Skip to main content

Turing’s Decidability

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Investing in the Age of Democracy
  • 240 Accesses

Abstract

Entrepreneurship is “the” source of information within the market process. However, it is not explicit, written or available to everyone. Although Finance professionals continuously seek to formalize entrepreneurship, there are necessary conditions to establish formalization. We examine them and show that entrepreneurship is not “decidable”. We discover that an entrepreneur is anyone who creates decidable problems or discovers previously undecidable ones and makes them decidable. This discovery comes in handy when one has to choose in which part of the capital structure (of a business) to invest.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 19.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 24.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    These comments are based on Formalizing Austrian Thought: A Suggested Approach, Revista Procesos de Mercardo, Año 2014, Vol. 11, No. 2, Madrid, (b) Complexity of Algorithms, Lecture Notes 1999, Peter Gács and László Lovász, Chapter 3, and Huerta de Soto’s The Austrian School: Market Order and Entrepreneurial Creativity, Edward Elgar Publishing (2008).

  2. 2.

    For an enjoyable and educating read on the subject, refer Huerta de Soto’s The Austrian School: Market Order and Entrepreneurial Creativity, Edward Elgar Publishing (2008).

  3. 3.

    The symbol “∈” means “belongs to”. Thus, “if x L” means “if x belongs to L”.

  4. 4.

    To be able to recur to probability theory, one must refer to a properly defined collective. A collective must fulfil two conditions: (a) the relative frequencies of particular attributes within a collective must converge to fixed limits, and (b) the fixed limits must not be affected by any place selection.

  5. 5.

    Measured in different periods, said convergence would change.

  6. 6.

    Modigliani, F.; Miller, M. (1958). The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment, American Economic Review.

  7. 7.

    In this case, given the collective “asset classes”, it is legitimate to use probability theory. To begin with, one can expect with confidence that the return of the asset class “equity” shall be higher than that of the asset class “debt”. Otherwise, there would be no entrepreneurship.

  8. 8.
  9. 9.

    I think investing in (private, not public) mezzanine only makes sense if you are a lawyer, looking for work.

  10. 10.

    The oil crisis of the twenty-first century had its origins in the productivity gains created by shale fracking, in the United States and Canada. This obviously led to an oversupply.

  11. 11.

    Cobb, Charles W. (Amherst College) and Douglas, Paul H. (Univ. Of Chicago), A Theory of Production, The American Economic Review, Vol. 18, No. 1, Supplement, Papers and Proceedings of the Fortieth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (Mar., 1928), pp. 139–165. Found at: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1811556?seq=1#page_scan_tab_contents

Bibliography

  • Sibileau, Martin. (2014). Formalizing Austrian Thought: A suggested approach. Madrid: Revista Procesos de Mercardo, Año 2014, Vol. 11, No. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gács, Peter (Boston University) and Lovász, László (Yale University). (Spring 1999). Complexity of Algorithms. Lecture Notes. Retrieved March 2013 from http://web.cs.elte.hu/~lovasz/complexity.pdf

  • Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (June 1958). The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment. American Economic Review. Vol. 48, No. 3, pp. 261–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cobb, Charles W. (Amherst College) and Douglas, Paul H. (Univ. Of Chicago). (March, 1928). A Theory of Production. The American Economic Review. Vol. 18, No. 1, Supplement, Papers and Proceedings of the Fortieth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, pp. 139. Retrieved January 2015 from http://www.jstor.org/stable/1811556?seq=1#page_scan_tab_contents

  • Huerta de Soto, Jesús. (2008). Market Order and Entrepreneurial Creativity. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendices

Appendix I: Monetary Policy and Capital Structure

Interestingly, the so-called quantitative easing (QE) policies of the twenty-first century shed light on the impact of monetary policy on capital structure decisions. QE, in the United States, consists in monetizing US federal government deficits:

In Fig. 3.5, the amount of US dollars in circulation increases when US sovereign debt is purchased by the Fed. The US dollars created are subsequently deposited in the banking system and the wonders of fractional reserve expand them multiple times. In so doing, the “loan” interest rate drops. But since 2009, given the magnitude of QE and the impact of the Basel III regulatory framework, the loan interest rate dropped so significantly that the profitability of the banking system plunged. Forced by law to increase capital and liquidity, and with lower interest rate margins, corporate banks embarked on a path of steady diminishing returns, protected by a blanket of lower expected loan losses. This situation led banks to look beyond common places, to lend to high-yield companies. In so doing, they reversed the natural relationship between decidability and capital structure, discussed in this lesson. Banks, partly funded themselves with demand deposits and partly with debt, could only remain profitable if they earned additional investment banking fees. Therefore, roles reversed and banks became de facto the new providers of venture capital for those sectors that could afford capital markets services (i.e. origination, advisory, hedging). They are usually undecidable ventures and the flavour of the day at that timeFootnote 10 happened to be the US and Canadian oil and gas shale, exploration and production companies. Within the exploration and production (E&P) sub-space, the reversal in the decidability/capital structure suffered the most. The vehicle was secured lending in the form of borrowing base credit lines (Figs. 3.6, 3.7):

Fig. 3.5
figure 5

Balance sheets of the Fed and US government under QE

Fig. 3.6
figure 6

Oil exploration and production without quantitative easing, under normal conditions

Fig. 3.7
figure 7

Oil exploration and production with quantitative easing and Basel III: The recipe for a lending crisis caused by policy makers

Indeed, the crash in the price of oil and gas was caused by factors beyond monetary policy. But, had the profitability of the banking sector not been decimated by regulations, banks would have not been pushed to the borrowing base lending sector in the volumes and at the prices they did. The contagion that took place during 2015 would have thus been much more limited.

Appendix II: Decidability and Economies of Scale

In any regular course of microeconomics, economies of scale may be formalized using the following function:

$$ Y=A\ {L}^{\alpha }\ {K}^{\beta } $$

Where:

  • Y = total production (the real value of all goods produced)

  • L = labour input (the total number of person-hours worked)

  • K = capital input (the real value of all machinery, equip.)

  • A = total factor productivity

  • α and β are the output elasticities of capital and labour, respectively. These values are constants determined by available technology.

If

$$ \alpha \kern0.5em +\kern0.5em \beta =\kern0.5em 1, $$

The production function has constant returns to scale, meaning that doubling the usage of capital K and labour L will also double output Y.

For example, when capital and labour double:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}A\ {\left(2\kern0.5em \times \kern0.5em L\right)}^{\alpha }{\left(2\kern0.5em \times \kern0.5em K\right)}^{\beta }=\\ {}A\ {2}^a\times \kern0.5em {L}^{\alpha}\kern0.5em \times \kern0.5em {2}^{\beta}\times {K}^{\beta }=\\ {}A\ {2}^{\left(\alpha +\beta \right)}\kern0.5em \times \kern0.5em {L}^{\alpha }\ {K}^{\beta}\end{array}} $$

With a + β = 1 and reorganizing 2 A Lα Kβ = 2 Y, which shows that Y (i.e. production) doubles too.

It is therefore easy to see that if:

$$ \alpha \kern0.5em +\kern0.5em \beta <1,\kern0.5em \mathrm{returns}\kern0.5em \mathrm{to}\kern0.5em \mathrm{scale}\ \mathrm{are}\ \mathrm{decreasing}, $$

And if:

$$ \alpha \kern0.5em +\kern0.5em \beta >1,\kern0.5em \mathrm{returns}\kern0.5em \mathrm{to}\kern0.5em \mathrm{scale}\ \mathrm{are}\ \mathrm{increasing}. $$

The above equation is known as the Cobb-Douglas production function, after Paul Douglas and Charles Cobb.Footnote 11 It assumes that there is already a decidable production process that has been identified, which by way of inputting fixed factors of production in a given proportion delivers the produce with a given return. This is by all means a mechanistic view, devoid of any economic sense. But this perspective has been taught and used for so long that we have come to believe in it unquestionably. It doesn’t have any economic sense because, to begin with, it is static. It does not explain how a product came to be, nor how will it remain competitive in the market. In other words, it completely misses the role of entrepreneurship and it assumes no flexibility in terms of resource reallocation. The fact that we cannot formalize such flexibility is not an excuse to ignore it.

With the development of information technology and the internet, a concept similar to “economies of scale” appeared, although this time it did have economic sense. I am referring to the concept of a “platform”. In a way, an online platform is a social institution. Its value derives from the spontaneous social cooperation that it brings to life and is therefore, by its very nature, a concrete form of undecidability. The fact that online platforms are valued by investors is proof that we humans acknowledge the concept of decidability. It is the cooperation that a platform enables what makes it a scalable resource, in a true economic, not mechanistic sense. As an investor, this is the real economies of scale that I look for in my investments allocated to equity.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Arisson, M. (2018). Turing’s Decidability. In: Investing in the Age of Democracy. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-95903-0_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-95903-0_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-95902-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-95903-0

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics