Skip to main content

The Homo Oeonomicus, Merchant Ethos, and Liberalism in Spain Under Enlightened Absolutism

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Honorable Merchant – Between Modesty and Risk-Taking

Part of the book series: Ethical Economy ((SEEP,volume 56))

  • 218 Accesses

Abstract

The following article deals with the formation of economic discourse in eighteenth century Spain. It argues that concepts such as common welfare or honorable businessman supported the establishment of economic thinking in the context of Bourbon Reformism – the predominant political current throughout the eighteenth century. A particular instance of this development are the Discursos mercuriales de Juan Enrique Graef: While Graef ran into serious trouble with censorship, he was also the first economic journalist and founder of the genre of economic press in Spain. With the introduction of liberal thought by Gaspar Melchor de Jovellanos and others, the concepts mentioned lost their prevalence, whereas the opposing notion of individual economic interest became an important reference point of economic thinking at the end of Enlightenment Spain.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Vogl (2012), p. 46. See also Vogl (2004), pp. 346–351.

  2. 2.

    Ibid.

  3. 3.

    Agamben (2013a).

  4. 4.

    It is revealing that Agamben (2013b) in his interview with the FAZ, which is frequently qualified, does not differentiate the conception of the economy, but rather allows it to exist as an antithesis of a culturally diverse and historically aware Europe: For more than two centuries, human energy has been focused on the economy. There are many indications that the moment has perhaps come for homo sapiens to reorganize human actions beyond this single dimension. It is precisely here that the Old Europe can make a decisive contribution to the future.”

  5. 5.

    On this point and the following, see Schoepp (2015).

  6. 6.

    Goytisolo (1979), p. 190.

  7. 7.

    In Américo Castro’s main work España en su historia (1938) the opening chapter contains a sketch of a tradition which can be described as non-economic. See specifically Castro (2001), p. 28, where a quote from Alonso Cartagena (1384–1456, Spanish humanist and Bishop of Burgos) is remarked on by Castro as follows: “El espíritu nobiliario unido al desdén por las actividades comerciales marcan ya el abismo que separará a España de la Europa capitalista: para este judío archiespañol, Cosme de Médicis no era sino un vil mercader.”

  8. 8.

    See Geisler (2013), p. 18f. Cf. the description of the economic development of Spain under Habsburg rule in Haebler (1888).

  9. 9.

    Cf. also the historical model in Hirschman (1980), in which, however, references to the Spanish cultural area are in short supply (cf. e.g. ibid., p. 67). See Max Weber ibid., p. 138. See also Pocock (1993), pp. 60–96.

  10. 10.

    Jovellanos (1987), p. 188. Predecessors here would not only be the Neo-Scholastics, but also the arbitristas, i.e. “project makers” of the seventeenth century, who have been wrongly forgotten, not least because of Quevedos satire in Buscón.

  11. 11.

    Vicens Vives (2 1974), p. 165.

  12. 12.

    See ibid., p. 164.

  13. 13.

    Elorza (1970), p. 34 (italics in the original).

  14. 14.

    Ibid.

  15. 15.

    Uztáriz (3 1757), p. 1.

  16. 16.

    Campillo y Cossío (1789, p. 68f).

  17. 17.

    Uztáriz (3 1757), from the prologue, not paginated. The reference to the Fall of Man is not uncommon in the tradition of Spanish economic treatises. It can be found in Tomás de Mercado, cf. Geisler (2013), p. 47.

  18. 18.

    Uztáriz (3 1757, p. 1).

  19. 19.

    See Thomas von Aquinas (1954): “sicut et corpus hominis et cuiuslibet animalis defluenet, nisi esset aliqua vis regitiva communis in corpore, quae ad bonum commune omnium membrorum intenderet.” The Spanish tradition will come back to this, e.g. Pedro Fernández de Navarrete in his text Conservación de monarquías y discursos políticos (1626), see Geisler (2014), p. 61.

  20. 20.

    See Once again Thomas (1954): “Nam unus homo per se sufficienter vitam transigere non posset. Est igitur homini naturale quod in societate multorum vivat.”

  21. 21.

    Mensching (2007), p. 83.

  22. 22.

    See Geisler (2013), p. 35.

  23. 23.

    Vogl (6 2012), p. 117. Following Geisler (2013), p. 32, it is undoubtedly worth remembering that the Aristotelian subsistence economy within the oikos was largely based on slave labor, which, for its part, was not subject to any appreciation or value creation. On the other hand, this ideology-critical view leaves out the form in which the Aristotelian distinction between regular economy and crematism is shaped by a cultural viewpoint, in which the anthropological primacy of the political community is inescapable and, moreover, is embedded in a specific form of the ancient cyclical conception of time (see Vogl, p. 122f.).

  24. 24.

    See Geisler (2013), p. 37.

  25. 25.

    See Geisler (2014), p. 62ff.

  26. 26.

    Weber (3 2010), p. 185.

  27. 27.

    Mercado (1977), not paginated [chapter VII]. See Geisler (2013), p. 45. According to this, Mercado’s significance lies in the renunciation of the scholastic doctrine of “fair price,” but above all in the knowledge that wealth is created by investing in goods. Mercado thus goes beyond the idea of a mere subsistence economy (cf. ibid.). In all this, it cannot be overlooked that Mercado’s entire treatise is permeated by the maxims of Christian natural law, which play a central role in his arguments.

  28. 28.

    See Geisler (2013), p. 53–70.

  29. 29.

    See Sánchez-Blanco (1990), Witthaus (2014), pp. 265–316.

  30. 30.

    Graef (1996), p. 191.

  31. 31.

    Ibid., p. 213.

  32. 32.

    See ibid., p. 206.

  33. 33.

    For a similar conception in Jacques Savary, see the contribution of Christoph Strosetzki in this volume.

  34. 34.

    For similar conceptions in France, see the work of Gipper (2002), especially with regard to Abbé Pluche: pp. 244–258.

  35. 35.

    Graef (1996), p. 191.

  36. 36.

    See Isidore of Seville (1911), not paginated: V, 4: “ut viri et feminae coniunctio, liberorum sucessio et educatio, communis omnium possessio, et omnium una libertas, adquisitio eorum quae caelo, terra, marique capiuntur.”

  37. 37.

    Graef (1996, p. 207). The skeptical use of the term “los intereses” may also be attributed to the traditional meaning of interés as monetary interest.

  38. 38.

    Ibid., P. 203f. (in italics in the text).

  39. 39.

    Ibid.

  40. 40.

    Ibid., p. 202.

  41. 41.

    See Machiavelli (1986), p. 136: “Non può, pertanto, uno signore prudente, né debbe, osservare la fede, quando tale osservianza li tornio contro e che sono spente le cagioni che la feciono promettere.”

  42. 42.

    Graef (1996), p. 205.

  43. 43.

    Ibid.

  44. 44.

    Recourse to the Jesuit Father Pedro de Ribadeneira. See Maravall (2001), p. 58.

  45. 45.

    See Heckscher (1932), Vol. 2, pp. 3–20.

  46. 46.

    On “policey in Spain, see Witthaus (2011), pp. 213–219.

  47. 47.

    The discussion concerning the true author of Nuevo sistema (see also Navarro García 1983), to which is linked a further discussion about the supposed plagiarism of the text by Bernado Ward in his Proyecto económico (the American part of Ward is largely identical to the Nuevo sistema) is rather enigmatic for our purposes. Incidentally, in my view the topic of the “policey” in Nuevo sistema suggests a later transcript, presumably at a time when Campillo was no longer alive. Therefore, there should be a lot of skepticism about whether Campillo is the real author of the Nuevo sistema.

  48. 48.

    See Bernecker (2002), p. 88f.

  49. 49.

    Campillo y Cossío (1789), S. 3.

  50. 50.

    See Campillo y Cossío (1789), p. 89–93. In Ward (1779), p. 257, this section – again, whose wording is almost identical – is entitled “Sobre los Indios.”

  51. 51.

    Ibid., p. 131.

  52. 52.

    Ibid., p. 134f.

  53. 53.

    Hirschman (1980), p. 20 and passim.

  54. 54.

    It thus seems apparent that an investigation of the discourses on affects and interests within the framework of the policey is still missing.

  55. 55.

    Campillo y Cossío (1789), p. 150.

  56. 56.

    In reference to the scientific-political domain of the Bourbons, see Lafuente and Peset (1988), pp. 29–79.

  57. 57.

    See Cladera (1787), pp. 458–461, 475–479. For a comparison to the French original, see Lüsebrink and Mussard (1994), pp. 71–95.

  58. 58.

    Cladera (1788), p. 865.

  59. 59.

    See Elorza (1970), p. 131f.

  60. 60.

    Locke, however, derives these rights from the Decalogue, which in turn has a natural relationship to human reason. See Waldron (2002), p. 97.

  61. 61.

    Foronda is cited from the original source in Espíritu: Cladera (1788), p. 593.

  62. 62.

    Ibid. See 2. Corinthians 3:3.

  63. 63.

    See ibid., p. 565.

  64. 64.

    Ibid., p. 593f.

  65. 65.

    See Jovellanos (2 1998), p. 235.

  66. 66.

    Particularly if one compares this with a detailed examination of economic historical events from the third book of Wealth of Nations.

  67. 67.

    Ibid., p. 243. It is possible that Jovellanos is responding here to Rousseau, where in the second discourse the self-preservation instinct qua amour de soi plays a central role in the state of nature, even though the civilizational process is viewed critically and as existing under the banner of self-love, amour-propre.

  68. 68.

    Ibid., p. 244f.

  69. 69.

    Ibid., p. 245.

  70. 70.

    Even if the architecture of this article – raison d’etat, policey, liberalism – is owed to the sequence of government models in Foucault (2004), in the last section the peculiarity of the Spanish development should nevertheless be more strongly outlined.

  71. 71.

    See Urban (2014).

Bibliography

  • Agamben, Giorgio. 2013a. Que l’Empire latin contre-attaque! Libération. http://www.liberation.fr/monde/2013/03/24/que-l-empire-latin-contre-attaque_890916. Accessed: 18 Sept 2015.

  • ———. 2013b. Die endlose Krise ist ein Machtinstrument. http://www.faz.net/aktuell/feuilleton/bilder-und-zeiten/giorgio-agamben-im-gespraech-die-endlose-krise-ist-ein-machtinstrument-12193816.html. Zugegriffen: 18 Sept 2015.

  • Bernecker, Walther. 2002. Spanische Geschichte. Von der Reconquista bis heute. Darmstadt: Primus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castro, Américo. 2001. España en su historia: christianos, moros y judios. Barcelona: Crítica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cladera, Cristóbal. 1787. Espíritu de los mejores diarios literarios que se publican en Europa, Nr. 47, 48. Madrid: Espinosa.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1788. Espíritu de los mejores diarios literarios que se publican en Europa, Nr. 96, 155. Madrid: Espinosa.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Campillo y Cossío, José. 1789. Nuevo sistema moderno de gobierno para la América. Madrid: Benito Cano.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Jovellanos, Gaspar Melchor. 41987. Obras en prosa, ed. José Caso González. Madrid: Castalia.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 21998. Espectáculos y diversiones públicas; Informe sobre la Ley Agraria. Guillermo Carnero. Madrid: Cátedra.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Mercado, Tomás. 1977. Suma de tratos y contratos, ed. Nicolás Sánchez-Albornoz. http://www.cervantesvirtual.com/obra-visor-din/suma-de-tratos-y-contratos%2D%2D0/html/. Zugegriffen: 07 Oct 2015.

  • de Uztáriz, Gerónimo. 31757. Theorica, y practica de comercio y de marina. Madrid: Antonio Sanz.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elorza, Antonio. 1970. La ideología liberal en la Ilustración española. Madrid: Tecnos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foucault, Michel. 2004. Sécurité, Territoire, Population. Cours au Collège de France. 1977–1978. Paris: Gallimard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geisler, Eberhard. 2013. El dinero en la obra de Quevedo. La crisis de identidad en la sociedad feudal española a principios del siglo XVII. Kassel: Edition Reichenberger.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2014. Reziprozität und Gabe im spanischen Theater des Siglo de Oro. In Handel, Handlung, Verhandlung. Theater und Ökonomie in der Frühen Neuzeit in Spanien, ed. Beatrice Schuchardt und Urs Urban, 59–93. Bielefeld: Transcript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gipper, Andreas. 2002. Wunderbare Wissenschaft. In Literarische Strategien naturwissenschaftlicher Vulgarisierung in Frankreich. München: Fink.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goytisolo, Juan. 1979. España y los españoles. Barcelona: Lumen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graef, Juan Enrique. 1996. Discursos mercuriales, ed. Francisco Sánchez-Blanco. Sevilla: Fundación el Monte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haebler, Konrad. 1888. Die wirtschaftliche Blüte Spaniens im 16. Jahrhundert und ihr Verfall. Berlin: Gaertners.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckscher, Eli. 1932: Der Merkantilismus, 2 Vols. Jena: Gustav Fischer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, Albert O. 1980. Leidenschaften und Interessen. Politische Begründungen des Kapitalismus vor seinem Sieg, Autorisierte Übersetzung von Sabine Offe. Frankfurt a. Main: Suhrkamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lafuente, Antonio, und José Luis Peset, eds. 1988. Carlos III y la ciencia de la Ilustración. Madrid: Alianza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lüsebrink, Hans-Jürgen, and Alexandre Mussard, eds. 1994. Avantages et désavantages de la découverte de l’Amérique: Chastellux, Raynal et le concours de l’Académie de Lyon. Saint Étienne: Université de Saint-Étienne.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machiavelli, Niccolò. 1986. In Il Principe. Der Fürst, ed. Philipp Rippel. Stuttgart: Reclam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maravall, José Antonio. 32001. Maquiavelo y maquiavelismo en España. Estudios de historia del pensamiento español. José Antonio Maravall, 41–66. 3. Madrid: Ediciones Cultura Hispánica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mensching, Günther. 2007. Thomas von Aquin. Über die Herrschaft des Fürsten. In Geschichte des politischen Denkens. Ein Handbuch, ed. Manfred Brocker, 78–92. Frankfurt a. Main: Suhrkamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Navarro García, Luis. 1983. Campillo y el Nuevo Sistema: Una atribución dudosa. Temas Americanistas 2: 67–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pocock, John G.A. 1993. Die andere Bürgergesellschaft. Zur Dialektik von Tugend und Korruption. Frankfurt a. Main/New York: Campus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez-Blanco, Francisco. 1990. Los Discursos Mercuriales (1752–1756) de Juan Enrique Graef: Opinión y poder en el movimiento ilustrado español. Estudios de Historia Social 52 (53): 477–489.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schoepp, Sebastian. 2015. Mediterraner Kapitalismus. http://sebastian-schoepp.blogspot.de/. Zugegriffen: 18 Sept 2015.

  • Urban, Urs. 2014. Tausch und Täuschung. Performative Kompetenz als Grundlage ökonomisch erfolgreichen Handelns im spanischen Pikaro-Roman. In Handel, Handlung, Verhandlung. Theater und Ökonomie in der Frühen Neuzeit in Spanien, ed. Beatrice Schuchardt, und Urs Urban, 161–177. Bielefeld: Transcript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vicens Vives, Jaume. 21974. Historia de España y América social y económica. Vicens-bolsillo. Vol. 4. Barcelona. (Los Borbones. El siglo XVIII en España y América).

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogl, Joseph. 2004. Kalkül und Leidenschaft. Poetik des ökonomischen Menschen. Zürich: Diaphanes.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 62012. Das Gespenst des Kapitals. Zürich: Diaphanes.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Aquin, Thomas. 1954. De regno ad regem Cypri [Textum Taurini 1954 editum]. http://www.corpusthomisticum.org/orp.html. Accessed 5 Oct 2015.

  • von Sevilla, Isidor. 1911. Etymologiarvm sive originvm, ed. Wallace M. Lindsay, Vol. 1. Oxford: Univsersity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Tschilschke, Christian. 2013. Der spanische Patient. Krisendiagnose, Reformdiskurse und Projektemacherei im spanischen 18. century. In Die Krise als Erzählung. Transdisziplinäre Perspektiven auf ein Narrativ der Moderne, ed. Uta Fenske, Walburga Hülk, und Gregor Schuhen, 169–187. Bielefeld: Transcript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Waldron, Jeremy. 2002. God, locke, and equality: Christian foundations in Locke’s political thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ward, Bernardo. 21779. Proyecto económico. Madrid: Ibarra.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, Max. 32010. Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus. Vollständige Ausgabe Dirk Kaesler. München: Beck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Witthaus, Jan-Henrik. 2011. Reform der Moral im Zeichen sozialer Mimesis. Überlegungen zu Politik und Policey in der Moralischen Wochenschrift El Censor. In Die Spectators in der Romania – eine transkulturelle Gattung? ed. Klaus-Dieter Ertler, 195–216. Frankfurt a. Main: Peter Lang.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2014. Sozialisation der Kritik im Spanien des aufgeklärten Absolutismus. Von Feijoo bis Jovellanos. Frankfurt a. Main: Klostermann.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jan-Henrik Witthaus .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Witthaus, JH. (2019). The Homo Oeonomicus, Merchant Ethos, and Liberalism in Spain Under Enlightened Absolutism. In: Lütge, C., Strosetzki, C. (eds) The Honorable Merchant – Between Modesty and Risk-Taking. Ethical Economy, vol 56. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-04351-3_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics