Skip to main content

Hayek, Deflation, Gold, and Nihilism

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Hayek: A Collaborative Biography

Part of the book series: Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics ((AIEE))

Abstract

In his early writings on business cycle theory and the Great Depression Hayek argued that business cycle downturns including the steep downturn of 1929–1931 were caused by unsustainable elongations of capital structure of the economy resulting from bank-financed investment in excess of voluntary saving. Because monetary expansion was the cause of the crisis, Hayek argued that monetary expansion was an inappropriate remedy to cure the deflation and high unemployment caused by the crisis. He therefore recommended allowing the Depression to take its course until the distortions that led to the downturn could be corrected by market forces. However, this view of the Depression was at odds with Hayek’s own neutral money criterion which implied that prices should fall during expansions and rise during contractions so that nominal spending would remain more or less constant over the cycle. Although Hayek strongly favoured allowing prices to fall in the expansion, he did not follow the logic of his own theory in favouring generally increasing prices during the contraction. This chapter explores the reasons for Hayek’s reluctance to follow the logic of his own theory in his early policy recommendations. The key factors responsible for his early policy recommendations seem to be his attachment to the gold standard and the seeming necessity for countries to accept deflation to maintain convertibility and his hope or expectation that deflation would overwhelm the price rigidities that he believed were obstructing the price mechanism from speeding a recovery. By 1935, Hayek’s attachment to the gold standard was starting to weaken, and in later years he openly acknowledged that he had been mistaken not to favor policy measures, including monetary expansion, designed to stabilize total spending.

The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Trade Commission or the individual Commissioners.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The position was secured for Hayek by his mentor, Ludwig von Mises, who was secretary of the Vienna Chamber of Commerce, one of the sponsoring institutions of the Institute.

  2. 2.

    The equilibrium of an economy with n real commodities corresponds a price vector consisting of n-1 relative prices per time period. That equilibrium price vector is invariant to scalar multiplication over all time period but also to exponential multiplication representing the expected rate of inflation across time periods.

  3. 3.

    Hayek (1934) actually understood the point in a different context noting in his reply to a review of Prices and Production by Hansen and Tout (1933) that a steady rate of monetary expansion would cease to have any effect on the capital structure of an economy once the public came to expect that rate of monetary expansion to persist over time, thereby anticipating by over 30 years Friedman’s (1968) argument that the long-run Phillips Curve is vertical.

  4. 4.

    J. L. Caton (2018) documents that in essay in the Economist, Hayek (1935) acknowledged that the demand of central banks for gold reserves was in fact a source of instability in the value of gold and that without some mechanism of international cooperation to limit the monetary demand for gold sufficiently to preserve a stable value of gold, restoring the widely abandoned gold standard could lead to renewed deflation. Thus, by 1935, Hayek seems to have accepted the Cassel-Hawtrey view that international cooperation was necessary to ensure that a gold standard would be consistent with international price stability, precisely the view that he had criticized so severely in his 1932 essay on the gold standard.

  5. 5.

    White uses this distinction to absolve Hayek from the charge that Hayek was a liquidationist, who was provided intellectual support for the liquidationist policies supposedly pursued by Andrew Mellon, Secretary of the Treasury. Following Eichengreen (1992), White suggests that insofar as the liquidationist position enjoyed any intellectual support, that support was derived from supporters of the real-bills doctrine in the Federal Reserve such as Adolph Miller, a former academic economist, and a member of the Fed Board of Governors. Eichengreen and White are quite probably correct in identifying the Fed as the source of liquidationist sentiment that was influencing administration and Fed policy. And White is also correct in noting that Hayek was an outspoken critic of the real-bills doctrine. However, disagreement about the real-bills doctrine does not establish any substantive difference between the liquidationist position of Miller and of his associates on the Fed and the liquidationist position espoused by Hayek in 1933. Presumably, Miller et al. were not unaware of the distinction between bankruptcy and liquidation in the economic sense; White provides no evidence that Miller et al. did not understand that distinction.

  6. 6.

    However, I am not aware of any evidence that Hayek in 1933 understood the full implications of the argument of his 1937 paper acknowledging that there is no market mechanism for achieving equilibrium when, given the lack of a complete set of markets, independent plans are coordinated only insofar as economic agents share identical expectations. Unless there is a market mechanism by which expectations are reconciled—and Hayek acknowledged the lack of such a mechanism—price and wage flexibility does not ensure a tendency toward equilibrium. At most, Hayek conceded, there is an observed, but not theoretically established, empirical tendency towards equilibrium.

References

  • Caldwell, B. (2005). Hayek’s Challenge: An Intellectual Biography of F. A. Hayek. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caton, J. (2018, January 26). The Evolution of Hayek’s Thought on Gold and Monetary Standards. AIER Sound Money Project Working Paper No. 2018-06. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3072766.

  • Corden, W. M. (1982). Exchange-Rate Protection. In R. N. Cooper, et al. (Eds.), The International Monetary System Under Flexible Exchange Rates: Global, Regional and National (pp. 17–39). Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B. (1992). Golden Fetters. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glasner, D. (1985). A Reinterpretation of Classical Monetary Theory. Southern Economic Journal, 52, 46–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glasner, D. (1989). On Some Classical Monetary Controversies. History of Political Economy, 21(2), 201–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glasner, D. (2017). Rules Versus Discretion in Monetary Policy Historically Contemplated. Journal of Macroeconomics, 54(Part A), 24–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glasner, D., & Zimmerman, P. (2014, July 7). The Sraffa-Hayek Debate on the Natural Rate of Interest. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2221695.

  • Friedman, M. (1968, March). The Role of Monetary Policy. American Economic Review, 58(1), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, A. H., & Tout, H. (1933, April). Annual Survey of Business Cycle Theory: Investment and Saving in Business Cycle Theory. Econometrica, 1(2), 119–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. ([1928] 1984). The Intertemporal Price Equilibrium and Movements in the Value of Money. In R. McCloughry (Ed.), Money, Capital and Fluctuations: Early Essays (pp. 171–215). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. ([1929] 1931, May). The Paradox of Savings. Economica, 32, 125–169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1931). Prices and Production. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1932 [1984]). The Fate of the Gold Standard. In R. McCloughry (Ed.), Money, Capital and Fluctuations: Early Essays (pp. 118–35). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1933 [1939]). The Present State and Immediate Prospects of the Study of Industrial Fluctuations. In Profits, Interest and Investment (pp. 171–182). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1934, April). Capital and Industrial Fluctuations. Econometrica, 2(2), 152–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1935, May 11). A Regulated Gold Standard. The Economist, 1077–1078.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1937a, February). Economics and Knowledge. Economica n.s., 4, 33–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1937b). Monetary Nationalism and International Stability. London: Longmans, Green and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1975). A Discussion with Friedrich A. Von Hayek: Held at the American Enterprise Institute on April 9, 1975. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howson, S. (2011). Lionel Robbins. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hume, D. ([1752] 1987). Of the Balance of Trade. In Essays Moral Political and Literary, Part II, 1777 edition. Reprinted by Liberty Classics. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1923). Tract on Monetary Reform. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klausinger, H. (2013). Introduction. In Business Cycles Volume VII of The Collected Works of F. A. Hayek. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laidler, D. (1999). Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. V. (1934 [1953]). The Theory of Money and Credit, new edition. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robertson, D. H. (1922). Money. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1980). A Corrected Version of Hume’s Equilibrating Mechanisms for International Trade. In J. S. Chipman & C. P. Kindleberger (Eds.), Flexible Exchange Rates and the Balance of Payments (pp. 141–158). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1954). The History of Economic Analysis. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L. H. (2008). Did Hayek and Robbins Deepen the Great Depression? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40(4), 751–768.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Glasner, D. (2018). Hayek, Deflation, Gold, and Nihilism . In: Leeson, R. (eds) Hayek: A Collaborative Biography. Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-91358-2_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-91358-2_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-91357-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-91358-2

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics