develop and operate by themselves. The assumption is that the results of this policy reduce transaction costs (1% of total value added).

The effects of policies are as follows (Table 6.7).

Table 6.7 Effects of policies promoting industrial alliances (unit: 100 million yuan)

Figure 6.25 shows that this policy has played a role; however, relative to other policies, the effect is not significant but is very efficient compared with the input. Furthermore, this result is only a static analysis. From a dynamic perspective, if this policy develops relatively mature industry associations and industry alliances, it will bring long-term benefits.

Fig. 6.25
figure 25

Effects of policies promoting industrial alliances (unit: 100 million)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Hong, S. (2020). Transactions and Cities. In: Vision and Calculation. Palgrave Macmillan, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-2898-9_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-2898-9_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-15-2897-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-15-2898-9

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics