Skip to main content

Electricity Market Integration and the Impact of Unilateral Policy Reforms

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The European Dimension of Germany’s Energy Transition
  • 1101 Accesses

Abstract

We investigate the impact that two German energy reforms—phase-out of nuclear power plants after the Fukushima incident and expansion of renewables due to fixed feed-in tariffs—had on neighbouring countries’ consumers. The unilateral German reforms generated substantial negative and positive impacts, respectively, in neighbouring countries with the highest overall effect of German policy found in France, not Germany; an annual negative impact on consumers of 3.15 billion €. We also find significant differences in market integration between neighbouring countries by calculating ratios between the estimated policy decisions’ impacts before and after controlling for interconnector congestion.

Our vision is of an integrated continent-wide energy system where energy flows freely across borders, based on competition and the best possible use of resources, and with effective regulation of energy markets at EU level where necessary.

European Commission (2015), A Framework Strategy for a Resilient Energy Union with a Forward-Looking Climate Change Policy, Brussels (Communication from the European Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee, the Committee of Regions and the European Investment Bank. A Framework Strategy for a Resilient Energy Union with a Forward-Looking Climate Change Policy. COM (2015) 80 final, February 2015, p. 2.).

The article is a reprint of Grossi, Luigi, Sven Heim, Kai Hüschelrath and Michael Waterson (2018), Electricity Market Integration and the Impact of Unilateral Policy Reforms, Oxford Economic Papers 70 (3), 799–820. This paper was previously published under the terms of the “Creative Commons CC BY license”.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See, e.g., De Jong et al. (2007) and Kristiansen (2007a, b).

  2. 2.

    See, e.g., Pollitt (2009a, b, 2012).

  3. 3.

    Other contributions include Leuthold et al. (2005), Green (2007) and Pellini (2014).

  4. 4.

    Using a dummy variable approach, Grossi et al. (2017) investigate the impact of the phase-out on the German market itself. They find prices in Germany have increased—most significantly in hours of low demand (caused by a shift in the merit order), with only a small price increase in hours of high demand, (caused by increased market power). Davis and Hausman (2016), a related exercise with some parallels, finds comparable price effects of an unexpected nuclear power plant closure in California. Using a semi-parametric regression approach to identify the marginal generation unit each time-period before and after the event, they find the closure created binding transmission constraints, causing short-run inefficiencies and potentially making it more profitable for certain plants to act non-competitively.

  5. 5.

    In 2014, the EEG surcharge was 6.24 ct/kWh. However, energy intensive industries are widely exempted from paying the surcharge.

  6. 6.

    Capacity in these areas has been growing rapidly, boosted by EEG support. According to the German Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy (2014), in late 2011, wind capacity reached almost 30 GW with photovoltaic power capacity at about 25 GW (out of a total system listed capacity of 175 GW). In sum, in the year 2011, more capacity had been added through renewables (wind: 1.9 GW; solar: 7.5 GW) than had been removed by the nuclear phase-out.

  7. 7.

    It should be noted that we control for the simultaneous generation from renewables in the neighbouring countries in all regressions and thus capture parallel developments therein.

  8. 8.

    We are grateful to an anonymous reviewer for suggesting a discussion in light of (strategic) trade theory.

  9. 9.

    Specifically, while producers in the trading partners’ countries are expected to increase profits due to less cheap nuclear plants in Germany, the respective consumers are likely to face reductions in consumer surplus due to higher market prices.

  10. 10.

    German and Austrian markets are fully integrated and therefore considered as a single market. Although Germany and Belgium are neighbouring countries, they currently are connected only through loop flows. However, according to Jauréguy-Naudin (2012), the TSOs of the two countries were considering the construction of an HVDC line with a capacity of 1000 MW. Furthermore, the existing (small) interconnector between Germany and Sweden is excluded due to data unavailability. Spain’s interconnector with France is very limited.

  11. 11.

    To avoid problems of quadratic transformation, the temperature indices are converted into degrees Fahrenheit, which always take positive values within our data. Source: Authors’ calculations.

  12. 12.

    Dickey-Fuller and Phillips-Perron tests clearly reject the null hypothesis of a unit root in the underlying price and load series; test statistics reported in Table A.2 in the online Appendix.

  13. 13.

    Unfortunately, we do not observe Scandinavian reservoir levels which would also be relevant, in particular we would expect them to have an effect on electricity prices in Denmark. Nordpool publishes such data but only since 2015.

  14. 14.

    We define congestion as the existence of a price difference between Germany and a certain neighbour in a certain hour.

  15. 15.

    In our empirical analysis below, we exclude such cases by assuming a state of congestion only as soon as the price difference exceeds 1 €/MWh. Our results are found to be also robust to price differences of 1%, 5% and 10% or 0 €/MWh.

  16. 16.

    See Table A.1 in the online Appendix.

  17. 17.

    While most countries use some form of feed-in tariff, some decided to introduce quota obligations, tenders, exemption from energy taxes or instruments as part of which a fraction of the revenue of general energy taxes finance renewable energy sources. See Ragwitz et al. (2012) for a detailed comparison of European renewable support schemes.

  18. 18.

    Although demand is often considered as perfectly inelastic, recent demand-side management activities aim at reacting to price signals and therefore question the assumption of perfectly inelastic demand. The Durbin-Wu-Hausman test for endogeneity will support this view later.

  19. 19.

    Temperature can be thought as an instrument because hotter temperatures increase electricity demand through the need for cooling, while colder temperatures require more electricity for heating purposes. The squared term captures a possible nonlinear relation.

  20. 20.

    The full set of regression tables is available in Tables A.4–A.11 of the Supplementary Materials.

  21. 21.

    The only, minor, exception is Poland.

  22. 22.

    The computed integration indices are surprisingly similar to the price correlations reported in Table A.1 in the online Appendix.

  23. 23.

    The coefficient measures the correlation between values in the first and the second row of Table 4.

  24. 24.

    The huge difference in terms of market integration across countries—for instance between Poland and the Czech Republic—might be surprising against the background of similar mean prices for Poland and the Czech Republic. However, the mean price similarity is rather coincidental as can be seen in Figure A.1 in the online Appendix.

  25. 25.

    In discussing the results, where we write of “consumers” we mean both domestic and industrial consumers, unless we qualify the word. Of note, the costs for German consumers are even higher than computed in Table 5 as German consumers also have to pay a so called “Renewable Energy Surcharge” (in German: EEG-Umlage).

  26. 26.

    The slight differences in the estimates for Germany found here compared to those reported in Grossi et al. (2017)—focusing on Germany only—result from several differences in the data set and the estimation method. First, data availability issues constrain us here to the observation period from 2010 to 2012, while Grossi et al. (2017) include the year 2009 in their analysis. Second, our estimations here are run on daily data while Grossi et al. (2017) go down to hourly level. Third, we were unable to include river-related control variables here as they were not consistently available for all countries. Fourth, we instrument for cross-border congestion while Grossi et al. (2017) argue it is exogenous in the case of Germany. Last, the estimation approach followed here is system-wide GMM including all neighbouring countries while Grossi et al. (2017) estimate the effects for Germany in isolation.

  27. 27.

    We treat Germany and Austria as separate markets here (with an average actual hourly load of 54.85 GWh for Germany and 7.46 GWh for Austria in our observation period).

  28. 28.

    Figure A.2 in the online Appendix illustrates the different load patterns for Germany/Austria and France.

  29. 29.

    Technically, we measure industry benefits from renewables in Germany here because German customers have to pay the costs resulting from the difference between the fixed feed-in tariffs for renewables and the wholesale price, the so-called EEG surcharge, as a part of their electricity bills. Industry, by contrast, is mainly exempted from paying the EEG surcharge.

  30. 30.

    Analogously, unilateral policy reforms made in a small country likely will have no impact, even in the implementing country.

References

  • Antweiler, W. (2016). Cross-border trade in electricity. Journal of International Economics, 101, 42–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baritaud, M., & Volk, D. (2014). Seamless power markets: Regional integration of electricity markets in IEA member countries. OECD/IEA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berk, I., & Yetkiner, H. (2014). Energy prices and economic growth: Theory and evidence in the long run. Renewable & Sustainable Energy Reviews, 36, 228–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Powell, J. (2004). Endogeneity in semiparametric binary response models. Review of Economic Studies, 71, 581–913.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Böckers, V., & Heimeshoff, U. (2014). The extent of European power markets. Energy Economics, 46, 102–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booz & Company, Newbery, D., Strbac, G., Pudjianto, D., Noel, P., & LeighFisher. (2013). Benefits of an integrated European energy market. Final Report prepared for European Commission (Directorate-General Energy), Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borenstein, S. (2012). The private and public economics of renewable electricity generation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26, 67–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J., & Spencer, B. (1985). Export subsidies and market share rivalry. Journal of International Economics, 18, 83–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, M., Peichl, A., Pestel, N., & Siegloch, S. (2014). Labor demand effects of rising electricity prices: Evidence for Germany. Energy Policy, 75, 266–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, L., & Hausman, C. (2016). Market impacts of a nuclear power plant closure. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 8, 92–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Jong, H., Hakvoort, R., & Sharma, M. (2007). Effects of flow-based market coupling for the CWE region. In Proceedings of the 4th European Congress Economics and Management of Energy in Industry, pp. 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Menezes, L. M., & Houllier, M. A. (2015). Germany’s nuclear power plant closures and the integration of electricity markets in Europe. Energy Policy, 85, 357–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domanico, F. (2007). Concentration in the European electricity industry: The internal market as solution? Energy Policy, 35, 5064–5076.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2015). Energy Union Package, communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council, achieving the 10% electricity interconnection target, making Europe’s electricity grid fit for 2020, COM(2015) 82 final, Brussels.

    Google Scholar 

  • German Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy. (2014). Stromerzeugungskapazitäten, Bruttostromerzeugung, Energiedaten und Bruttostromverbrauch, Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, R. (2007). Nodal pricing of electricity: How much does it cost to get it wrong? Journal of Regulatory Economics, 31, 125–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossi, L., Heim, S., & Waterson, M. (2017). The impact of the German response to the Fukushima Earthquake. Energy Economics, 66, 450–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J. (1983). Oil and macroeconomy since world war II. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 228–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hardle, W., & Mammen, E. (1993). Comparing nonparametric versus parametric regression fits. Annals of Statistics, 21, 1926–1947.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Imbens, G., & Wooldridge, J. (2009). Recent developments in the econometrics of program evaluation. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 5–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jauréguy-Naudin, M. (2012). The European power system – Decarbonization and cost reduction: Lost in transmissions? In Note de l’Ifri. Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P. (2011). Comparing the costs of intermittent and dispatchable electricity generating technologies. American Economic Review, 101, 238–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilian, L. (2008). The economic effects of energy price shocks. Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 871–909.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knopf, B., Pahle, M., Kondziella, H., Joas, F., Edenhofer, O., & Bruckner, T. (2014). Germany’s nuclear phase-out: Sensitivities and impacts on electricity prices and CO2 emissions. Economics of Energy & Environmental Policy, 3, 89–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kristiansen, T. (2007a). A preliminary assessment of the market coupling arrangement on the kontek cable. Energy Policy, 35, 3247–3255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kristiansen, T. (2007b). An assessment of the Danish–German cross-border auctions. Energy Policy, 35, 3369–3382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P., Obstfeld, M., & Melitz, M. (2014). International economics: Theory and policy (10th ed.). Harlow: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leuthold, F., Rumiantseva, I., Weigt, H., Jeske, T., & von Hirschhausen, C. (2005). Nodal pricing in the German electricity sector – A welfare economics analysis, with particular reference to implementing offshore wind capacities. Working Paper WP-EM-08a, Dresden University of Technology, Chair for Energy Economics and Public Sector Management.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel, A. (2012). Using heteroscedasticity to identify and estimate mismeasured and endogenous regressor models. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 30, 67–80.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Mjelde, J., & Bessler, D. (2009). Market integration among electricity markets and their major fuel source markets. Energy Economics, 31, 482–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mork, K. (1989). Oil and the macroeconomy when prices go up and down: An extension of Hamilton’s results. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 740–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neuhoff, K., Barquin, J., Bialek, J., Boyd, R., Dent, C., Echavarren, F., Grau, T., von Hirschhausen, C., Hobbs, B., Kunz, F., Nabe, C., Papaefthymiou, G., Weber, C., & Weigt, H. (2013). Renewable electric energy integration: Quantifying the value of design of markets for international transmission capacity. Energy Economics, 40, 760–772.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newbery, D., Strbac, G., & Viehoff, I. (2015). The benefits of integrating European electricity markets. EPRG Working Paper 1504, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nitsche, R., Ockenfels, A., Röller, L. H., & Wiethaus, L. (2010). The electricity wholesale sector: Market integration and competition. ESMT White Paper WP-110-01, Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oseni, M. O., & Pollitt, M. G. (2014). Institutional arrangements for the promotion of regional integration of electricity markets. World Bank Development Research Group, Policy Research Working Paper 6947.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pellini, E. (2014). Essays on European electricity market integration. PhD Thesis, Surrey Energy Economics Centre, Guildford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollitt, M. (2009a). Evaluating the evidence on electricity reform: Lessons for the South East Europe (SEE) market. Utilities Policy, 17, 13–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollitt, M. (2009b). Electricity liberalisation in the European union: A progress report. Electricity Policy Research Group Working Paper No. 0929, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollitt, M. (2012). The role of policy in energy transitions: Lessons from the energy liberalisation era. Energy Policy, 50, 128–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puka, L., & Szulecki, K. (2014). Beyond the “Grid-Lock” in electricity interconnectors, DIW Discussion Paper 1378, Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ragwitz, M., Winkler, J., Klessmann, C., Gephart, M., & Resch, G. (2012). Recent developments of feed-in systems in the EU – A research paper for the International Feed-In Cooperation, Report Commissioned by the Ministry for the Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety, Karlsruhe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, P. (1988). Root-n-consistent semiparametric regression. Econometrica, 56, 931–954.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, T. (2007). The convergence of electricity prices in Europe. Applied Economics Letters, 14, 473–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serralles, R. (2006). Electric energy restructuring in the European union: Integration, subsidiarity and the challenge of harmonization. Energy Policy, 34, 2542–2551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zachmann, G. (2008). Electricity wholesale market prices in Europe: Convergence? Energy Economics, 30, 1659–1671.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Ulrich Laitenberger, Philipp Schmidt-Dengler, Frank Wolak, Oliver Woll, the editor James Forder and two anonymous referees for helpful remarks and Bastian Sattelberger for excellent research assistance. The paper has benefited from presentation at the 2015 CRESSE conference.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sven Heim .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Ethics declarations

Supplementary Material

Supplementary material is available online at the OUP website. This comprises an online Appendix and the data replication files. The data used in the paper are bought from commercial providers and are not publicly available. Independent researchers, however, can be given access to the data required to run the do-file at ZEW subject to the signing of a data usage contract. The usage contract allows independent researchers to access the data, but not to take the data set away from ZEW.

Funding

This work was supported in part by the Engineering and Physical Sciences Research Council of the UK under grant number EP/K002228 to MW. We benefited from the facilities of ZEW in producing the paper.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Grossi, L., Heim, S., Hüschelrath, K., Waterson, M. (2019). Electricity Market Integration and the Impact of Unilateral Policy Reforms. In: Gawel, E., Strunz, S., Lehmann, P., Purkus, A. (eds) The European Dimension of Germany’s Energy Transition. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-03374-3_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-03374-3_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-03373-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-03374-3

  • eBook Packages: EnergyEnergy (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics