Skip to main content

Pensions

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Public Economics

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 1639 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter, we first review empirical facts of public pension systems in OECD countries. Subsequently, we introduce a public pension system in the standard two-period overlapping generations (OLG) model of Chap. 2. We consider two different social security systems, pay-as-you-go (PAYG) versus fully funded. While a fully funded pension system does not have any effect on aggregate savings if capital markets are perfect, aggregate savings fall significantly in a PAYG system. Since public pensions are likely to distort household labor supply decisions, we endogenize labor supply below. In addition, we extend the two-period model to a more realistic 70-period model in which the retirement period is smaller than the working period. Next, we derive the optimal amount of pensions in a PAYG system and study how the demographic transition and aging of the population affect the sustainability of social security. We also discuss the findings of the literature on quantitative pension studies in detail. Finally, we introduce the concept of fiscal space and point out its sensitivity with respect to the aging that takes place in many industrialized countries at present.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In the United Kingdom, the modern pension system was introduced in 1908 with the help of the Old Age Pensions Act. The United States initially only provided pensions for federal employees under the Civil Service Retirement System in 1920.

  2. 2.

    In 1916, the retirement age was reduced to 65 years.

  3. 3.

    Sometimes, the working age is defined over a larger age range, e.g., 15–64, 20–64, or 20–69 years. Accordingly, take care when comparing old-age dependency ratios from different sources.

  4. 4.

    In this book, we will sometimes distinguish the two old-age dependency ratios OADR2 and OADR3, which refer to the retirees aged 65 (and above) and those aged 70 (and above). While we primarily use OADR2 as our reference value, it may sometimes be important to consider the evolution of OADR3, e.g., when we study pension policies that extend the retirement age to 70 years.

  5. 5.

    The data are taken from the UN population division and refer to the medium-fertility variant. See Appendix 6.3 for a more detailed description of the data.

  6. 6.

    Thanks to Hana Ševčíková for providing the data on dependency ratio forecasts in the United States and the EU14 countries.

  7. 7.

    For the US economy in the year 2050, standard empirical distribution tests such as the Lilliefors, Cramer-von Mises, Anderson-Darling, and Watson tests reject the normality assumption of the OADR2 distribution at the 1% or 5% level of significance. This observation does not hold uniquely for all countries in our data sample (the US and 14 EU-countries).

  8. 8.

    An excellent non-technical survey of pension designs to meet the demographic challenge is provided by Barr and Diamond (2008).

  9. 9.

    There are many other public policies that may help to alleviate the pressure on public pension systems during the demographic transition that we do not study in here. Among others, the government could attempt to increase the labor force participation rate, encourage higher immigration (of young individuals), or to use family policies to increase the fertility rate.

  10. 10.

    However, in recent years, as the baby boomers have begun to retire, many countries have also started to reduce pension benefits, e.g., Italy in 1995 through the Dini reform.

  11. 11.

    In Germany, the contribution was evenly split between the employer and employee in 2013. Each side pays a contribution rate of 9.45%. In a Walrasian labor market, the legal incidence, i.e., who pays the contribution rate, does not affect the economic incidence, i.e., who actually bears the burden of the tax. If, however, the labor market is subject to a distortion such as a minimum gross wage, the legal incidence does affect the economic incidence.

  12. 12.

    Börsch-Sopan and Winter (2001) estimate that the pension payments in Germany will increase from 10.0% of GDP in 1995 to 18.4% of GDP in 2030. To finance these higher expenditures resulting from an aging population, the contribution rate will have to increase to 41.1% by 2030.

  13. 13.

    The authors study a variety of pension reform proposals for the US economy in a general equilibrium model with labor-augmenting technical progress, endogenous bequests, and endogenous labor supply similar to the model we will study in this chapter. They consider different scenarios for the reform of the public pension system. The number reported in the text above corresponds to their experiment 1.

  14. 14.

    There are other institutional details of the German social insurance system that we will neglect in the following, e.g., there is a social security contribution ceiling, meaning that, in 2013, contributions were only paid on a gross annual income up to an amount of €69.600 (West Germany) or €58.800 (East Germany). In addition, the number of contribution years enters the formula used to compute the pensions. For further details on the German pension system, see Fehr (1999).

  15. 15.

    In Switzerland, for example, the fully funded pension system is part of a three-part pension system. The other two parts are a mandatory PAYG public pension and an employer-based pension.

  16. 16.

    From the theory of finance, we know that it is optimal to diversify risk, which implies that pension systems should combine the two different systems as is done, for example, in the three-part public pension system in Switzerland.

  17. 17.

    All payments are made at the end of the period.

  18. 18.

    As one exception, the first pillar of the Swiss pension system is also financed by sources other than wage income, e.g., by a levy on the income of the self-employed.

  19. 19.

    This argument is taken from Chapter 3.2 in Blanchard and Fischer (1989).

  20. 20.

    Recall that \((1+r)s_t = c^2_{t+1}-(1+n)d\).

  21. 21.

    This effect is absent in the derivation of (6.15) where we only consider an unexpected change of d t and d t+1 on the savings of the generation born in period t. Since the capital stock k t is predetermined, the wage w t does not change for the present (working) generation, but only for future generations.

  22. 22.

    The intuition for this result given in Sect. 3.2.5 was that increasing the capital stock results in lower interest rates r and, with s r > 0, in lower savings s, such that capital cannot grow without bound.

  23. 23.

    See Appendix 4.2 for the derivation of the Frisch labor supply elasticity in the case of a Cobb-Douglas utility function.

  24. 24.

    See also Sect. 4.4.5 for a discussion of the empirical evidence on ν 1.

  25. 25.

    You should attempt to compute these values. In the computation, we set ν 0 = 257.15 as implied by the calibration in the case of elastic labor supply (see the following section).

  26. 26.

    As an alternative measure of the welfare change, some authors use output equivalent change. In this case, Δ is computed as the percentage of output by which the consumption levels in the old steady state need to be raised to obtain the same utility as in the new steady state.

  27. 27.

    We will consider the effects of a gradual policy change in Sect. 6.4.3.

  28. 28.

    To derive the elasticity, simply take the logarithm on both sides of (6.27c) implying

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \ln l_t = \nu_1 \left[ \ln \left((1-\tau) w_t\right) + \ln \lambda_t -\ln \nu_0\right] \end{aligned}$$

    and notice that

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \ln l_t}{\partial \ln \left((1-\tau) w_t \right)} = \frac{\partial l_t}{\partial \left( (1-\tau) w_t\right)} \frac{(1-\tau) w_t}{l_t} = \nu_1.\end{aligned}$$
  29. 29.

    More specifically, we need to solve (6.21a) for w 0 and w 1 in periods 0 and 1, (6.21b) for r 1 in period 1, and (6.28) and (6.30) in period 0.

  30. 30.

    See also Appendix 4.1.

  31. 31.

    The algorithm used in our program is also very sensitive to the number of transition periods. In particular, for a larger number of transition periods, the solution does not converge.

  32. 32.

    Of course, we are quite idealistic in assuming that the individual is able to determine the parameters ρ pen and pen min. Usually, the pension is a complicated function of contributions and the number of contribution years. In Germany, for example, years of university eduction increase your pension despite that students do not contribute to the PAYG system.

  33. 33.

    In steady state, output and capital both grow at the rate γ. The US growth rate of real GDP per capita amounted to 2.00% during the period 1960–2011.

  34. 34.

    The results are computed with the help of the GAUSS program Ch6_social_security4.g, which solves the non-linear system of equations (6.43) with the Gauss-Newton Algorithm. In addition, we recalibrate ν 0 such that, for τ = 0 and γ = 80%, the steady-state labor supply is equal to l = 0.30.

  35. 35.

    The data for the US economy are taken from Hansen (1993). The efficiency profile for Germany is computed with the help of the average hourly wages of s-year-olds during the period 1990–1997 following the method of Hansen (1993). Average productivity is normalized to one. We further interpolated the productivity-age profile with a polynomial function of order 3. We used data from the Cross National Data Files for West Germany during the period 1990–1997, which are extracted from the German Socio Economic Panel, GSOEP.

  36. 36.

    The consideration of the highest income households would not significantly affect our welfare results on optimal social security. The welfare effect of social security is a second-order consideration for these households since the pension income from social security is a relatively small share of total savings for the top income earners.

  37. 37.

    In a recent study, however, Caliendo, Guo, and Hosseini (2014) demonstrate that this result is sensitive to the assumption of whether (1) bequest income is fixed or endogenous and (2) bequest income is redistributed anonymously or through a direct linkage between deceased parents and surviving children.

  38. 38.

    In addition, Heer (2018) models income uncertainty from unemployment and specifies a more general utility function with Epstein-Zin preferences that include the Cobb-Douglas utility function (6.45) as a special case.

  39. 39.

    Be careful when you compare our equilibrium conditions to those in the literature. In some cases, the indexation of the survival probabilities is different and ϕ s denotes the probability to survive up to age s conditional on surviving up to age s − 1 as in İmrohoroğlu, İmrohoroğlu, and Joines (1995) or Huggett (1996), while our notation follows Conesa and Krueger (1999).

  40. 40.

    In the literature, expected lifetime utility is either stated in the form of (6.44) (e.g., in İmrohoroğlu, İmrohoroğlu, and Joines 1995 or Huggett 1996) or the product of the cumulative survival probabilities, \(\prod _{j=1}^s \phi _{t+j-2,j-1}\), is dropped from this expression (e.g., in Conesa and Krueger 1999). In the latter case, expectations are also formed with respect to (stochastic) survival and instantaneous utility of being dead is set equal to zero. We adhere to the former notation so that expectations \(\mathbb {E}_t\{.\}\) are only formed with respect to stochastic idiosyncratic productivity. This notation will be useful in a model of Chap. 7.5 where we analyze the demographic transition. In this model, survival of the individuals is stochastic, while individual productivity is deterministic. As a consequence, the derivation of the Euler equation that contains the survival probability of the individual as an additional factor will become more evident.

  41. 41.

    In Chap. 5, we denoted the labor income tax rate by τ L. Notice that the tax on labor income in this model is the sum of the wage income tax and the social security contribution rate, τ L = τ w + τ p.

  42. 42.

    In contrast to Sect. 6.3.4, we do not assume pensions to be related to the individual’s lifetime social security contributions. Our simplifying assumption is supported by the results of Fehr, Kallweit, and Kindermann (2013) and Heer (2018), who find in their studies with earnings-dependent pensions that pensions should optimally be provided lump-sum rather than earnings-dependent.

  43. 43.

    The mean of the workers’ efficiency \( \eta \epsilon \bar y_s\) is normalized to one.

  44. 44.

    Related research that uses such a value for β includes İmrohoroğlu, İmrohoroğlu, and Joines (1995) and Huggett (1996). With this value of β, the effective time discount factor of the newborn for utility at age s, \(\beta ^{s-1} \left (\prod _{j=1}^{s} \phi _{j-1}\right )\), displays an increasing weight to instantaneous utility until real lifetime age 63, before it declines again and even falls below one after the real lifetime age 82 (for the survival probabilities for the year 2015).

  45. 45.

    The concept of the value function is introduced in Appendix 6.2.

  46. 46.

    An alternative would be to either let government expenditures be a production input or let the government provide a public consumption good. See the applications in Chaps. 4 and 5.

  47. 47.

    In Problem 6.6, you are asked to test whether consumption habits help to improve the modeling of consumption-age behavior in a standard Auerbach-Kotlikoff model that implies a downward jump in consumption at the age of retirement.

  48. 48.

    One of the first studies to highlight the role of the OLG model in accounting for observed wealth heterogeneity was Huggett (1996).

  49. 49.

    See De Nardi (2015) for a survey of modeling wealth heterogeneity in quantitative general equilibrium models.

  50. 50.

    İmrohoroğlu and Kitao (2009) also study the effect of the Frisch labor supply elasticity on aggregate labor and the labor-age profile. They distinguish between two different scenarios for the pension reform, consisting of the downsizing of the system by 50% or the total elimination of social security. İmrohoroğlu and Kitao show that the effect of pension reforms on aggregate labor is rather insensitive to the Frisch elasticity, while the profile of hours over the life-cycle is highly sensitive. They also find substantial welfare gains from the reduction in pensions even in the case of a low labor supply elasticity. According to their Table 6.2, the long-run welfare gain of half-privatization amounts to 4.3% of total consumption for a low Frisch elasticity equal to η lw = 0.5. In contrast to our approach, however, they do not model permanent productivity differences between the workers, and thus, income heterogeneity is smaller in their model than in ours.

  51. 51.

    We neglect one factor that might increase the welfare effects of social security, however. Fuster, İmrohoroğlu, and İmrohoroğlu (2003) find that in the case of two-sided altruism towards ancestors and descendants, the welfare effects of social security are enhanced. Altonij, Hayashi, and Kotlikoff (1997), however, present empirical evidence that rejects the implications of altruism for intergenerational risk-sharing behavior.

  52. 52.

    More precisely, we assume that the per capita government expenditures grow at the exogenous rate of technological growth.

  53. 53.

    For example, Kitao (2014) also considers a linear adjustment over a period of 50 years.

  54. 54.

    Recall that aggregate labor L t in period t is expressed relative to total population N t.

  55. 55.

    For example, young workers in the years 2050–2060 supply the highest number of working hours during the entire transition period, but their wealth peaks only at the end of their working life in later years.

  56. 56.

    Recall that we assumed that \(\tilde G\) would remain at its 2015 level. In addition, government revenue from accidental bequests declines due to higher survival probabilities. The latter effect, however, is rather modest.

  57. 57.

    Recall that we consider only the average lifetime utility of the individual generations. The welfare effects might vary considerably across the different productivity types (see also Table 6.7 for the steady-state analysis for the year 2015).

  58. 58.

    A study that focuses on the political implementability of a transition from the status quo to a reduction in PAYGO pensions in the US is provided by Conesa and Krueger (1999). In accordance with our argument, they find that although the transition to a fully funded pension system would imply substantial welfare gains, a majority of voters would be worse off from this option and thus favor the status quo.

  59. 59.

    See pages 174–177 in Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987).

  60. 60.

    Recall (if your age allows for it) that computer technology in these years was less capable of handling such numerical problems with a high dimension of (individual) state variables.

  61. 61.

    As noted by İmrohoroğlu, İmrohoroğlu, and Joines (1999), this high value for optimal pensions results from the fact that their model is characterized by dynamic inefficiency in the absence of social security. Higher pensions and, hence, lower savings actually increase total consumption at low replacement rates. In addition, İmrohoroğlu, İmrohoroğlu, and Joines (1999) argue that the US economy is dynamically efficient, as shown by Abel, Mankiw, Summers, and Zeckhauser (1989). In our model above, we only consider dynamically efficient economies in which the population growth rate is below the economic growth rate. İmrohoroğlu, İmrohoroğlu, and Joines (1999) also include land as a (constant) production factor in addition to capital and labor and, as a consequence, their economy is dynamically efficient. They find the optimal unfunded PAYG public pensions in the US to be zero in the stationary state.

  62. 62.

    Another study with exogenous labor supply that focuses on the distortion of social security contributions affecting the accumulation of capital is Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (1999). The main channel emphasized in their model is the financing of pensions with a distortionary income tax that is levied on labor and capital income. Since labor supply is exogenous, the distortion only affects capital accumulation. The authors compare the current system (as of 1996) to alternative scenarios including the abolition of the social security system and a system that is partially PAYG and partially fully funded. They find the alternatives to imply significant welfare gains if general equilibrium effects are taken into account.

  63. 63.

    İmrohoroğlu, İmrohoroğlu, and Joines (1995) find that the optimal level of social security “appears to be zero when … we incorporate exogenous technological progress in the model”.

  64. 64.

    Notice that another asset variable in the form of government debt enters our model, and in general equilibrium, the sum of debt (equivalently, government assets) and capital is equal to aggregate savings.

  65. 65.

    You are asked to compute the Hicksian efficiency gain for the two-period OLG model from Sect. 6.3.2 in Problem 6.4.

  66. 66.

    To keep the model tractable, Krueger and Ludwig (2007) assume that pensions depend only on the permanent efficiency type, not on the stochastic individual component. In addition, the authors study the transition dynamics under the assumption that contribution rates freeze in 2004. Beyond these assumptions, the model closely resembles that in the previous section.

  67. 67.

    There are two different tax rates that fulfill the condition of a balanced budget (the two points of interception of the Laffer curve and the line of government expenditures G 2015); naturally, the government chooses the lower tax rate on the upward-sloping side of the Laffer curve.

  68. 68.

    However, they simplify the model by not considering income uncertainty.

  69. 69.

    Their model is in some respects more elaborate than ours, in particular with respect to the projection of public medical expenditures; it also includes age-specific fertility rates. In addition, the authors assume that the interest rate on government debt is 1.145% lower than the rate of return on capital throughout the transition.

  70. 70.

    We will discuss the role of debt in the next chapter.

  71. 71.

    In fact, we could drop the expectational operator \(\mathbb {E}_t\) in the Bellman equation for the retired and replace it by the survival probability ϕ s,t because they do not face income uncertainty (in contrast to workers).

  72. 72.

    A detailed description can be found in Chapter 11.6.1 in Heer and Maußner (2009).

  73. 73.

    This value for the final year is found by trial and error. We choose 2250 because the transition of the endogenous values is complete by then. In Fig. 6.15, we drop the presentation of the final periods to better illustrate the transition.

  74. 74.

    Our households are naive in the sense that they ignore their future behavior in the optimization decision in period 1; in other words, in period 1, they do not realize that they will behave the same way in period 2 (applying quasi-hyperbolic discounting to the discounted utility of the remaining lifetime).

  75. 75.

    A seminal paper that introduces you to quasi-hyperbolic discounting and commitment technologies is Laibson (1997).

  76. 76.

    In addition, İmrohoroğlu, İmrohoroğlu, and Joines (2003) find that social security is not effective in correcting for under-saving that results from time-inconsistent preferences.

  77. 77.

    The following description is taken from Chapter 9.1 in Heer and Maußner (2009).

References

  • Abel, A. B., Mankiw, N. G., Summers, L. H., & Zeckhauser, R. J. (1989). Assessing dynamic efficiency: Theory and evidence. Review of Economic Studies, 56, 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alkema, L., Raftery, A. E., Gerland, P., Clark, S. J., Pelletier, F., Buettner, T., & Heilig, G. K. (2011). Probalistic projections of the total fertility rate for all countries. Demography, 48, 815–839.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonij, J. G., Hayashi, F., & Kotlikoff, L. (1997). Parental altruism and intervivos transfers: Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 105, 1121–1166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio, O., Kitao, S., & Violante, G. L. (2007). Global demographic trends and social security reform. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 144–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach, A. J., & Kotlikoff, L. (1987). Dynamic fiscal policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barr, N., & Diamond, P. (2008). Reforming pensions—Principles and policy choices. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. J., & Fischer, S. (1989). Lectures on macroeconomics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Börsch-Sopan, A. H., & Winter, J. (2001). Population aging, savings behavior and capital markets (NBER working paper No. 8561).

    Google Scholar 

  • Braun, R. A., & Joines, D. H. (2015). The implications of a graying Japan for government policy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 57, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Budría Rodriguez, S., Díaz-Giménez, J., & Quadrini, V. (2002). Updated facts on the U.S. distributions of earnings, income, and wealth. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 26, 2–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caliendo, F. N., Guo, N. L., & Hosseini, R. (2014). Social security is NOT a substitute for annuity markets. Review of Economic Dynamics, 17, 739–755.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conesa, J. C., & Krueger, D. (1999). Social security reform with heterogeneous agents. Review of Economic Dynamics, 2, 757–795.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Nardi, M. (2015). Quantitative models of wealth inequality: A survey (NBER Working Paper, 21106).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • De Nardi, M., & Yang, F. (2016). Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 77, 130–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Nardi, M., Imrohoroğlu, S., & Sargent, T. J. (1999). Projected US demographics and social security. Review of Economic Dynamics, 2, 575–615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, H. (1999). Welfare effects of dynamic tax reforms. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, H., Kallweit, M., & Kindermann, F. (2013). Should pensions be progressive? European Economic Review, 63, 94–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández-Villaverde, J., & Krueger, D. (2007). Consumption over the life cycle: Facts from consumer expenditure survey data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(3), 552–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuster, L., İmrohoroğlu, A., & İmrohoroğlu, S. (2003). A welfare analysis of social security in a dynastic framework. International Economic Review, 44, 1247–1274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerland, P., Raftery, A. E., Sevčíková, H., Li, N., Gu, D., Spoorenberg, T., Alkema, L., Fosdick, B. K., Chunn, J., Lalic, N., Bay, G., Buettner, T., Heilig, G. K., & Wilmoth, J. (2014). World population stabilization unlikely this century. Science, 346, 234–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guvenen, F., Karahan, F., Ozkan, S., & Sang, J. (2015). What do data on millions of U.S. workers reveal about life-cycle earnings risk? (NBER Working Paper Series, 20913).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, G. (1993). The cyclical and secular behavior of the labor input: Comparing efficiency units and hours worked. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 8, 71–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, G., & İmrohoroğlu, S. (2008). Consumption over the life cycle: The role of annuities. Review of Economic Dynamics, 11(3), 566–583.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heer, B. (2018). Optimal pensions in aging economies. B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 18, 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heer, B., & Irmen, A. (2014). Population, pensions and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 46, 50–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heer, B., & Maußner, A. (2009). Dynamic general equilibrium modeling: Computational methods and applications (2nd ed.). Heidelberg: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Heer, B., Polito, V., & Wickens, M. R. (2017). Population aging, social security and fiscal limits (CEPR Discussion Paper Series, DP11978).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hubbard, R. G., & Judd, K. L. (1987). Social security and individual welfare: Precautionary saving, borrowing constraints, and the payroll tax. American Economic Review, 77, 630–646.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huggett, M. (1996). Wealth distribution in life-cycle economies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 38, 373–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurd, M. D. (1989). Mortality risk and bequests. Econometrica, 57, 799–813.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • İmrohoroğlu, S., & Kitao, S. (2009). Labor supply elasticity and social security reform. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 867–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • İmrohoroğlu, A., İmrohoroğlu, S., & Joines, D. H. (1995). A life cycle analysis of social security. Economic Theory, 6, 83–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • İmrohoroğlu, A., İmrohoroğlu, S., & Joines, D. H. (1999). Social security in an overlapping generations economy with land. Review of Economic Dynamics, 2, 638–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • İmrohoroğlu, A., İmrohoroğlu, S., & Joines, D. H. (2003). Time-inconsistent preferences and social security. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 745–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judd, K. L. (1998). Numerical methods in economics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kitao, S. (2014). Sustainable social security: Four options. Review of Economic Dynamics, 17, 756–779.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, D., & Ludwig, A. (2007). On the consequences of demographic change for rates of returns to capital, and the distribution of wealth and welfare. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 49–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, D., & Perri, F. (2006). Does income inequality lead to consumption inequality? Evidence and theory. Review of Economic Studies, 73, 163–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 443–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza, E. G., Razin, A., & Tesar, L. L. (1994). Effective tax rates in macroeconomics: Cross country estimates of tax rates on factor incomes and consumption. Journal of Monetary Economics, 34, 297–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishiyama, S., & Smetters, K. (2007). Does social security privitization produce efficiency gains? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 1677–1719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2015). Pensions at a Glance 2015: OECD and G20 indicators. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2017). Pensions at a Glance 2017: OECD and G20 indicators. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quadrini, V. (2000). Entrepreneurship, saving, and social mobility. Review of Economic Dynamics, 3, 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raftery, A. E., Li, N., Sevčíková, H., Gerland, P., & Heilig, G. K. (2012). Bayesian probabilitic population projections for all countries. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 109, 13915–13921.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raftery, A. E., Chunn, J., Gerland, P., & Sevčíková, H. (2013). Bayesian probabilitic projections of life expectancy for all countries. Demography, 50, 777–801.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokey, N., Lucas, R. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1989). Recursive methods in economic dynamics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storesletten, K., Telmer, C. I., & Yaron, A. (1999). The risk-sharing implications of alternative social security arrangements. Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, 50, 213–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storesletten, K., Telmer, C. I., & Yaron, A. (2004). Consumption and risk sharing over the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51, 609–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UN (2015). World population prospects: The 2015 revision, Methodology of the United Nations population estimates and projections (ESA/P/WP. 242).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendices

Appendix 6.1: Accidental Bequests

To understand why accidental bequests in (6.56e) are given by the sum of next-period assets \(\tilde k'\) and the interest \(r_{t+1}\tilde k'\), we will consider a simplified two-period model. In particular, let N t(1) and N t(2) denote the sizes of the young and old generations in period t. The survival probability of the young is denoted by ϕ 1, and population grows at rate n, implying:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} N_{t+1}(2)&=\phi_1 N_t(1), \end{aligned} $$
(6.61a)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} N_{t+1}(1)&=(1+n) N_t(1). \end{aligned} $$
(6.61b)

Consequently, total population is given by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} N_t = N_t(1)+N_t(2).\end{aligned}$$

Total accidental bequests are confiscated by the government and redistributed lump-sum to the total population in the amount N t+1 tr t+1 in period t + 1:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} Beq_{t+1}= N_{t+1} tr_{t+1}.\end{aligned}$$

For the rest of the model, we stipulate that the standard equilibrium conditions of the two-period OLG model in Chap. 3 hold. Therefore, the aggregate capital stock K t+1 at the beginning of period t + 1 is equal to total savings of the young generation at the end of period t, N t(1)s t; consumption of the young \(c^1_{t+1}\) is equal to their wage income plus transfers minus savings; and consumption of the old \(c^2_{t+1}\) is equal to savings plus interest and transfers. Finally, the factor prices are equal to their marginal products. These conditions are summarized by the following equations:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} N_t(1) s_t &= K_{t+1}, \end{aligned} $$
(6.62a)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} N_{t+1}(1) s_{t+1} &=K_{t+2}, \end{aligned} $$
(6.62b)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} c^1_{t+1} &= w_{t+1} l_{t+1} + tr_{t+1} -s_{t+1}, \end{aligned} $$
(6.62c)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} c^2_{t+1} & = (1+r_{t+1})s_t + tr_{t+1}, \end{aligned} $$
(6.62d)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} r_{t+1} &= F_K\left(K_{t+1},l_{t+1}N_{t+1}(1)\right) -\delta, \end{aligned} $$
(6.62e)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} w_{t+1} & =F_L\left(K_{t+1},l_{t+1}N_{t+1}(1)\right). \end{aligned} $$
(6.62f)

As before, we assume that production is characterized by constant returns to scale, implying:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} Y_t = F(K_t,l_{t}N_{t}(1) ) = F_K\left(K_{t},l_{t}N_{t}(1)\right) K_t + F_L\left(K_{t},l_{t}N_{t}(1)\right) l_t N_t(1).\end{aligned}$$

In the goods market equilibrium:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} K_{t+1}(1-\delta) + Y_{t+1} = N_{t+1}(1) c^1_{t+1} + N_{t+1}(2) c^2_{t+1} + K_{t+2}.\end{aligned} $$
(6.63)

Inserting the above equations into the equation for the goods market equilibrium, we derive

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} &K_{t+1} +w_{t+1} l_{t+1} N_{t+1}(1) + r_{t+1} K_{t+1}\\ &= w_{t+1} l_{t+1} N_{t+1}(1) + N_{t+1} (1) tr_{t+1} - N_{t+1}(1) s_{t+1} \\ &+N_{t+1}(2) \left[ 1+r_{t+1} \right] s_t + N_{t+1}(2) tr_{t+1}+K_{t+2}, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

and therefore,

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} K_{t+1} + r_{t+1} K_{t+1}&= N_{t+1} tr_{t+1}+ N_{t+1}(2) \left[ 1+r_{t+1} \right] s_t\\ &= N_{t+1} tr_{t+1}+ \phi_1 N_{t}(1) \left[ 1+r_{t+1} \right] s_t\\ &= N_{t+1} tr_{t+1}+ \phi_1 \left[ 1+r_{t+1} \right] K_{t+1}.\end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Consequently,

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} Beq_{t+1} = N_{t+1} tr_{t+1} = (1-\phi_1) \left[ 1+r_{t+1} \right] K_{t+1}.\end{aligned} $$
(6.64)

Appendix 6.2: Computation of the Large-Scale OLG Model in Sect. 6.4

Solving for the stationary equilibrium is a computational challenge. Recall how we solved the two-period OLG model with a PAYG pension system and defined contribution benefits in Sect. 6.3.2. We were able to directly solve the first-order conditions of the households together with the equilibrium equations. In particular, the optimality condition with respect to the labor supply was given by (6.33c). In the large-scale OLG model in Sect. 6.4, the computational problem is much more complicated. We cannot solve for the optimal labor supply for all workers alive because of their high numbers. For this reason, consider the first period of life, s = 1. In this cohort, we have four different types of workers with the productivity types η i 𝜖 j with i = 1, 2 and j = 1, 2. They all accumulate different amounts of savings. At age 2, they may change their productivity type such that the number of heterogeneous workers increases to 4 × 2 = 8. Since the workers accumulate different amounts of savings depending on their employment history, the workers in a cohort are different (with respect to their savings) even for the same productivity type 𝜖 i η j. Prior to retirement at age s = 45, we observe 4 × 244 = 7.0 ⋅ 1013 different workers. We cannot solve this problem with the help of direct computation for such a large number of agents. Instead, we use value function iteration.

2.1 Value Function Iteration

To describe the optimization problem, we use a recursive representation of the consumer’s problem, following Stokey, Lucas, and Prescott (1989). This specification is very amenable to the solution methods described below. Let \(V_t(k_t^s,s,\epsilon ,\eta )\) be the value of the objective function of the s-year-old agent with wealth \(k_t^s\), age s, permanent efficiency type 𝜖, and individual productivity η in period t. The value function V t(.) is equal to the optimized discounted expected lifetime utility. Thus, for the individual during the last period of his life, s = 70, the stationary value function is simply given by:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} V_t(k_t^{70},70,\epsilon,\eta) = \max_{c_t^{70},k_{t+1}^{71}} u(c_t^{70},1) \end{aligned}$$

subject to \(k_{t+1}^{71}\ge 0\) and the budget constraint (6.55) noticing that \(c^s_t=A_t \tilde c_t^s\) and \(k^s_t=A_t \tilde k^s_t\). Obviously, the optimal policy is given by \(\tilde k_{t+1}^{71}=0\) and

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \tilde c_t^{70}= \tilde pen_t + \left[1+(1-\tau^K) r_t\right] \tilde k_t^{70}+\tilde tr_t.\end{aligned}$$

The household completely consumes its income (from pensions and interest) and wealth during the last period of life.

In the second-to-last period of life, s = 69, the value function is given by the following equation:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} V_t(k_t^{69},69,\epsilon,\eta) = \max_{c_t^{69},k_{t+1}^{70},c_{t+1}^{70},k_{t+2}^{71}} \left\{ u(c_t^{69},1) + \beta \mathbb{E}_t u(c_{t+1}^{70},1) \right\} \end{aligned}$$

subject to the budget constraint (6.55) in periods t and t + 1. It will be convenient to transform the above equation into one with stationary values. For this reason, divide the equation by \(A_t^{\iota (1-\sigma )}\), which results in

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} & \tilde V_t(\tilde k_t^{69},69,\epsilon,\eta) \\ &= \max_{\tilde c_t^{69},\tilde k_{t+1}^{70},\tilde c_{t+1}^{70},\tilde k_{t+2}^{71}} \left\{ u(\tilde c_t(69),1) + (1+\gamma)^{\iota(1-\sigma)} \beta \mathbb{E}_t u(\tilde c_{t+1}^{70},1) \right\}, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

with \(\tilde V_t\equiv V_t/A_t^{\iota (1-\sigma )}\). In addition, we have used the fact that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \frac{u(c_{t+1}^{70},1)}{A_t^{\iota (1-\sigma)}}=\frac{(c_{t+1}^{70})^{\iota (1-\sigma)}}{1-\sigma} \frac{1}{A_t^{\iota (1-\sigma)}}= \frac{(\tilde c_{t+1}^{70})^{\iota (1-\sigma)}} {1-\sigma} (1+\gamma)^{\iota(1-\sigma)}.\end{aligned}$$

Equivalently, the above dynamic equation can be restated as a recursive equation as follows:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} & \tilde V_t(\tilde k_t^{69},69,\epsilon,\eta)= \max_{\tilde c_t^{69},\tilde k_{t+1}^{70}} \left\{ u(\tilde c_t^{69},1) \right. \\ & \left. + (1+\gamma)^{\iota(1-\sigma)} \beta \mathbb{E}_t \tilde V_{t+1}(\tilde k_{t+1}^{70},70,\epsilon,\eta) \right\}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

For the household aged s, we can use this recursive formulation more generally as follows:

(6.65)

subject to (6.55) and (6.46). Equation (6.65) is also known as the Bellman equation. We will exploit its recursive nature to compute the optimal policy functions of the households (for given factor prices {w t, r t}, government transfers \(\tilde tr_t\), and pension policies \(\tilde pen_t\)).

We solve for the optimization problem of the household starting in the last period of its life, working our way back to the first period of the household’s life. As we do not know the exact value of \(\tilde k_t^{70}\), we compute the value function \(\tilde V(\tilde k,70,\epsilon ,\eta )\) over a range of \(\tilde k\in [\tilde k_{min},\tilde k_{max}]\). Since we assume a liquidity constraint \(\tilde k\ge 0\), we choose \(\tilde k_{min}=0\). Finding a good value for the upper limit of the interval \(\tilde k_{max}\) is more difficult. Since we do not yet know the equilibrium values of w, r, \(\tilde tr\), or \(\tilde pen\), we do not know the maximum income of households that is required to obtain a possible guess for the upper limit of savings. We, instead, advocate for a rather pragmatic procedure. We will calibrate our model such that the real interest rate r is approximately equal to 4% as observed in the US economy. In addition, we know the mass of working agents in our model, which is approximately 2/3. Assuming that average productivity is equal to one and agents work approximately 30% of their available time (we will calibrate the model accordingly below), we obtain a rough estimate of \(\tilde L \approx 0.2\). From the first-order condition of the firm, we know that \(r=\alpha \tilde k^{\alpha -1} \tilde L^{1-\alpha }-\delta \). Consequently, we can compute an approximate value of \(\tilde k=6.19\). Since savings initially increase over the working life, wealth \(\tilde k_t^s\) will also be hump-shaped over the life-cycle and may well exceed average wealth. We, therefore, choose an initial value of \(\tilde k_{max}=20\) and find it to be non-binding in our computations.

Since we cannot compute the value function of the 70-year-old at each point of the interval \([\tilde k_{min},\tilde k_{max}]\) (the number of all points is infinite), we only perform this calculation at certain grid points. We choose equispaced grids with n k = 100 points. In the computation of the value function of the 69-year-old, we will need the value of the value function at age s = 70 between grid points. To obtain this, we will interpolate linearly between grid points if necessary.

Computing the value function \(\tilde V(\tilde k, s, \epsilon ,\eta )\) at a grid point \((\tilde k^i,70,\epsilon ,\eta )\), i = 1, …, n k, is straightforward and follows from the budget constraint and the definition of the utility function:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \tilde V_t(\tilde k^i, 70,\epsilon,\eta) =\frac{\left( \tilde pen_t + \left[1+(1-\tau^K) r_t\right] \tilde k^i +\tilde tr_t \right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)}}{1-\sigma}.\end{aligned}$$

Notice that the value of the value function is the same for all productivity types (𝜖, η) since they no longer affect income as long as households have accumulated the same wealth \(\tilde k^i\).

For the retired households with age s = 69, 68, …, 46, we have to solve an optimization problem in one variable. To do so, let us consider the Bellman equation at age s = 69 at a grid point \((\tilde k^i,69,\epsilon ,\eta )\) Footnote 71:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \tilde V_t(\tilde k^i,69,\epsilon,\eta) = \max_{\tilde c_t^{69},\tilde k_{t+1}^{70}} \left\{ u(\tilde c_t^{69},1) + (1+\gamma)^{\iota(1-\sigma)}\beta \mathbb{E}_t \tilde V_t(\tilde k_{t+1}^{70},70,\epsilon,\eta) \right\}. \end{aligned}$$

If we substitute for \(\tilde c_t^{69}\) from the budget constraint (6.55), the maximand within the brackets is a function of \(\tilde k_{t+1}^{70}\). There are various numerical procedures to solve such a maximization problem. In the Gauss program Ch6_optimal_pension.g, we use the so-called golden section search.Footnote 72 The basic idea of this method is to bracket the maximum \(\tilde k^{-}\le \tilde k_{t+1}^{70} \le \tilde k^{+}\) and let this interval shrink against zero. The limit points are easy to choose, e.g., \(\tilde k^{-}=0\) for the lower limit and \(\tilde k^{+}\) as the value for which \(\tilde c_t=0\). In the next step, two points within the interval are selected, and the one with the lower value for the right-hand side of the above equation becomes the new limit point of the interval. The golden section search method optimizes the choice of these new points. This procedure is iterated until the interval length is sufficiently small, e.g., 10−6, and we then stop.

For the working agent, the maximization problem is more complicated because he also chooses his optimal labor supply \(l_t^s\). There are various numerical methods that are able to compute this two-dimensional optimization problem. We have chosen to transform the problem into two nested one-dimensional optimization problems and apply golden section search in the outer loop over the next-period capital stock \(\tilde k_{t+1}\) and direct computation from the first-order condition with respect to labor l t with the help of the Gauss-Newton algorithm in the inner loop.

Once we have solved the individual optimization problem, we can aggregate individual savings and labor supply to derive aggregate quantities and update our initial guesses of \(\tilde K\), \(\tilde L\), and the factor prices w and r. The budgets of the government and the pension system imply the values for \(\tilde tr\) and τ p. We update the old values by taking a weighted average of the two and iterating until convergence. The complete algorithm is described in Algorithm 6.1.

Algorithm 6.1 Computation of the Stationary Equilibrium of the OLG Model in Sect. 6.4.1

We compute the transition dynamics for the US economy as described in Algorithm 9.2.1 in Heer and Maußner (2009). We first choose a number of transition periods under the assumption that the transition is complete by 2250.Footnote 73 Next, we compute the initial and final steady states and project a trajectory for the endogenous values of \(\{\tilde K_t,\tilde L_t,\bar l_t,\tau ^w_t,\tau ^p_t,\tilde tr_t\}_{t=2015}^{2250}\). As our initial guess, we postulate a linear adjustment path for all endogenous variables. We assume that the economy is in steady state in and prior to 2015. For given path of \(\{\tilde K_t,\tilde L_t,\bar l_t,\tau ^w_t,\tau ^p_t,\tilde tr_t\}_{t=2015}^{2250}\), we compute the individual policy functions in each year and aggregate individual labor supply and consumption. With the help of the consistency conditions and the fiscal budget constraints, we are able to provide a new guess for the path of \(\{\tilde K_t,\tilde L_t,\bar l_t,\tau ^w_t,\tau ^p_t,\tilde tr_t\}_{t=2015}^{2250}\). Again, we use a simple dampening iterative scheme, as described in Section 3.9 of Judd (1998), to update the sequence \(\{\tilde K_t,\tilde L_t,\bar l_t,\tau ^w_t,\tau ^p_t,\tilde tr_t\}_{t=2015}^{2250}\) until the sequence converges (with an accuracy equal to 10−6).

The run time of the computer program Ch6_optimal_pension.g depends sensitively on the amount of grid points n k and is considerable. Using Windows 7 on a computer with a 64-BIT system, 32 MB RAM, and an Intel(R) Xeon(R) 2.90 GHz processor, the stationary equilibrium is computed within 4 min, while the computation of the transition takes approximately 14 h.

Appendix 6.3: Data Sources

The data on population are taken from the UN, while the pensions-related data are retrieved from the OECD.

  • Old-age dependency ratio The data presented in Fig. 6.1 is published by the UN in its World Population Prospects: The 2017 Revision, ‘File POP/13-D: Old-age dependency ratio 65+/(25–64) by region, subregion and country, 1950–2100 (ratio of population 65+ per 100 population 25–64)’. The UN provides projections of the OADR for a ‘low’, ‘medium’, and ‘high’ fertility variant. If not mentioned otherwise, we use the ‘medium’ fertility variant.

  • Pension spending The data displayed in Fig. 6.3 are taken from the OECD (2015), Pensions Statistics: Pensions at a Glance (Accessed on February 15, 2018).

    http://data.oecd.org/socialexp/pension-spending.htm.

  • Pension replacement rates The data in Fig. 6.4 presents the gross pension replacement rates of men as a percentage of pre-retirement earnings and can be retrieved from OECD (2017), Gross pension replacement rates (indicator). doi: 10.1787/3d1afeb1-en (Accessed on February 15, 2018).

    https://data.oecd.org/pension/gross-pension-replacement-rates.htm.

Problems

6.1

Recompute the solution to Numerical Examples in Sect. 6.3 with the following changes:

  1. 1.

    Check the robustness of the results with respect to the intertemporal elasticity of substitution 1∕σ, with σ ∈{2, 4}.

  2. 2.

    Assume that capital depreciates completely so that the real interest rate is represented by

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} r_t= \alpha k_t^{\alpha-1} l_t^{1-\alpha}-1.0.\end{aligned}$$

6.2

Contribution-Based Pensions in the Three-Period OLG Model Assume that an agent lives three periods. Each period length is equal to 20 years. In the first two periods, the agent is working, and in the third period, he receives a pension. Each generation has mass 1∕3. We will only consider the steady state.

Lifetime utility is given by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} U= \sum_{s=1}^3 \beta^{s-1} u(c^s,1-l^s).\end{aligned} $$
(6.66)

Instantaneous utility is presented by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} u(c,1-l)=u(c,1-l)=\frac{\left( c (1-l)^\iota \right)^{1-\sigma}}{1-\sigma},\end{aligned} $$

with ι = 2.0 and σ = 2.0. Assume that β = 0.90. Time is allocated to either work or leisure.

During the first two periods, households work; in the third period, they retire (l 3 ≡ 0). Agents are born without assets, k 1 = 0. In addition, the workers pay contributions to the pension system equal to τ = 10% of their gross labor income. Therefore, the budget constraint at age s = 1, 2 is given by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} (1-\tau) w l^s +(1+r) k^s = c^s + k^{s+1}. \end{aligned} $$

During retirement, agents receive pensions that depend on past earnings

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} d=\sum_{s=1}^2 \tau w l^s.\end{aligned} $$

In particular, the pension system does not pay any interest on accumulated contributions. The pension depends on accumulated contributions as follows:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} pen(d)=pen_{min}+\rho_{pen} d.\end{aligned} $$

Therefore, the budget constraint of the retired worker is given by:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} pen(d) +(1+r) k^3 = c^3. \end{aligned} $$

In addition, we assume that the government runs a balanced budget:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \tau w \frac{l^1+l^2}{3} = \frac{1}{3} \left( pen_{min}+\rho_{pen} d\right).\end{aligned} $$

Assume that ρ pen = 0.5, implying

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} pen_{min}=0.5 \tau w (l^1+l^2).\end{aligned} $$

Production is modeled as in Sect. 6.3:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} Y=K^\alpha L^{1-\alpha},\end{aligned} $$

with

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} L= \frac{l^1+l^2}{3}, \;\;\; K= \frac{k^2+k^3}{3},\end{aligned}$$

and α = 0.36.

Factors are rewarded by their marginal products:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} w_t & = (1-\alpha) \left(\frac{K_t}{L_t}\right)^{\alpha},\\ r_t& =\alpha \left(\frac{K_t}{L_t}\right)^{\alpha-1}-\delta. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

The depreciation rate is set equal to δ = 0.5.

  1. 1.

    Solve the problem with the help of direct computation (solving a system of non-linear equations). Show that the first-order conditions are given by

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \lambda^1 &=\left(c^1\right)^{-\sigma} \left( 1-l^1\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)} ,\\ \lambda^2 &=\left(c^2\right)^{-\sigma} \left( 1-l^2\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)} ,\\ \lambda^3 &=\left(c^3\right)^{-\sigma}, \\ \iota \left(c^1\right)^{1-\sigma} \left( 1-l^1\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)-1} & = \lambda^1(1-\tau) w +\beta^2 \lambda^3 \rho_{pen} \tau w,\\ \iota \left(c^2\right)^{1-\sigma} \left( 1-l^2\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)-1} & = \lambda^2 (1-\tau) w +\beta \lambda^3 \rho_{pen} \tau w,\\ \lambda^1 &= \beta \lambda^2 (1+r),\\ \lambda^2 &= \beta \lambda^3 (1+r). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

    For given aggregate variables w and r, the 7 first-order conditions together with the 3 budget constraints are a system of non-linear equations in 10 unknowns c s and λ s, s = 1, 2, 3, l 1, l 2, k 2, k 3. Use numerical methods to solve the system. Start with educated guesses for K and L, compute the individual policy functions, and update K and L accordingly. Compute the implied gross pension replacement rate with respect to the earnings in the second period. How does the abolition of social security affect output, labor, and welfare?

  2. 2.

    Assume that the government switches from a defined contribution to a defined benefit system and that it applies the same gross pension replacement rate with respect to the earnings in the second period as above (for the case with τ = 10%). What are the effects on labor supply, savings, output, and the social security contribution rate τ?

6.3

Quasi-Hyperbolic Discounting Recompute the three-period OLG model from Problem 6.2. However, instead assume (1) that pensions are not contribution-based but provided lump-sum (ρ pen = 0) and (2) that the household behaves inconsistently and in a naive way. Therefore, let the household at age 1 assume that its lifetime utility is represented by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} U= u(c^1,1-l^1)+ \mu \beta u(c^2,1-l^2) +\mu \beta^2 u(c^3,1-l^3),\;\; \mu<1, \end{aligned} $$
(6.67)

rather than by Eq. (6.66), where μ denotes the hyperbolic discounting parameter. The household maximizes its utility for μ = 0.85 in period 1, where the first-order conditions are given by:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \lambda^1 &=\left(c^1\right)^{-\sigma} \left( 1-l^1\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)} ,\\ \lambda^2 &=\left(c^2\right)^{-\sigma} \left( 1-l^2\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)} ,\\ \lambda^3 &=\left(c^3\right)^{-\sigma}, \\ \iota \left(c^1\right)^{1-\sigma} \left( 1-l^1\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)-1} & = \lambda^1(1-\tau) w,\\ \iota \left(c^2\right)^{1-\sigma} \left( 1-l^2\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)-1} & = \lambda^2 (1-\tau) w,\\ \lambda^1 &=\mu \beta \lambda^2 (1+r),\\ \lambda^2 &= \beta \lambda^3 (1+r). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Solve this system of equations for 10 unknowns c s and λ s, s = 1, 2, 3, l 1, l 2, k 2, k 3 and denote the solutions by \(\tilde c^s\), \(\tilde \lambda ^s\), \(\tilde k^s\), and \(\tilde l^s\).

In period 2, however, the household behaves in an inconsistent way and, for a given k 2, re-maximizesFootnote 74

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} U= u(c^2,1-l^2)+ \mu \beta u(c^3,1-l^3).\end{aligned}$$

The first-order conditions with respect to c 2, c 3, l 2, and k 3 are given by:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \lambda^2 &=\left(c^2\right)^{-\sigma} \left( 1-l^2\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)} ,\\ \lambda^3 &=\left(c^2\right)^{-\sigma}, \\ \iota \left(c^2\right)^{1-\sigma} \left( 1-l^2\right)^{\iota (1-\sigma)-1} & = \lambda^2 (1-\tau) w,\\ \lambda^2 &= \mu \beta \lambda^3 (1+r). \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Denote the solutions to these equilibrium conditions as \(\hat c^s\) and \(\hat \lambda ^s\), s = 2, 3, \(\hat l^2\), and \(\hat k^3\). The household suffers from inconsistent behavior and chooses smaller savings for μ < 1 in period 2 than it would have chosen in period 1.Footnote 75

In general equilibrium, aggregate capital and labor are given by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} K &=\frac{ \tilde k^2 + \hat k^3}{3},\\ L &= \frac{ \tilde l^1 + \hat l^2}{3}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

In a large-scale OLG model with individual income uncertainty, İmrohoroğlu, İmrohoroğlu, and Joines (2003) show that quasi-hyperbolic discounting at the rate of 15% lowers the capital stock by approximately 20% at any social security contribution rate.Footnote 76 Can you verify this result in the above example for pension replacement rates θ pen ∈{0, 50%}?

6.4

Hicksian Compensation Consider Fig. 6.5. Recompute the dynamics of the model under the assumption that the two cohorts alive at the time of the policy changes in period 1 are compensated such that the consumption equivalent change in comparison to the cohorts in the economy without the policy change is zero. Further assume that future generations receive transfers or pay lump-sum taxes such that (1) they all have equal lifetime utility and (2) the net present value of these transfers is equal to the payments of transfers to the cohorts in period 1. How large is the Hicksian efficiency gain?

6.5

Compute the optimal pension in the model of Sect. 6.4.1 under the assumption that the government holds both government consumption \(\tilde G\) and transfers \(\tilde Tr\) constant at their benchmark equilibrium values. Adjust the wage income tax rate τ w such that the government budget (6.50) is balanced.

6.6

A Simple Auerbach-Kotlikoff Model Footnote 77 Consider a 60-period OLG model in the tradition of Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987). Three sectors can be depicted: households, production, and the government.

Households Every year, a generation of equal measure is born. The total measure of all generations is normalized to one. Their first period of life is period 1.

Households live J = 60 years. Consequently, the measure of each generation is 1/60. During their first T = 40 years, agents supply labor \(l_t^s\) at age s in period t enjoying leisure \(1-l_t^s\). After 40 years, retirement is mandatory (\(l_t^s=0\) for s > 40) for the remaining T R = 20 years. Agents maximize lifetime utility at age 1 in period t:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \sum_{s=1}^{J} \beta^{s-1} u(c_{t+s-1}^s,1-l_{t+s-1}^s), \end{aligned}$$

where β denotes the discount factor. Instantaneous utility is a function of both consumption and leisure:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} u(c,1-l)=\frac{\left( c (1-l)^\iota \right)^{1-\sigma}-1}{1-\sigma}. \end{aligned} $$
(6.68)

Agents are born without wealth, \(k_t^1=0\), and do not leave bequests, \(k_t^{61}=0\). Agents receive income from capital \(k_t^s\) and labor \(l_t^s\). The real budget constraint of the working agent is given by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} k_{t+1}^{s+1}=(1+r_t) k_t^s +(1-\tau_t) w_t l_t^s-c_t^s, \;\;\; s=1,\ldots,T, \end{aligned}$$

where r t and w t denote the interest rate and the wage rate in period t, respectively. Wage income in period t is taxed at rate τ t. We can also interpret \(\tau _t w_t l_t^s\) as the worker’s social security contributions.

The first-order conditions of the working household are given by:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} (1-\tau_t) w_t &=\frac{u_{1-l}(c_t^s,1-l_t^s)}{u_c(c_t^s,1-l_t^s)}=\iota \frac{c_t^s}{1-l_t^s},\\\frac{1}{\beta}&= \frac{ u_c(c_{t+1}^{s+1},1-l_{t+1}^{s+1}) } {u_c(c_t^s,1-l_t^s)} \left[1+r_{t+1}\right] \end{aligned} $$
(6.69)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} & = \frac{ \left(c_{t+1}^{s+1}\right)^{-\sigma} \left(1-l_{t+1}^{s+1}\right)^{\iota(1-\sigma)} }{\left(c_{t}^s\right)^{-\sigma} \left(1-l_{t}^s\right)^{\iota(1-\sigma)}}\left[1+r_{t+1}\right]. \end{aligned} $$
(6.70)

During retirement, agents receive public pensions pen irrespective of their employment history, and the budget constraint of the retired worker is given by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} k_{t+1}^{s+1}=(1+r_t) k_t^s + pen-c_t^s, \;\;\; s=T+1,\ldots,T+T^R. \end{aligned}$$

The first-order condition of the retired worker is given by (6.70) with \(l_t^s=0\).

Production Firms are of measure one and produce output Y t in period t with labor L t and capital K t. Labor L t is paid wage w t. Capital K t is hired at rate r t and depreciates at rate δ. Production Y t is characterized by constant returns to scale and assumed to be Cobb-Douglas:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} Y_t= K_t^\alpha L_t^{1-\alpha}. \end{aligned} $$
(6.71)

In factor market equilibrium, factors are rewarded with their marginal products:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} w_t&=(1-\alpha) K_t^\alpha L_t^{-\alpha}, \end{aligned} $$
(6.72)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} r_t&=\alpha K_t^{\alpha-1} L_t^{1-\alpha}-\delta. \end{aligned} $$
(6.73)

Government The government uses the revenues from taxing labor to finance its expenditures on social security:

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \tau_t w_t L_t= \frac{T^R}{T+T^R} pen. \end{aligned} $$
(6.74)

Following a change in the provision of public pensions pen or in gross labor income w t L t, the labor income tax rate τ t adjusts to keep the government budget balanced.

Equilibrium An equilibrium for a given government policy pen and initial distribution of capital \(\left \{k_0^s\right \}_{s=1}^{J}\) is a collection of individual policy rules \(c(s,k_t^s,K_t,L_t)\), \(l(s,k_t^s,K_t,L_t)\), and \(k'(s,k_t^s,K_t,L_t)\), and relative prices of labor and capital {w t, r t}, such that:

  1. (i)

    Individual and aggregate behavior are consistent:

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} L_t&=\sum_{s=1}^{40} \frac{l_t^s}{60},\\ K_t&=\sum_{s=1}^{60} \frac{k_t^s}{60}. \end{aligned} $$

    The aggregate labor supply L t is equal to the sum of the labor supplies of each cohort, weighted by their mass 1∕J = 1∕60. Similarly, the aggregate capital supply is equal to the sum of the capital supplies of all cohorts.

  2. (ii)

    Relative prices {w t, r t} solve the firm’s optimization problem.

  3. (iii)

    Given relative prices {w t, r t} and the government’s policy pen, the individual policy rules c(.), l(.), and k′(.) solve the consumer’s optimization problem.

  4. (iv)

    The goods market clears:

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} K_t^\alpha L_t^{1-\alpha} = \sum_{s=1}^{60} \frac{c_t^s}{60} + K_{t+1}-(1-\delta) K_{t}. \end{aligned} $$
  5. (v)

    The government budget is balanced.

Calibration The benchmark case is characterized by the following calibration: σ = 2, β = 0.99, α = 0.3, δ = 0.1, replacement rate \(\theta ^p=\frac {pen}{(1-\tau ) w \bar l}=0.3\) (where \(\bar l\) denotes the average labor supply in the economy). ι is chosen to imply a steady-state labor supply of the working agents approximately equal to \(\bar l=35\%\) of available time and amounts to ι = 2.0.

  1. 1.

    Compute the steady state using numerical methods. To do so, you have to consider a system of 99 non-linear equations in the variables k s, s = 2, …, 60 and l s, s = 1, …, 40. Show that the shape of the consumption-age profile resembles that presented in Fig. 6.11 and displays a downward jump at the beginning of retirement. Show that the steady-state level of output is equal to Y = 0.3842.

  2. 2.

    Introduce a consumption tax of 10% that is retransferred lump-sum to the household. How does the consumption tax affect steady-state values?

  3. 3.

    Introduce a government sector that consumes 20% of steady-state output Y , G = 0.0768. Compare the following three tax instruments to finance G: (1) a tax on consumption τ c, (2) a tax on capital income τ K (assuming that depreciation is tax-deductible), and (3) a wage income tax rate τ w. Assume further that government consumption provides utility to the household that is additively separated from the utility in consumption and leisure such that the first-order conditions of the household are not affected by government consumption G. What are the steady-state effects of these three tax instruments on capital, labor, and output? What is the tax instrument that results in the lowest welfare losses? To answer these questions, compute the consumption equivalent change of each policy measure with respect to the case without government consumption.

  4. 4.

    Introduce consumption habits

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} u(c^s,l^s;c^{s-1}) = \frac{\left[ (c^s-\kappa c^{s-1}) \left(1-l^s\right)^\iota \right]^{1-\sigma}}{1-\sigma},\;\;\; \kappa \in [0,1)\end{aligned}$$

    with κ = 0.7. In addition, assume that the utility of the newborn generation is given by \(u(c^1,l^1)=\frac {\left [ c^1 \left (1-l^1\right )^\iota \right ]^{1-\sigma }}{1-\sigma }\). Notice that you cannot solve the problem recursively but have to solve the system of 99 variables simultaneously. Use your solution from the case without habits as an initial value for {l 1, l 2, …, l 40, k 2, k 3, …, k 60}. Do consumption habits help to make the consumption-age profile smoother? In particular, does the downward jump in consumption at the beginning of retirement disappear?

  5. 5.

    In the literature, two types of PAYG pension systems are often distinguished, the Bismarck versus the Beveridge system. In the former, only employed workers contribute to the pension system, and the contribution is levied on the wage income. In the latter, all households contribute prior to their retirement age, and contributions are based on total income, i.e., including capital income. Moreover, while in the Bismarck system, pensions are closely linked to contributions, the Beveridge pension system provides a guaranteed minimum income during retirement and redistributes strongly.

    In the above model, introduce a pension system that provides a lump-sum payment to the retired worker that is financed by a tax on both labor and capital income. Compare this with the average lifetime utility under a PAYG pension system that collects contributions that are levied only on labor income.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Heer, B. (2019). Pensions. In: Public Economics. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-00989-2_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics