Skip to main content

Resource Allocations within Families

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Economic Analysis of Families and Society

Part of the book series: Advances in Japanese Business and Economics ((AJBE,volume 16))

  • 498 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter, we analyze resource allocation within families, especially the transfer of resources between parents and children. What is the difference between a parent-children relationship and an ordinary relationship between humans? It can be explained by love or the “altruism” of parents towards their children. Parents’ altruism towards their children can be well understood from the biological and evolutionary viewpoints.

[T]ell me which one of you loves me most, so that I can give my largest gift to the one who deserves it most.

Shakespeare, W. King Lear. [I-1]

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    We can observe resource transfer between spouses and among siblings. Some analyses examine resource transfer between husbands and wives, as suggested by our discussion in Sect. 4.3. However, very few analyses investigate resource transfer among siblings, suggesting that their relationship does not have special characteristics, except for the general rivalry and battle for the love and wealth of their parents, as suggested by Shakespeare’s King Lear and the story of Cain and Abel in the Old Testament. See Sect. 5.2.3 for the discussion on strategic bequest motives and their effects on the relationships among siblings.

  2. 2.

    See Cartwright (2000, Chap. 10) for considerations on the parent–children relationship from the perspective of the biology.

  3. 3.

    The proposition is slightly different from the original one in Becker (1974), but let us show the essence of the Rotten-Kid Theorem by considering a simple sufficient condition in the proposition.

  4. 4.

    Imagine a mountain whose contours can be drawn as the indifference curves labeled as \(P_1\), \(P_2\), and \(P_3\).

  5. 5.

    Although it is assumed in Fig. 5.2 to be a simple line where \(c^*_k(a) = c^*_k\) for all a, it does not have to be such a line, in general.

  6. 6.

    Note that the child is assumed to choose \(a^{**}\) because its utility is the same as that at B, that is, the minimum utility. If the parent wants to choose the action \(a^{**}\) for sure, the parent can increase the bequest slightly so that the utility of the child becomes strictly higher than the minimum.

  7. 7.

    The credibility of the parent giving the bequest to the child may be in question. However, we assume here that it is credible because the legal system will allow the parent to commit to the statement. That is, the legal system works as the commitment device for the parent. See Remark 3.8 for the discussion on the credibility of the threat and the commitment.

  8. 8.

    \(P^\prime (e)\) and \(P^{\prime \prime }(e)\) represent the first derivative and second derivative of the function P. We use the similar notations below.

  9. 9.

    For simplicity, we assume that the child’s utility will not be discounted. Even if we consider the “inter-cohort discount factor,” as long as it is close to one, we can get the same results as those obtained here.

  10. 10.

    We can derive the equation as follows. First, we rewrite the basic budget constraint as \(c^t_2 + d^t = y^t - c^{t+1}_1 n^t\), and using the definition \(\rho ^t \equiv {d^t \over c^t_1}\), we derive \(d^{t} = \rho ^t c^t_1\) and \(c^{t+1}_1 = {d^{t+1} \over \rho ^{t+1}}\). By substituting them, we have \(c^t_2 + \rho ^t c^t_1 = y^t - {d^{t+1}n^t \over \rho ^{t+1}}\). Now, as we have \(c^t_3 = d^{t+1}n^t\), dividing both sides by \(\rho ^{t+1}\) and adding them to both sides of the budget constraint above, we have \(\rho ^t c^t_1 + c^t_2 + {c^t_3 \over \rho ^{t+1}} = y^t\). Finally, by dividing both sides of the equation by \(\rho ^t\), we have Eq. (5.5).

  11. 11.

    The problem will be especially serious when the traditional norm of children supporting their parents breaks down in the process of economic development.

  12. 12.

    In a simple model with perfect capital markets, child allowance and the policy to reduce the pension payment when an individual has a smaller number of children are the same. However, there are many people who agree with the former policy and disagree with the latter. From the perspective of policy design, it is interesting to see that people indicate different attitudes towards policies that are essentially equivalent.

  13. 13.

    In the model, it is assumed that the taxation to finance the child allowance does not have any distortionary effect.

References

  • Becker, G. (1974). A theory of social interactions. Journal of Political Economy, 82(6), 1063–1093.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, D., Shleifer, A., & Summers, L. H. (1985). The strategic bequest motives. Journal of Labor Economics, 4(3), S151–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, N., & Waldman, M. (1990). The rotten kid theorem meets the samaritan’s dilemma. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(1), 155–165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cartwright, J. (2000). Evolution and human behavior. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chami, R. (1996). King Lear’s Dilemma: Precommitment versus the last word. Economics Letters, 52, 171–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cigno, A. (1991). Economics of the family. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cigno, A. (1993). Intergenerational transfers without altruism: Family, market and state. European Journal of Political Economy, 7, 505–518.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Groezen, B., Leers, T., & Meijdam, A. C. (2003). Social security and endogenous fertility: Pensions and child allowances as Siamese Twins. Journal of Public Economics, 87(2), 233–251.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1977). Shakespeare vs. Becker on altruism: The importance of having the last word. Journal of Economic Literature, 15(2), 500–502.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horioka, C. (1983). The applicability of the life cycle model of savings to Japan. Mimeo: Kyoto University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sussman, M. B., Cates, J. N., & Smith, O. T. (1970). Inheritance and the family. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wintrobe, R. (1981). It pays to do good, but not to do more good than it pays: A note on the survival of altruism. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 2, 201–213.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shinji Yamashige .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Japan KK

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Yamashige, S. (2017). Resource Allocations within Families. In: Economic Analysis of Families and Society. Advances in Japanese Business and Economics, vol 16. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55909-2_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics