Skip to main content

Abstract

This chapter concludes on the main findings of the book. Further, this chapter suggests that the Court of Justice plays a more active role in shaping the average consumer by adjusting the law and policy underpinning the average consumer to apply the average consumer more consistently and coherently. As for the contextualisation, the General Court and national courts should clarify the inconsistencies, and particularly, the Nordic judiciaries should make the role of the average consumer in confusion-based disputes more explicit.

This chapter claims that the inconsistencies of the average consumer in European trademark law through a feedback loop may dynamically impact the state of the law and the market by impacting the relevant stakeholders. The stakeholders include the Court of Justice, General Court, national courts, trademark owners and their competitors.

A way forward to clarify the policy underlying the average consumer, is for the Advocates General to include more explicit trademark policy into their opinions that, if the opinions are confirmed by the Court of Justice, will create a more solid policy foundation for the court’s decisions. In this context, the economic function of trademarks as lowering consumer search costs could be considered to create a better policy steer guiding the contextualisation of the average consumer.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    On the understanding of these terms, see Chap. 2, Sects. 2.1 and 2.2.1.

  2. 2.

    See Chap. 5, Sect. 5.3.2 and Chap. 11, Sect. 11.1. On the divide between the Court of Justice and other courts, see also Chap. 4.

  3. 3.

    See Chap. 7, Sect. 7.5.2.

  4. 4.

    See Chap. 4, Sect. 4.2.1.

  5. 5.

    Ibid, Sect. 4.3.1.

  6. 6.

    See Chap. 2, Sect. 2.3.1.

  7. 7.

    See Chap. 8, Sect. 8.5.

  8. 8.

    See Chap. 10, Sect. 10.2.1.

  9. 9.

    See Chap. 8, Sect. 8.3.

  10. 10.

    See Chap. 9, Sect. 9.3.2.1 and Chap. 10, Sect. 10.3.

  11. 11.

    See Chap. 3, Sect. 3.3.2, Chap. 9, Sect. 9.3.2.2 and Chap. 10, Sect. 10.3.

  12. 12.

    See Chap. 9, Sect. 9.3.2.2.

  13. 13.

    See Chap. 10, Sects. 10.2.110.2.3.

  14. 14.

    Ibid, Sect. 10.2.4.

  15. 15.

    Ibid, Sect. 10.3.

  16. 16.

    Ajos, Case 15/2014, [2016], (DKSC), p. 44-51. For further on the decision, see Chap. 3, Sect. 3.3.2.2.

  17. 17.

    See Chap. 10, Sect. 10.2.4 and Chap. 11, Sect. 11.2.1.

  18. 18.

    Ibid, Sect. 10.2 and Chap. 1, Sect. 1.2.

  19. 19.

    See Chap. 1, Sect. 1.2 and Chap. 11, Sect. 11.2.2.

  20. 20.

    See Chap. 11, Sect. 11.4.1.1.

  21. 21.

    As laid out in Chap. 1, Sect. 1.3.

  22. 22.

    This term was already found in the passing off decision from 1866 Seixo v. Provezende. See Chap. 9, Sect. 9.3.2.1.

  23. 23.

    See Chap. 1, Sect. 1.5.5.

  24. 24.

    See Chap. 6, Sects. 6.2 and 6.4.

  25. 25.

    See Chap. 7, Sects. 7.2, 7.5.2 and 7.6.

  26. 26.

    See Chap. 11, Sect. 11.1.

  27. 27.

    OHIM v. BORCO, Case C-265/09 P, [2010] ECR I-8265, para 25. See Chap. 11, Sect. 11.1.

  28. 28.

    See Chap. 11, Sect. 11.6.

  29. 29.

    Anecdotally, the author of this book has heard from an employee at the EUIPO that this presumption has its origin in a presentation made by an expert on consumer behaviour. Several members of the CJEU allegedly attended the presentation.

  30. 30.

    See Chap. 1, Sect. 1.3.

  31. 31.

    Dinwoodie, Graeme B., ‘Trademarks and Territory: Detaching Trademark Law from the Nation-State’, Houston Law Review, vol. 41/no. 3, (2004), pp. 885, p. 889-890 (italics added).

  32. 32.

    Interflora v. Marks & Spencer, [2014] EWCA Civ 1403, para 113. See Chap. 11, Sects. 11.2.1 and 11.4.2.

  33. 33.

    See e.g. Chap. 11, Sect. 11.4.1.1.

  34. 34.

    The focus of Gibson’s article is how the grey areas of intellectual property law, including trademark law, will expand licensing markets of senior right owners due to risk aversion among competitors. In sum, the feedback loop in trademark law is described as: First, that if a trademark is unlicensed by the senior trademark owner, “use is likely to cause confusion among consumers as to whether the mark owner produced, sponsored, or approved of the goods.” Second, to be on the safe side, junior users of trademarks will seek a license from the senior owner, even if unnecessary. Third, as a “norm,” consumers will become used to seeing an expanding practice of licensed trademarks. “And what consumers view as the norm becomes the norm because consumer perception is trademark law’s touchstone.” Gibson, James, ‘Risk Aversion and Rights Accretion in Intellectual Property Law’, the Yale Law Journal, vol. 116 (2007), pp. 882, p. 907-908. Generally, on trademark law, ibid, p. 907-927.

  35. 35.

    Altia v. Arctic Beverage Group, TOSLO-2017-52797, [2018]. NODC. For further on the decision, see Chap. 11, Sect. 11.4.2.2.

  36. 36.

    Altia v. Arctic Beverage Group, TOSLO-2017-52797, [2018]. NODC, p. 7.

  37. 37.

    On this role of the trademark system, see Chap. 1, Sect. 1.3.3.

  38. 38.

    Ibid, Sect. 1.3.1.

  39. 39.

    See Chap. 9, Sect. 9.3.1.1. Broadly, on the origin function see Chap. 1, Sect. 1.3.1.

  40. 40.

    Fhima, Ilanah, ‘Introducing Reality into Trade Mark Law’, Journal of Intellectual Property Law & Practice, vol. 9/no. 8, (2014), pp. 1, p. 3.

  41. 41.

    Ibid, p. 4.

  42. 42.

    See Grynberg, Michael, ‘Trademark Litigation as Consumer Conflict’, New York University Law Review, vol. 83/no. 1, (2008), pp. 60, p. 83.

  43. 43.

    See ibid, p. 87.

  44. 44.

    Gibson, James, ‘Trademark Law as an Agency Problem’, (2015 (an unpublished draft is with the author of this book)), p. 1.

  45. 45.

    See Chap. 9, Sect. 9.3.1.2.

  46. 46.

    See Chap. 4, Sect. 4.3.5, including footnote 158.

  47. 47.

    See Chap. 1, Sect. 1.3.2 and Chap. 4, Sect. 4.3.4.

  48. 48.

    On those means of interpretation, see Chap. 4, Sect. 4.3.4.

  49. 49.

    See Chap. 1, Sect. 1.3.2.

  50. 50.

    See Chap. 1, Sects. 1.3.1 and 1.3.2.

  51. 51.

    See Laustsen, Rasmus D., ‘An Economic Analysis of EU Trademark Law; the Role of the Average Consumer in Trademark Infringement between Two Confusingly Similar Trademarks’, in Lyngsie, Jacob, Mortensen, Bent O. G. and Østergaard, Kim eds., Rets- og Kontraktøkonomi: Law & Economics an Anthology (Djøf Publishing, 2016), 37, in particular p. 47-53.

  52. 52.

    Laband, David N., ‘An Objective Measure of Search Versus Experience Goods’, Economic Inquiry, vol. 29/no. 3, (1991), pp. 497, p. 498. Laband has presented a similar view in terms of classifying search and experience goods in two extreme categories. However, Laband’s classification does not consider that credence goods are logically further away from search goods since even higher search costs are incurred on credence goods than on experience goods by consumers when obtaining information on the goods.

  53. 53.

    Darby, Michael R., and Karni, Edi, ‘Free Competition and the Optimal Amount of Fraud’, Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 16/no. 1, (1973), pp. 67, p. 311-312, p. 313.

  54. 54.

    Economides, Nicolas, ‘The Economics of Trade Marks’, Trademark Reporter, vol. 78 (1987), pp. 523, p. 531. Examples of such products are washing machines, refrigerators, television sets and HiFi equipment.

  55. 55.

    Darby, Michael R., and Karni, Edi, ‘Free Competition and the Optimal Amount of Fraud’, Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 16/no. 1, (1973), pp. 67, p. 68-69, Redmond, William, ‘Three Modes of Competition in the Marketplace’, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, vol. 72/no. 2, (2013), pp. 423, p. 429 and Posner, Richard A., ‘Economic Analysis of Law’, (9th edn, Aspen, 2014), p. 121. Redmond refers to certain services of a technical nature as credence goods, including certain legal, medical and repair services. Posner refers to cars as examples of credence goods. According to Darby and Karni, the purchaser of credence goods will not have a different experience after having purchased the goods. The quality of credence goods may not be assessed until after a longer post sale time has passed.

  56. 56.

    See particularly, Laustsen, Rasmus D., ‘An Economic Analysis of EU Trademark Law; the Role of the Average Consumer in Trademark Infringement between Two Confusingly Similar Trademarks’, in Lyngsie, Jacob, Mortensen, Bent O. G. and Østergaard, Kim eds., Rets- og Kontraktøkonomi: Law & Economics an Anthology (Djøf Publishing, 2016), 37, p. 51-53.

  57. 57.

    Examples of well-known e-commerce platforms are eBay and Amazon.com. Examples of the use of trademarks for online information search are search engines (like Google), user generated content (such as TripAdvisor, Trustpilot and PriceRunner).

  58. 58.

    On the rational actor model, see Chap. 6, Sects. 6.6.16.6.2.

  59. 59.

    Posner, Richard A., ‘Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law’, Stanford Law Review, vol. 50 (1997-1998), pp. 1551, p. 1559.

  60. 60.

    Ibid. On the behavioural man, see Chap. 6, Sect. 6.6.3 and the summarising discussion in Sect. 6.6.4.

  61. 61.

    Posner, Richard A., ‘Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law’, Stanford Law Review, vol. 50 (1997-1998), pp. 1551, p. 1559.

  62. 62.

    Towfigh, Emanuel V. and Petersen, Niels, ‘Economic Methods for Lawyers’, (1st edn, Edward Elgar, 2015), p. 18.

  63. 63.

    Corbin, Ruth M., ‘The Moron in a Hurry – a Creature of Law Or Science?’, in Archibald, Todd L. and Echlin, Randall Scott eds., Annual Review of Civil Litigation 2015 (1st edn, Carswell, 2015), 43, p. 56.

  64. 64.

    Ibid, p. 58-61.

  65. 65.

    Weatherall, Kimberlee, ‘The Consumer as the Empirical Measure of Trade Mark Law’, Modern Law Review, vol. 80/no. 1, (2017), pp. 57, p. 85-86. Weatherall seems to respond to Dinwoodie and Gangjee who also refer to similar “quick and dirty” approaches that could “have limited predictive value in the real world.” Dinwoodie, Graeme, and Gangjee, Dev, ‘The Image of the Consumer in EU Trade Mark Law’, in Leczykiewicz, Dorota, and Weatherill, Stephen eds., The Images of the Consumer in EU Law: Legislation, Free Movement and Competition Law (1st edn, Hart, 2016), 339, p. 365.

  66. 66.

    Weatherall, Kimberlee, ‘The Consumer as the Empirical Measure of Trade Mark Law’, Modern Law Review, vol. 80/no. 1, (2017), pp. 57, p. 85.

  67. 67.

    Paco Underhill, Why We Buy: The Science of Shopping: Updated and Revised for the Internet, the Global Consumer and Beyond (1st ed. 2009), p. 24.

  68. 68.

    Ibid, p. 25.

  69. 69.

    In 2009 Underhill stated that grocery studies had shown that 60-70 % of all grocery purchases in supermarkets were unplanned. Ibid, p. 105.

  70. 70.

    Thaler, Richard, ‘Toward a Positive Theory and Consumer Choice’, in Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos eds., Choices, Values, and Frames (1st edn, Cambridge University Press, 2000), 269, p. 269 (italics added). See Chap. 6, Sect. 6.6.3.

  71. 71.

    Besides the findings by Underhill, inspiration for this observation came, when the author of this book had an enlightening talk with marketing professor Lisa R. Szykman on this book project. Confronted with the trademark law’s focus on consumer confusion, Szykman intuitively responded that consumers in a retail setting do not reach the stage where they are confused (or likely to be) in the cognitive sense of the word. See also Chap. 6, Sect. 6.6.4.

  72. 72.

    On the principle, see Chap. 11, Sect. 11.1.

  73. 73.

    In Danish: “appellerer vel nærmest til smilet hos den dommer, der har varemærkerne liggende som henholdsvis bilag A og bilag B, og som naturligvis ikke kan undlade at lægge dem ved siden af hinanden. Har han imidlertid gjort det blot i den brøkdel af et sekund, som det tager at opfatte mærkerne, vil store dele af de procederende advokaters argumentation om ligheden eller forskelligheden mellem mærkerne prelle af på ham.” Koktvedgaard, Mogens, ‘Konkurrenceprægede Immaterialretspositioner: Bidrag til Læren om de Lovbestemte Enerettigheder og Deres Forhold til den Almene Konkurrenceret’, (1st edn, Juristforbundet, 1965), p. 179.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Laustsen, R.D. (2020). Putting the Average Consumer into Perspective. In: The Average Consumer in Confusion-based Disputes in European Trademark Law and Similar Fictions . Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-26350-8_12

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-26350-8_12

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-26349-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-26350-8

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics