Skip to main content

Are Losses from Natural Disasters More Than Just Asset Losses?

The Role of Capital Aggregation, Sector Interactions, and Investment Behaviors

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Advances in Spatial and Economic Modeling of Disaster Impacts

Part of the book series: Advances in Spatial Science ((ADVSPATIAL))

Abstract

The welfare impact of a natural disaster depends on its effect on consumption, not only on the direct asset losses and human losses that are usually estimated and reported after disasters. This chapter proposes a framework to assess disaster-related consumption losses, starting from an estimate of the asset losses, and leading to the following findings. First, output losses after a disaster destroys part of the capital stock are better estimated by using the average—not the marginal—productivity of capital. A model that describes capital in the economy as a single homogeneous stock would systematically underestimate disaster output losses, compared with a model that tracks capital in different sectors with limited reallocation options. Second, the net present value of disaster-caused consumption losses decreases when reconstruction is accelerated. With standard parameters, discounted consumption losses are only 10% larger than asset losses if reconstruction is completed in 1 year, compared with 50% if reconstruction takes 10 years. Third, for disasters of similar magnitude, consumption losses are expected to be lower where the productivity of capital is higher, such as in capital-scarce developing countries. This mechanism may partly compensate for the many other factors that make poor countries and poor people more vulnerable to disasters.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 149.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 199.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 199.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In many estimates of households’ disaster losses, one can find “asset losses” and “income losses” [see for instance Patankar and Patwardhan (2014)]. Howewer, it is often the case that “asset losses” represent the losses to the assets owned by the considered household and “income losses” represent the loss in income due to damages to other people’s (or public) assets. For instance, a household can lose its house (an asset loss) and be unable to work because its firm is damaged (a loss to the firm owner’s asset) or because transportation is impossible (a loss of public assets). In that case, no double counting is happening.

  2. 2.

    The analysis presented in this chapter builds on previous working papers by the authors (Hallegatte 2014; Hallegatte and Vogt-Schilb 2016).

  3. 3.

    Note that if the value of asset losses ΔK is defined as the discounted value of the lost production, then by definition the asset losses are equal to lost production. Here, we highlight the difference between the asset losses measured by their pre-disaster value and the lost production.

  4. 4.

    These ripple effects can even take place within a factory, if one segment of the production process is impossible and therefore interrupts the entire production.

  5. 5.

    In growth models, the impossibility to relocate capital can be represented by a non-negativity constraint on investments: investments in capital K1 cannot be negative, with the divestment used to consume or invest in K2; see an example in Rozenberg et al. (2018).

  6. 6.

    Other assets may exhibit negative externality, e.g. air pollution from a coal power plant.

  7. 7.

    One limitation of using only two variables is that we have to assume that the return on reconstruction is constant, which is obviously an oversimplification. One way to include priorities for reconstruction (more productive destroyed assets can be rebuilt before less productive destroyed assets), is to keep a disaggregated production function.

  8. 8.

    Specific instruments such as contingent credit lines help with reconstruction financing. See for instance on the World Bank’s Cat-DDO, http://treasury.worldbank.org/bdm/pdf/Handouts_Finance/CatDDO_Product_Note.pdf

  9. 9.

    One difficulty is the fact that an economy affected by a disaster may never return to its initial situation: some activities may disappear permanently, while new sectors may appear. Hurricanes in La Réunion, a French island off the coast of Madagascar, in 1806 and 1807 led to a shift from coffee to sugar cane production, for instance. Also, “good” reconstruction may improve the quality and resilience of infrastructure and productive capital (Benson and Clay 2004; Skidmore and Toya 2002). In this rule of thumb, however, we assess the cost of the disaster as the losses that occur if the economy returns to its initial state, leaving economic growth aside. A modeling exercise with an endogenous growth model (Hallegatte and Dumas 2009) suggests that introducing even an optimistic version of this effect would not change results dramatically. Moreover, even if there is no “return to the initial situation,” defining the “cost” as “the cost to return to the initial situation” provides a useful (and comparable) benchmark.

  10. 10.

    The reality is more complex than what has been described here because not all output losses are translated into consumption losses. In practice, the loss in output changes the terms of the inter-temporal investment-consumption trade-off and translates into ambiguous instantaneous changes in consumption and investment. But the main conclusions of the analysis are not affected by this complexity.

  11. 11.

    Conversely, if a disaster makes a large fraction of the population leave the city (such as Katrina in New Orleans) or if many jobs disappear as a result, then the cost of housing may decrease because of the shock. Changes in risk perceptions could also lead to a decrease in home values, as illustrated in Bin and Polasky (2004)).

References

  • Acemoglu D, Carvalho VM, Ozdaglar A, Tahbaz-Salehi A (2012) The network origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 80(5):1977–2016. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA9623

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albala-Bertrand JM (2013) Disasters and the networked economy. Routledge, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baqaee DR (2018) Cascading failures in production networks. Econometrica 86:1819–1838

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrot J-N, Sauvagnat J (2016) Input specificity and the propagation of idiosyncratic shocks in production networks. Q J Econ 131(3):1543–1592

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benson C, Clay EJ (2004) Understanding the economic and financial impacts of natural disasters. World Bank, Washington, DC

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bin O, Polasky S (2004) Effects of flood hazards on property values: evidence before and after Hurricane Floyd. Land Econ 80(4):490–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boehm C, Flaaen A, Pandalai-Nayar N (2019) Input linkages and the transmission of shocks: firm-level evidence from the 2011 Tōhoku earthquake. Rev Econ Stat 101:60–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen AJ (1989) Prices, capital, and the one-commodity model in neoclassical and classical theories. Hist Polit Econ 21(2):231–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen AJ, Harcourt GC (2003) Retrospectives: whatever happened to the Cambridge capital theory controversies? J Econ Perspect 17:199–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farhi E, Baqaee D (2017) The macroeconomic impact of microeconomic shocks: beyond Hulten’s Theorem. In: 2017 Meeting Papers. Society for Economic Dynamics

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon P, Richardson HW, Davis B (1998) Transport-related impacts of the Northridge earthquake. National Emergency Training Center

    Google Scholar 

  • Hallegatte S (2008) An adaptive regional input-output model and its application to the assessment of the economic cost of Katrina. Risk Anal 28(3):779–799

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallegatte S (2014) Economic resilience: definition and measurement. The World Bank, Washington, DC

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hallegatte S, Dumas P (2009) Can natural disasters have positive consequences? Investigating the role of embodied technical change. Ecol Econ 68(3):777–786

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallegatte S, Ghil M (2008) Natural disasters impacting a macroeconomic model with endogenous dynamics. Ecol Econ 68(1):582–592

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallegatte S, Vogt-Schilb A (2016) Are losses from natural disasters more than just asset losses? The role of capital aggregation, sector interactions, and investment behaviors

    Google Scholar 

  • Hallegatte S, Bangalore M, Vogt-Schilb A (2016) Socioeconomic resilience: multihazard assessments in 117 countries. World Bank Group, Washington, DC

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Haraguchi M, Lall U (2015) Flood risks and impacts: a case study of Thailand’s floods in 2011 and research questions for supply chain decision making. Int J Disaster Risk Reduct 14(December):256–272. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijdrr.2014.09.005

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henriet F, Hallegatte S, Tabourier L (2012) Firm-network characteristics and economic robustness to natural disasters. J Econ Dyn Control 36(1):150–167. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2011.10.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hornbeck R, Keniston D (2014) Creative destruction: barriers to urban growth and the great Boston fire of 1872. Working Paper 20467. National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber.org/papers/w20467

  • Hulten CR (1978) Growth accounting with intermediate inputs. Rev Econ Stud 45(3):511–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kroll CA, Landis JD, Shen Q, Stryker S (1991) Economic impacts of the Loma Prieta earthquake: a focus on small businesses. Berkeley Plann J 5(1). https://doi.org/10.5070/BP35113132

  • Lucas RE (1990) Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? Am Econ Rev 80(2):92–96

    Google Scholar 

  • McCarty C, Smith S (2005) Florida’s 2004 Hurricane season: local effects. Florida Focus, BEBR University of Florida 1

    Google Scholar 

  • Mechler R (2004) Natural disaster risk management and financing disaster losses in developing countries, vol 1. Verlag Versicherungswirtsch

    Google Scholar 

  • Okuyama Y (2003) Economics of natural disasters: a critical review. Research Paper 2003–12, Regional Research Institute, West Virginia University, USA

    Google Scholar 

  • Okuyama Y (2004) Modeling spatial economic impacts of an earthquake: input-output approaches. Disaster Prev Manag: Int J 13(4):297–306. https://doi.org/10.1108/09653560410556519

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patankar A, Patwardhan A (2014) Estimating the uninsured losses due to extreme weather events and implications for informal sector vulnerability: a case study of Mumbai, India. Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Rapp GC (2005) Gouging: terrorist attacks, hurricanes, and the legal and economic aspects of post-disaster price regulation. KY Law J 94:535–560

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson J (1974) History versus equilibrium. Thames Polytechnic, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose A, Wei D (2013) Estimating the economic consequences of a port shutdown: the special role of resilience. Econ Syst Res 25(2):212–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose A, Oladosu G, Liao S-Y (2007) Business interruption impacts of a terrorist attack on the electric power system of Los Angeles: customer resilience to a total blackout. Risk Anal 27(3):513–531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rozenberg J, Vogt-Schilb A, Hallegatte S (2018) Instrument choice and stranded assets in the transition to clean capital. J Environ Econ Manag, November. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2018.10.005

  • Skidmore M, Toya H (2002) Do natural disasters promote long-run growth? Econ Inq 40(4):664–687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stewart F, Fitzgerald EVK (2001) War and underdevelopment. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (1974) The Cambridge-Cambridge controversy in the theory of capital; a view from New Haven: a review article. J Polit Econ 82(4):893–903

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taschereau-Dumouchel M (2017) Cascades and fluctuations in an economy with an endogenous production network

    Google Scholar 

  • Tierney KJ (1997) Business impacts of the Northridge earthquake. J Conting Crisis Manag 5(2):87–97. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-5973.00040

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Todo Y, Nakajima K, Matous P (2015) How do supply chain networks affect the resilience of firms to natural disasters? Evidence from the Great East Japan earthquake. J Reg Sci 55(2):209–229. https://doi.org/10.1111/jors.12119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toya H, Skidmore M (2007) Economic development and the impacts of natural disasters. Econ Lett 94(1):20–25. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2006.06.020

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wai LC, Wongsurawat W (2013) Crisis management: western digital’s 46-day recovery from the 2011 flood disaster in Thailand. Strateg Leadersh 41(1):34–38

    Google Scholar 

  • West CT, Lenze DG (1994) Modeling the regional impact of natural disaster and recovery: a general framework and an application to Hurricane Andrew. Int Reg Sci Rev 17(2):121–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper is a background paper for the World Bank report “Unbreakable: Building the resilience of the poor in the face of natural disasters.” It benefited from comments and feedback from many people, including Jinqiang Chen and the participants to the ENGAGE workshop hosted by the Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research in Potsdam, Germany, on June 20–21, 2016.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stephane Hallegatte .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Price Impacts and the Cost of Reconstruction

Appendix: Price Impacts and the Cost of Reconstruction

The equality of asset value and output is valid only for marginal changes, i.e. for small shocks that do not affect the structure of the economy and the relative prices of different goods and services. The impact is different for large shocks. Such non-marginal shocks affect prices, while asset and output losses are often estimated assuming unchanged (pre-disaster) prices (e.g., assuming that if a house is destroyed, the family who owns the house can rent another house at the pre-disaster price). But this assumption is unrealistic if the disaster causes more than a small shock. In post-disaster situations, indeed, a significant fraction of houses may be destroyed, leading to changes in the relative price structure. In this case, the price of alternative housing can be much higher than the pre-disaster price, as a consequence of the disaster-related scarcity in the housing market.Footnote 11

For large shocks, estimating the value of lost output service should take into account the price change. Compared with an assessment based on the pre-disaster prices, it can lead to a significant increase in the assessed disaster cost.

Post-disaster price is especially sensible in the construction sector, which sees final demand soar after a disaster. For instance, Fig. 2.3 shows the large increase in wages for roofers and carpenters in two areas heavily affected by hurricane losses in Florida in 2004. This inflation affects the replacement cost of capital and is referred to as “demand surge” in the insurance industry.

Fig. 2.3
2 line graphs plot annualized wage change percentage in Miami and Fort Pierce versus months. 2 lines, roofers and all occupations show a decreasing trend till December 2004, then increase up to October 2005 before decreasing again. The maximum values are as follows. Miami. Roofers (December 2004, 18.00). All occupations (October 2005, 6.00). Fort Pierce. Carpenters (December 2004, 25.00). All occupations (December 2003, 5.50). All values are estimated.

Wages for qualified workers involved in the reconstruction process (roofer and carpenter), in two areas where losses have been significant after the 2004 hurricane season in Florida. Data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, Occupational Employment Surveys in May 03, Nov 03, May 04, Nov 04, May 05, May 06, May 07

Post-disaster price inflation is often considered as resulting from unethical behavior from businesses, justifying anti-gouging legislation (e.g., Rapp 2005). But it also has positive consequences by supporting the optimal allocation of the remaining capital (e.g., housing) and by incentivizing quick reconstruction. This inflation, indeed, helps attract qualified workers where they are most needed and creates an incentive for all workers to work longer hours, therefore compensating for damaged assets and accelerating reconstruction. It is likely, for instance, that higher prices after hurricane landfalls are useful to make roofers from neighboring unaffected regions move to the landfall region, therefore increasing the local production capacity and reducing the reconstruction duration. Demand surge, as a consequence, may also reduce the total economic cost of a disaster, even though it increases its financial burden on the affected population.

In extreme cases, or where price adjustment is constrained by ethical considerations or anti-gouging regulations, there may be rationing, i.e. the price cannot clear the market and supply is not equal to demand: there is no available house for rent at any price, there is no qualified worker to repair a roof. In these situations, even using the post-disaster price underestimates the losses.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Hallegatte, S., Vogt-Schilb, A. (2019). Are Losses from Natural Disasters More Than Just Asset Losses?. In: Okuyama, Y., Rose, A. (eds) Advances in Spatial and Economic Modeling of Disaster Impacts. Advances in Spatial Science. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-16237-5_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics