Skip to main content

Price Distortions and Public Information: Theory, Experiments, and Simulations

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 887 Accesses

Abstract

This paper studies the effects on the asset price of the introduction of a public signal in the presence of asymmetric private information in a decentralized market. We introduce an artificial market model populated by bounded rational agents with heterogeneous levels of reasoning: sophisticated and naive traders. The model captures the main impacts of public information analyzed in the laboratory experiments reported by Ruiz-Buforn et al. (Higher-order beliefs and overweighting of public information in a laboratory financial market, 2019). Public information, when correct, coordinates market activity, improving price convergence to the fundamentals. By contrast, unwarranted public information pushes prices away from fundamentals. This strong influence of public information on prices is primarily driven by its common knowledge property.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Cognitive hierarchical models represent stock markets where some traders believe, incorrectly and over-confidently, that their strategy is the most sophisticated. In such situations, “the players are not in equilibrium because some players’ beliefs are mistaken” (Camerer et al. 2004).

  2. 2.

    Ruiz-Buforn et al. (2018) test the overweighting phenomenon when traders can acquire costly private information.

  3. 3.

    The amount of cash is a loan that they must give back at the closing of the market.

  4. 4.

    Hereafter, we will denote the expected dividend as \(D_i \equiv E[D=1|x_i,y]\).

  5. 5.

    The expected payoff denotes the income of the trader after dividend payment.

  6. 6.

    The proposer knows with certainty the gains of his action since they do not depend on the liquidation value of the asset.

  7. 7.

    See Appendix 7.1 for the extended functions.

  8. 8.

    For example, she identifies the proposer as type H when she observes a bid \(b>D_M\). In case she observes a buy offer at \(b>D_L\), she infers the probability that the expected dividend of the proposer is \(D_H\) or \(D_M\). A bid \(b<D_L\) does not carry additional information since any trader makes positive expected payoffs buying at a very low price.

  9. 9.

    Table 3 in Appendix 7.2 describes the information revealed in every offer, together with some illustrative examples to explain the computing process of the expected payoffs.

  10. 10.

    Recall that sophisticated traders believe all other traders are naive.

  11. 11.

    The quadratic nature of the costs is necessary for having an optimal value for the number of offers.

  12. 12.

    In order to compute it, we refer to Table 1. Note that \(f(\tau _i,\tau '_i)=0 \quad \forall i\).

  13. 13.

    We omit the \(\varepsilon \) parameter for notational convenience.

  14. 14.

    During the experiment, earnings and dividends are designated in experimental currency units (ECU) and converted into Euro at the end of the session.

  15. 15.

    Within treatments, we differentiate between two types of markets. Markets with a correct public or common signal are labeled “Correct PS” and “Correct CS”, respectively. Markets with an incorrect released signal are labeled as “Incorrect PS” and “Incorrect CS”.

  16. 16.

    In treatment B, one group of subjects participate and, therefore, there are 10 markets. In treatments PS and CS, two groups of subjects participate; we have therefore 20 markets for each treatment.

  17. 17.

    In the CS scenario, the procedure for the resolution of the theoretical model is explained in Appendix 8.

  18. 18.

    We denote now the released signal by \(\hat{y}\) instead of y like in Eq. (1) to unify the three scenarios (benchmark, public signal, and common signal) into a single equation.

  19. 19.

    We assume that the number of traders is sufficiently large that the fluctuations around the mean can be neglected.

  20. 20.

    From Fig. 3 one can infer that we would obtain similar results if the fixed proportion of sophisticated traders lies in the interval \(\theta \in [0.2,0.7]\).

  21. 21.

    The intuition to follow when a sophisticated trader receives a sell offer is similar to a buy offer.

  22. 22.

    We adopt the following notation throughout the examples of received offers. b and a indicate whether the received offer is a buy or a sell offer, respectively; subindex \(\{H, M, L\}\) stands for the level of the price, which is equivalent to the expected dividend level; \(H^-\) and \(H^+\) are used to denote that the price is slightly below or above the level \(D_H\), namely \(D_H-\varepsilon \) and \(D_H+\varepsilon \), respectively.

  23. 23.

    In CS, privately uninformed traders are absent, therefore \(\chi _i\in \{-3,-1,1,3\}\). Remember that in PS scenario, traders might be informed \(x_i\in \{-2,2\}\) or uninformed \(x_i=0\).

References

  • Allen F, Morris S, Shin HS (2006) Beauty contests and iterated expectations in asset markets. Rev Finan Stud 19(3):719–752

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Weigelt K (1991) Information mirages in experimental asset markets. J Bus 64:463–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer CF, Ho T-H, Chong J-K (2004) A cognitive hierarchy model of games. Q J Econ 119(3):861–898

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corgnet B, DeSantis M, Porter D (2015) Revisiting information aggregation in asset markets: reflective learning & market efficiency. ESI Working Papers

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffie D (2012) Dark markets: asset pricing and information transmission in over-the-counter markets. Princeton University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffie D, Gârleanu N, Pedersen LH (2005) Over-the-counter markets. Econometrica 73(6):1815–1847

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffie D, Malamud S, Manso G (2015) Reprint of: information percolation in segmented markets. J Econ Theory 158:838–869

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffie D, Manso G (2007) Information percolation in large markets. Am Econ Rev 97(2):203–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman SJ, Stiglitz JE (1980) On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. Am Econ Rev 70:393–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1945) The use of knowledge in society. Am Econ Rev 35(4):519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris S, Shin HS (2002) Social value of public information. Am Econ Rev 92(5):1521–1534

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris S, Shin HS (2005) Central bank transparency and the signal value of prices. Brook Papers Econ Act 2005(2):1–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott CR, Sunder S (1982) Efficiency of experimental security markets with insider information: an application of rational-expectations models. J Polit Econ 90(4):663–698

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott CR, Sunder S (1988) Rational expectations and the aggregation of diverse information in laboratory security markets. Econometrica 56:1085–1118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruiz-Buforn A (2019) On the impact of public information in financial markets: an experimental approach (Doctoral dissertation, Universitat Jaume I, Castellón de la Plana, España). Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.net/10803/667025

  • Ruiz-Buforn A, Alfarano S, Camacho-Cuena E, Morone A (2018) Crowding out effect and traders’ overreliance on public information in financial markets: a lesson from the lab. MPRA Paper 88866, University Library of Munich, Germany

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller R J (2002) Irrational exuberance in the media. The Right to Tell, p 83

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to the Universitat Jaume I under the project UJI-B2018-77 and the Generalitat Valenciana for the financial support under the project AICO/2018/036. Alba Ruiz Buforn acknowledges the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology under an Formación de Profesorado Universitario (FPU14/01104) grant.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Simone Alfarano .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

7 Public Signal Scenario

1.1 7.1 Sophisticated Proposers

The expected payoff function of a sophisticated proposer has two components: (i) the expected payoff if the offer is accepted multiplied by the probability of acceptance and (ii) the expected payoff if the offer is rejected, i.e., \(D_i\). Submitting sell offers:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^S(a|D_i)=\sum _j \left( a \; Pr[a<D_j|D_i] + D_i \; Pr[a\ge D_j|D_i] \right) \;. \end{aligned}$$

Submitting buy offers:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^S(b|D_i)= \sum _j \Big ( (2 D_i-b) \; Pr[b>D_j|D_i] + D_i \; Pr[b\le D_j|D_i] \Big ) \;. \end{aligned}$$

1.2 7.2 Sophisticated Receivers

This section provides some illustrative examples to clarify the computation of expected payoffs when a sophisticated trader receives an offer. Table 3 lists all inferences that a sophisticated trader can make observing a particular offer, assuming all offers are submitted by naive traders.

Table 3 Sophisticated receivers’ inference about the expected dividend of the proposer

Receiving Buy Offers: An Example Footnote 21

Let us suppose that a sophisticated trader \(S_L\), whose expected dividend is \(D_L\) observes a bid. She updates her beliefs and decides whether accepting or rejecting the offer. For instance, in case she observes a bid \( b_{H^-}=D_H-\varepsilon \), she infers the type of proposer is a naive whose expected dividend is \(D_H\).Footnote 22

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^S( b_{H^-},D_L) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} b_{H^-} &{} \text { accepting the bid} \\ \sum _j D_{Lj} \; Pr[D_j|D_j>b_{H^-}] &{} \text { rejecting the bid} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

where \(D_j=D_H\) since a naive trader with a high expected dividend is the only trader submitting this offer without incurring in losses. Thus \(D_{Lj}=D_{LH}\) refers to the updated expected dividend, where subindex L means her prior expected dividend and H is the guessed proposer’s expected dividend. Her updated expected dividend is

$$\begin{aligned} D_{LH} \equiv E[D=1|x_L,x_H,y]=\frac{1}{1+\left( \frac{1-p}{p}\right) ^{-2+2}\left( \frac{1-q}{q}\right) ^{y}} \;. \end{aligned}$$

In case she observes a bid \(b_{M^-}=D_M-\varepsilon \), the type of proposer might be M or H.

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^S( b_{M^-},D_L) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \begin{aligned} b_{M^-} \end{aligned} &{} \text { accepting the bid} \\ \begin{aligned} D_{LM} \; Pr[D_M|D_M>b_{M^-}]\\ {} +D_{LH} \; Pr[D_H|D_H>b_{M^-}] \end{aligned} &{} \text { rejecting the bid} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

where the updated expected dividend is given by

$$\begin{aligned} D_{LM}\equiv E[D=1|x_L,x_M,y]=\frac{1}{1+\left( \frac{1-p}{p}\right) ^{-2+0}\left( \frac{1-q}{q}\right) ^{y}} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} D_{LH}\equiv E[D=1|x_L,x_H,y]=\frac{1}{1+\left( \frac{1-p}{p}\right) ^{-2+2}\left( \frac{1-q}{q}\right) ^{y}} \; . \end{aligned}$$

The probability assigned to a proposer of type M given that the receiver has an expected dividend \(D_L\) is computed by

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} Pr[D_M|D_M>b_{M^-}]=\frac{Pr[b_{M^-}|D_M] \;\; Pr[D_M|D_L]}{Pr(b_{M^-}|D_L)}\\ =\frac{\frac{1}{4}2pq[(1-D_L)+D_L]}{\frac{1}{4}[D_L(p^2+2pq)+(1-D_L)(q^2+2pq)]} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Conversely, she cannot update her beliefs when she observes a bid \(b_{L^-}=D_L-\varepsilon \) because any type of trader could submit that offer.

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^S( b_{L^-},D_L) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \begin{aligned} b_{L^-} \end{aligned} &{} \text { accepting the bid} \\ \begin{aligned} D_{L} \end{aligned} &{} \text { rejecting the bid} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

8 Common Signal Scenario

The analysis of the common signal scenario follows the same structure as the case of PS scenario. The main difference with the PS scenario lies in the sophisticated traders’ strategies. Nonetheless, the lack of common knowledge does not change naive traders’ behavior since they evaluate signals according to their precision about fundamentals. This Appendix explains the main differences in the CS scenario and the results of the model.

1.1 8.1 Sophisticated Traders

Sophisticated traders consider the distribution of information in order to assess market demand. However, contrary to public signal, the common signal does not allow them to better characterized the potential market demand. They estimate the potential demand assuming each trader possesses three independent private signals \(\{x_i,y_i\}\) because they are not aware that \(y_i\) is identical to all traders. We must redefine, therefore, the expected dividend for a trader of type i as:

$$\begin{aligned} E[D=1|x_i,y_i]=\frac{1}{1+\left( \frac{1-p}{p}\right) ^{x_i}\left( \frac{1-q}{q}\right) ^{y_i}} \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where \(x_i=\{-2,0,2\}\) refers to private signals and \(y_i=\{-1,1\}\) refers to the common signal. Notwithstanding the common signal is unique for all traders in the market, the sophisticated traders classify traders in four groups according to the four possible expected dividends \(\{D_H,D_{\overline{M}},D_{\underline{M}},D_L\}\), corresponding to all the possible combinations of \(\chi _i=(x_i+y_i)\).Footnote 23 We introduce the notation \(\overline{M}\) and \(\underline{M}\) to denote the low and high intermediate levels. The variable i takes the values \(\{H,\overline{M},\underline{M},L\}\). It is important to stress, however that only three are the levels effectively present in the market. For instance, if the common signal is \(y_i=1\), existing types of traders are \(\{H,\overline{M},\underline{M}\}\) and the types of traders are \(\{\overline{M},\underline{M},L\}\) when common signal is \(y_i=-1\). The optimal offer is computed by following the process explained in Sect. 2.2.

In case a sophisticated trader receives an offer, it provides her with new information to be updated. Unlike markets in the PS scenario, she identifies four possible type of proposers \(j\in \{H,\overline{M},\underline{M},L\}\), although one of them does not actually exist.

1.2 8.2 Transactions

Tables 4 and 5 list the market transactions when the dividend is \(D=1\) and the common signal is correct or incorrect, respectively. The first column denotes the proposer’s type according to his level of reasoning and expected dividend. The second and the third columns show the optimal offer of each trader while the last column shows the counterpart of every transaction.

In order to compare the results between common and public signal, one should consider that when the common signal indicates dividend 1, \(j=\overline{M}\) corresponds to the M and \(j=\underline{M}\) corresponds to L. If the common signal indicates dividend 0, \(j=\overline{M}\) corresponds to the H and \(j=\underline{M}\) corresponds to M. We rename the type of traders and offers for each prediction of the common signal \(y_i =\{-1,1\}\) for an easier comparison between markets with common signal and markets where the released signal is public. Considering only private signals, the possible types of traders are \(\{H,{\overline{M}}, {\underline{M}}\}\) if the common signal predicts dividend 1 (Table 4); otherwise \(j\in \{{\overline{M}},{\underline{M}}, L\}\) (Table 5). Considering the previous changes, we define a vector of market prices following the proposer’s type offer in Table 4, \(\mathbf {P}=(D_M,D_L,D_L,D_M,D_H,D_M,D_L)\). The vector of transaction prices when the common signal predicts dividend 0 is \(\mathbf {P}=(D_M,D_H,D_H,D_M,D_H,D_M,D_L)\), which is listed in Table 5.

Finally, the expected number of transactions per unit of time is listed in Table 6. The mean price is computed by Eq. (6).

Table 4 Transactions when the common signal is 1
Table 5 Transactions when the common signal is \(-1\)
Table 6 Expected number of transactions per unit of time for every type of trader, given \(D=1\) in CS scenario

9 Robustness: Does Market Configuration Matter?

This subsection aims at testing the relevance of the distribution of signals in markets with public information. Intuitively, the proportion of informed traders in the aggregation and dissemination of information matters. For example, an incorrect public signal might largely distort prices when the proportion of informed traders is small. However, an incorrect public signal should be harmless when most of the traders are informed. Since the most concerning case is the impact of an incorrect public signal, we restrict our attention to the PS scenario to assess the importance of market configuration. We define three market configurations based on observed distributions of information across traders in the laboratory experiment. (i) Config. 1, markets are populated by 5 uninformed and 10 informed traders. (ii) Config. 2, markets are populated by 1 misinformed trader, 7 uninformed traders and 7 informed traders. (iii) Config. 3 where markets are populated by 2 misinformed, 5 uninformed and 8 informed traders.

Figure 6 shows that mean prices change depending on the distribution of private information. When the public signal is correct, one can see that the computational mean takes similar values to the theoretical prediction in markets where uninformed and misinformed traders have a large presence (Config. 2 and Config. 3). For the markets with an incorrect public signal, the public signal always dominates the mean price. The impact is larger when the proportion of informed traders is small (Config. 2 and Config. 3).

Fig. 6
figure 6

Mean price of the market configurations assuming dividend \(D=1\). Shaded area shows 1 standard deviation of the Monte Carlo simulations

Altogether, we can claim that the market configuration can generate systematic deviations from the theoretical prediction, however “not too large”, i.e., the general conclusions still hold. A special case seems to be the configuration where there is absence of misinformed traders. The mean price is noticeably higher than the other market configurations, independently of the prediction of the released signal \(y=\{1,-1\}\). Besides, it is interesting to note that there are no transactions when \(\theta =1\). Therefore, if a market where all traders are sophisticated and none is misinformed, we have no transactions.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Ruiz-Buforn, A., Alfarano, S., Camacho-Cuena, E. (2019). Price Distortions and Public Information: Theory, Experiments, and Simulations. In: Chakrabarti, A., Pichl, L., Kaizoji, T. (eds) Network Theory and Agent-Based Modeling in Economics and Finance. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-8319-9_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics