Skip to main content

Dynamic Pricing Over Finite Horizons

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Revenue Management and Pricing Analytics

Abstract

In this chapter, we first consider the problem of dynamically pricing one or more products that consume a single resource. Sales take place over a finite selling horizon, and the objective is to maximize the expected revenue that can be obtained from a finite inventory of the resource. We will assume that inventories cannot be replenished during the sales horizon. This problem setup holds for hotels, airlines, and seasonal merchandise including fashion retailing that have long procurement lead times. In this chapter, we focus on models that explicitly consider the stochastic and dynamic nature of demand. We use dynamic programming formulations to compute an optimal policy as a function of the remaining inventory and the time-to-go. In some cases, we are able to give closed-form solutions for the value function and the optimal pricing policy. In other cases, we resort to numerical solutions and to heuristic policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • E. Adida, O. Ozer, Why markdown as a pricing modality? Manag. Sci. 65(5), 2161–2178 (2019)

    Google Scholar 

  • E. Adida, G. Perakis, A robust optimization approach to dynamic pricing and inventory control with no backorders. Math. Program. 107 (1–2), 97–129 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • E. Adida, G. Perakis, A nonlinear continuous time optimal control model of dynamic pricing and inventory control with no backorders. Nav. Res. Logist. 54 (7), 767–795 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • E. Adida, G. Perakis, Dynamic pricing and inventory control: robust vs. stochastic uncertainty models – a computational study. Ann. Oper. Res. 181 (1), 125–157 (2010b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. Akan, B. Ata, R.C. Savaskan-Ebert, Dynamic pricing of remanufacturable products under demand substitution: a product life cycle model. Ann. Oper. Res. 211 (1), 1–25 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. Akan, B. Ata, J.D. Dana, Revenue management by sequential screening. J. Econ. Theory 159 (B), 728–774 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • B. Ata, J.D. Dana, Price discrimination on booking time. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 43 (November), 175–181 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Aviv, Y. Levin, M. Nediak, Counteracting strategic consumer behavior in dynamic pricing systems, in Consumer-Driven Demand and Operations Management Models, ed. by S. Netessine, C.S. Tang (Springer, New York, 2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • G. Aydin, S. Ziya, Pricing promotional products under upselling. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 10 (3), 360–376 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Aydin, S. Ziya, Technical note – personalized dynamic pricing of limited inventories. Oper. Res. 57 (6), 1523–1531 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • L. Baardman, M.C. Cohen, K. Panchamgam, G. Perakis, D. Segev, Scheduling promotion vehicles to boost profits. Manag. Sci. 65 (1), 55–70 (2019)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. Bansal, C. Maglaras, Dynamic pricing when customers strategically time their purchase: asymptotic optimality of a two-price policy. J. Revenue Pricing Manag. 8 (1), 42–66 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Bertsimas, S. de Boer, Dynamic pricing and inventory control for multiple products. J. Revenue Pricing Manag. 3 (4), 303–319 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Bertsimas, J. Hawkins, G. Perakis, Optimal bidding in online auctions. J. Revenue Pricing Manag. 8 (1), 21–41 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O. Besbes, I. Lobel, Intertemporal price discrimination: structure and computation of optimal policies. Manag. Sci. 61 (1), 92–110 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O. Besbes, C. Maglaras, Revenue optimization for a make-to-order queue in an uncertain market environment. Oper. Res. 57 (6), 1438–1450 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O. Besbes, C. Maglaras, Dynamic pricing with financial milestones: feedback-form policies. Manag. Sci. 58 (9), 1715–1731 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O. Besbes, A. Zeevi, Blind network revenue management. Oper. Res. 60 (6), 1537–1550 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O. Besbes, D. Iancu, N. Trichakis, Dynamic pricing under debt: spiraling distortions and efficiency losses. Manag. Sci. 64 (10), 4572–4589 (2018)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Bitran, R. Caldentey, An overview of pricing models and revenue management. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 5 (3), 203–229 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Bitran, R. Caldentey, S. Mondschein, Coordinating clearance markdown sales of seasonal products in retail chains. Oper. Res. 46 (5), 609–624 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • C. Borgs, O. Candogan, J. Chayes, I. Lobel, H. Nazerzadeh, Optimal multiperiod pricing with service guarantees. Manag. Sci. 60 (7), 1792–1811 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • T. Boyaci, G. Gallego, Coordinating pricing and inventory replenishment policies for one wholesaler and one or more geographically dispersed retailers. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 77 (2), 95–111 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • P. Bremaud, Point Processes and Queues: Martingale Dynamics (Springer Verlag, New York, 1980)

    Google Scholar 

  • G. Cachon, P. Feldman, Price commitments with strategic consumers: why it can be optimal to discount more frequently…than optimal. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 17 (3), 399–410 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G.P. Cachon, R. Swinney, Purchasing, pricing, and quick response in the presence of strategic consumers. Manag. Sci. 55 (3), 497–511 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G.P. Cachon, R. Swinney, The value of fast fashion: quick response, enhanced design, and strategic consumer behavior. Manag. Sci. 57 (4), 778–795 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R. Caldentey, G. Vulcano, Online auction and list price revenue management. Manag. Sci. 53 (5), 795–813 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R. Caldentey, Y. Liu, I. Lobel, Intertemporal pricing under minimax regret. Oper. Res. 65 (1), 104–129 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • F. Caro, J. Gallien, Clearance pricing optimization for a fast-fashion retailer. Oper. Res. 60 (6), 1404–1422 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • L.E. Celis, G. Lewis, M. Mobius, H. Nazerzadeh, Buy-it-now or take-a-chance: price discrimination through randomized auctions. Manag. Sci. 60 (12), 2927–2948 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O. Ceryan, O. Sahin, I. Duenyas, Dynamic pricing of substitutable products in the presence of capacity flexibility. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 15 (1), 86–101 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O. Ceryan, I. Duenyas, O. Sahin, Dynamic pricing and replenishment with consumer upgrades. Prod. Oper. Manag. 27 (4), 663–679 (2018)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • L.M.A. Chan, D. Simchi-Levi, J. Swann, Pricing, production, and inventory policies for manufacturing with stochastic demand and discretionary sales. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 8 (2), 149–168 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Chen, V.F. Farias, Simple policies for dynamic pricing with imperfect forecasts. Oper. Res. 61 (3), 612–624 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Chen, V.F. Farias, On the efficacy of static prices for revenue management in the face of strategic customers. Technical report, MIT, Cambridge, MA (2017)

    Google Scholar 

  • Y. Chen, V.F. Farias, Robust dynamic pricing with strategic customers. Math. Oper. Res. 43 (4), 1119–1142 (2018)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • N. Chen, G. Gallego, Welfare analysis of dynamic pricing. Manag. Sci. 65 (1), 139–151 (2019)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Chen, P. Hu, Joint pricing and inventory management with deterministic demand and costly price adjustment. Oper. Res. Lett. 40 (5), 385–389 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Chen, S. Jasin, Power of dynamic pricing in revenue management with strategic (forward-looking) customers. Technical report, University of Michigan, Ann Arbour, MI (2018)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • N. Chen, J. Nasiry, Does loss aversion preclude price variation? Manuf. Serv. Oper.Manag. (2019, forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  • Y. Chen, C. Shi, Joint pricing and inventory management with strategic customers. Oper. Res. (2019, forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  • X. Chen, D. Simchi-Levi, Coordinating inventory control and pricing strategies with random demand and fixed ordering cost: the infinite horizon case. Math. Oper. Res. 29 (3), 698–723 (2004a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Chen, D. Simchi-Levi, Coordinating inventory control and pricing strategies with random demand and fixed ordering cost: the finite horizon case. Oper. Res. 52 (6), 887–896 (2004b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Chen, D. Simchi-Levi, Coordinating inventory control and pricing strategies with random demand and fixed ordering cost: the continuous review model. Oper. Res. Lett. 34 (3), 323–332 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Chen, D. Simchi-Levi, Pricing and inventory management, in The Oxford Handbook of Pricing Management, ed. by R. Phillips, O. Ozer (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2012), pp. 784–822

    Google Scholar 

  • X. Chen, S. Zhou, F. Chen, Integration of inventory and pricing decisions with costly price adjustments. Oper. Res. 59 (5), 1144–1158 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Chen, Z. Pang, L. Pan, Coordinating inventory control and pricing strategies for perishable products. Oper. Res. 62 (2), 284–300 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Q. Chen, S. Jasin, I. Duenyas, Real-time dynamic pricing with minimal and flexible price adjustments. Manag. Sci. 62 (8), 2437–2455 (2016b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Chen, P. Hu, S. Shum, Y. Zhang, Dynamic stochastic inventory management with reference price effects. Oper. Res. 64 (6), 1529–1536 (2016c)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Chen, P. Hu, Z. Hu, Efficient algorithms for dynamic pricing problem with reference price effect. Manag. Sci. 63 (12), 4389–4408 (2017b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • H. Chen, M. Hu, J. Wu, Intertemporal price discrimination via randomized pricing. Technical report, University of Toronto, Toronto, ON (2018a)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • M. Cohen, S. Gupta, J. Kalas, G. Perakis, An efficient algorithm for dynamic pricing using a graphical representation. Technical report, MIT, Cambridge, MA (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • M. Cohen, J. Kalas, G. Perakis, Optimizing promotions for multiple items in supermarkets. Technical report, MIT, Cambridge, MA (2017a)

    Google Scholar 

  • M.C. Cohen, N.-H.Z. Leung, K. Panchamgam, G. Perakis, A. Smith, The impact of linear optimization on promotion planning. Oper. Res. 65 (2), 446–468 (2017c)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. Cohen, R. Lobel, G. Perakis, Dynamic pricing through data sampling. Prod. Oper. Manag. 27 (6), 1074–1088 (2018b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • W. Elmahraby, P. Keskinocak, Dynamic pricing in the presence of inventory considerations: research overview, current practices, and future directions. Manag. Sci. 49 (10), 1287–1309 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • A. Federgruen, A. Heching, Combined pricing and inventory control under uncertainty. Oper. Res. 47 (3), 454–475 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Feng, G. Gallego, Optimal starting times of end-of-season sales and optimal stopping times for promotional fares. Manag. Sci. 41 (8), 1371–1391 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Feng, G. Gallego, Perishable asset revenue management with Markovian time-dependent demand intensities. Manag. Sci. 46 (7), 941–956 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • K.J. Ferreira, B.H.A. Lee, D. Simchi-Levi, Analytics for an online retailer: demand forecasting and price optimization. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 18 (1), 69–88 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Gallego, G. van Ryzin, Optimal dynamic pricing of inventories with stochastic demand over finite horizons. Manag. Sci. 40 (8), 999–1020 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Gallego, G.J. van Ryzin, A multiple product dynamic pricing problem and its applications to network yield management. Oper. Res. 45 (1), 24–41 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Gallego, R. Phillips, O. Sahin, Strategic management of distressed inventories. Prod. Oper. Manag. 17 (4), 402–415 (2008b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Gallego, A. Li, V.A. Truong, X. Wang, Online personalized resource allocation with customer choice. Technical report, Columbia University, New York, NY (2016c)

    Google Scholar 

  • G. Gallego, M.Z.F. Li, Y. Liu, Dynamic nonlinear pricing of inventories over finite sales horizons. Technical report, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Hong Kong (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  • J. Gallien, Dynamic mechanism design for online commerce. Manag. Sci. 54 (2), 291–310 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • I.I. Gihman, A.V. Skorohod, Controlled Stochastic Processes (Springer Verlag, New York, 1979)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • N. Golrezaei, H. Nazerzadeh, Auctions with dynamic costly information acquisition. Oper. Res. 65 (1), 130–144 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • N. Golrezaei, H. Nazerzadeh, R. Randhawa, Dynamic pricing for heterogeneous time-sensitive customers. Technical report, University of Southern California, Los Angeles, CA (2017)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • A. Heching, G. Gallego, G.J. van Ryzin, Markdown pricing: an empirical analysis of policies and revenue potential at one apparel retailer. J. Pricing Revenue Manag. 1 (2), 139–160 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Hu, W.J. Hopp, Price trends in a dynamic pricing model with heterogeneous customers: a martingale perspective. Oper. Res. 57 (5), 1298–1302 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Z. Hu, X. Chen, P. Hu, Technical note – dynamic pricing with gain-seeking reference price effects. Oper. Res. 64 (1), 150–157 (2016b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • S.M. Kakade, I. Lobel, H. Nazerzadeh, Optimal dynamic mechanism design and the virtual-pivot mechanism. Oper. Res. 61 (4), 837–854 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Kanoria, H. Nazerzadeh, Dynamic reserve prices for repeated auctions: learning from bids, in Web and Internet Economics, ed. by T.-Y. Lie, Q. Qi (Springer International Publishing, Beijing, 2014), pp. 232–232

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • S. Kunnumkal, H. Topaloglu, A stochastic approximation algorithm for making pricing decisions in network revenue management problems. J. Revenue Pricing Manag. 9 (5), 419–442 (2010b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • C.W. Kuo, H.S. Ahn, G. Aydin, Dynamic pricing of limited inventories when customers negotiate. Oper. Res. 59 (4), 882–897 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Lei, S. Jasin, A. Sinha, Joint dynamic pricing and order fulfillment for e-commerce retailers. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 20 (2), 269–284 (2018)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Levin, J. McGill, M. Nediak, Price guarantees in dynamic pricing and revenue management. Oper. Res. 55 (1), 75–97 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Levin, J. McGill, M. Nediak, Risk in revenue management and dynamic pricing. Oper. Res. 56 (2), 326–343 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Levin, J. McGill, M. Nediak, Optimal dynamic pricing of perishable items by a monopolist facing strategic consumers. Prod. Oper. Manag. 19 (1), 40–60 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Levin, M. Nediak, A. Bazhanov, Quantity premiums and discounts in dynamic pricing. Oper. Res. 62 (4), 846–863 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • T. Levina, Y. Levin, J. McGill, M. Nediak, Dynamic pricing with online learning and strategic consumers: an application of the aggregating algorithm. Oper. Res. 57 (2), 327–341 (2009a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • T. Levina, Y. Levin, J. McGill, M. Nediak, Strategic consumer cooperation in a name-your-own-price channel. Prod. Oper. Manag. 24 (12), 1883–1900 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • H. Li, W.T. Huh, Optimal pricing for short life-cycle products when customer price sensitivity varies over time. Nav. Res. Logist. 59 (7), 552–576 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • W.S. Lim, C.S. Tang, An auction model arising from an internet search service provider. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 172 (3), 956–970 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • W.S. Lim, C.S. Tang, Optimal dynamic pricing strategies in the presence of speculators and forward looking consumers: are speculators friends or foes? Prod. Oper. Manag. 22 (3), 571–587 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Liu, W.L. Cooper, Optimal dynamic pricing with patient customers. Oper. Res. 63 (6), 1307–1319 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Q. Liu, G.J. van Ryzin, Strategic capacity rationing to induce early purchases. Manag. Sci. 54 (6), 1115–1131 (2008b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Q. Liu, G.J. van Ryzin, Strategic capacity rationing when customers learn. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 13 (1), 89–107 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • I. Lobel, Dynamic pricing with heterogeneous patience levels. Technical report, New York University, New York, NY (2017)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • C. Maglaras, J. Meissner, Dynamic pricing strategies for multiproduct revenue management problems. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 8 (2), 135–148 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • P.R. McAfee, V. te Velde, Dynamic pricing with constant demand elasticity. Prod. Oper. Manag. 17 (4), 432–438 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • A. Mersereau, D. Zhang, Markdown pricing with unknown fraction of strategic customers. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 14 (3), 355–370 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • J. Nasiry, I. Popescu, Advance selling when consumers regret. Manag. Sci. 58 (6), 1160–1177 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • N. Osadchiy, G. Vulcano, Selling with binding reservations in the presence of strategic consumers. Manag. Sci. 56 (12), 2173–2190 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O. Ozer, Y. Zheng, Markdown or everyday low price: the role of behavioral motives. Manag. Sci. 62 (2), 326–346 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • A.G. Sogomonian, C.S. Tang, A modeling framework for coordinating promotion and production decisions within a firm. Manag. Sci. 39 (2), 191–203 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Y. Song, S. Ray, T. Boyaci, Technical note: optimal dynamic joint inventory-pricing control for multiplicative demand with fixed order costs and lost sales. Oper. Res. 57 (1), 245–250 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • N. Surasvadi, C. Tang, G. Vulcano, Using contingent markdown with reservation to profit from strategic consumer behavior. Prod. Oper. Manag. 26 (12), 2226–2246 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G.J. van Ryzin, G. Vulcano, Optimal auctioning and ordering in an infinite horizon inventory-pricing system. Oper. Res. 52 (3), 346–367 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Vulcano, G.J. van Ryzin, C. Maglaras, Optimal dynamic auctions for revenue management. Manag. Sci. 48 (11), 1388–1407 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Z. Wang, Technical note – intertemporal price discrimination via reference price effects. Oper. Res. 64 (2), 290–296 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Z. Wang, Y. Ye, Hidden-city ticketing: the cause and impact. Transp. Sci. 50 (1), 288–305 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • J. Wang, Y. Levin, M. Nediak, Selling passes to strategic customers. Technical report, Queen’s University, Kingston (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  • R. Yin, Y. Aviv, A. Pazgal, and C.S. Tang. Optimal markdown pricing: implications of inventory display formats in the presence of strategic customers. Manag. Sci. 55 (8), 1391–1422 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Zhang, W.L. Cooper, Managing clearance sales in the presence of strategic customers. Prod. Oper. Manag. 17 (4), 416–431 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Zhang, W. Cooper, Pricing substitutable flights in airline revenue management. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 197 (3), 848–861 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Zhang, R. Kallesen, Incorporating competitive price information in revenue management. J. Revenue Pricing Manag. 7, 17–26 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Zhang, Z. Lu, Assessing the value of dynamic pricing in network revenue management. INFORMS J. Comput. 25 (1), 102–115 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Zhang, L. Weatherford, Dynamic pricing for network revenue management: a new approach and application in the hotel industry. INFORMS J. Comput. 29 (1), 18–35 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Theorem 9.3

Notice that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial V(t,x)}{\partial t} = \mathcal{R}_t(\varDelta V(t,x)) \geq 0,\end{aligned}$$

with the inequality strict as long as d t(p) > 0 for some p > ΔV (t, x), or equivalently if \(\varDelta V(t,x) < \bar {r}_t\). This shows that V (t, x) is increasing in t. To show that V (t, x + 1) ≥ V (t, x), consider a sample path argument where the system with x + 1 units of inventory uses the optimal policy for the system with x units of inventory until either the system with x units runs out of stock or time runs out. If the system with x units of inventory runs out at time s, then the system with x + 1 units of inventory can still collect V (s, 1) ≥ 0. On the other hand, if time runs out, the two systems collect the same revenue. Consequently, the system with x + 1 units of inventory makes at least as much revenue resulting in V (t, x + 1) ≥ V (t, x).

Clearly ΔV (t, 1) ≤ ΔV (t, 0) = ∞. Assume as the inductive hypothesis that ΔV (t, y) is decreasing in y ≤ x for all t ≥ 0. We want to show that ΔV (t, x + 1) ≤ ΔV (t, x), or equivalently that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} V(t,x+1) + V(t,x-1) \leq V(t,x) + V(t,x). \end{aligned} $$
(9.22)

We will use a sample path argument to construct the establish inequality (9.22). Consider four systems, one with x + 1 units of inventory, one with x − 1 units of inventory, and two with x units of inventory. Assume that we follow the optimal policy for the system with x + 1 and for the system with x − 1 that are on the left hand side of inequality (9.22). For the two systems on the right, we use the sub-optimal policies designed for x + 1 and x − 1 units of inventory, respectively. We follow these policies until one of the following events occurs: time runs out, the difference in inventories for the systems on the left drops to 1, or the inventory of the system with x − 1 units drops to zero. After that time, we follow optimal policies for all four systems.

To establish inequality (9.22), we will show that the revenues obtained for the systems in the right are at least as large as for the systems on the left, even though sub-optimal policies are used for the systems in the right. This is obviously true if we run out of time since the realized revenues of the two systems on the right are exactly equal to the realized revenues from the two systems on the left. Assume now that at time s ∈ (0, t), the difference in inventories of the two systems on the left hand side drops to 1, so that the states are (s, y + 1) and (s, y) for some y < x. This means that system on the left with x + 1 units of inventory had x − y units of sale and the system with x − 1 units of inventory had x − 1 − y units of sale. This implies that the system on the right that was following the policy designed for x + 1 reaches state (s, y), while the system that was using the policy designed for x − 1 reaches state (s, y + 1). Clearly, the additional optimal expected revenues over [0, s] for each pair of systems are V (s, y + 1) + V (s, y) = V (s, y) + V (s, y + 1), showing that the system on the right gets as much revenue as the system on the left even if sub-optimal policies are used for part of the horizon. Finally, if the inventory of the system with x − 1 units of inventory drops to 0 at some time s ∈ [0, t), so that state of the systems on the left are, respectively, (s, y) and (s, 0) for some y, such that 1 < y ≤ x, while the systems on the right are (s, y − 1) and (s, 1). From the inductive hypothesis, we know that ΔV (s, y) ≤ ΔV (s, 1) for all y ≤ x and all s ≤ t. Consequently,

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}V(s,y) + V(s,0) \leq V(s,y-1) + V(s,1),\end{aligned}$$

and once again the pair of systems on the right result in at least as much revenue even though sub-optimal policies are used for part of the sales horizon.

We now show that ΔV (t, x) is increasing in t. This is equivalent to

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial V(t,x)}{\partial t} = \mathcal{R}_t(\varDelta V(t,x)) \geq \mathcal{R}_t(\varDelta V(t,x-1)) = \frac{\partial V(t,x-1)}{\partial t},\end{aligned}$$

but this is true on account of \(\mathcal {R}_t(z)\) being decreasing in z and ΔV (t, x) being decreasing in x. We now show that P(t, x) = p t(ΔV (t, x)) is decreasing in x. This follows because p t(z) is increasing in z and ΔV (t, x) is decreasing in x.

Clearly, P(t, x) = p t(ΔV (t, x)) is also increasing in t provided that p t(z) is increasing in t since ΔV (t, x) is also increasing in t and p t(z) is increasing in z. Clearly, p t(z) = p(z) holds if d t(p) = d(p) for all t. Moreover, if h t(p) is decreasing in t, then p t(z) is the root of the equation (p − z)h t(p) = 1, and this is increasing in t.

We now show that V (t, x) is strictly increasing in t if \(\varDelta V(t,x) < \bar {r}_t\). This follows because

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial V(t,x)}{\partial t} = \mathcal{R}_t(\varDelta V(t,x)) >0,\end{aligned}$$

as any price \(p \in (\varDelta V(t,x), \bar {r}_t)\) returns a positive profit. Notice that this is automatically true if p t(z) is increasing in z because

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial V(t,x)}{\partial t} = \mathcal{R}_t(\varDelta V(t,x)) \geq \mathcal{R}_t(\varDelta V(t,1)) = \mathcal{R}_t(V(t,1)) > 0,\end{aligned}$$

where the first inequality follows because \(\mathcal {R}_t\) is decreasing and V (t, 1) = ΔV (t, 1) ≥ ΔV (t, x) for all x ≥ 1. The strict inequality follows because \(V(t,1) < \bar {r}_t\), as otherwise the single unit must sell with probability one at the choke-off point, but by definition the demand at the choke-off point is zero. Consequently, there is a p t > V (t, 1) with d t(p) > 0 implying that \(\mathcal {R}_t(V(t,1)) > 0\).

To show that V (t, x) is concave, notice that if \(\mathcal {R}_t(z)\) is differentiable, then

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial^2 V(t,x)}{\partial t^2} = \mathcal{R}^{\prime}_t(\varDelta V(t,x)) \frac{\partial \varDelta V(t,x)}{\partial t} \leq 0,\end{aligned}$$

follows since \(\mathcal {R}^{\prime }_t(z) \leq 0\), on account of \(\mathcal {R}_t(z)\) being decreasing in z, and from the fact that ΔV (t, x) is increasing in t.

Proof of Proposition 9.11

Recall that \(\bar {V}(t,x) = \int _0^t \mathcal {R}_s(z(t,x))ds + xz(t,x)\). Since \(\mathcal {R}_t(z)\) is continuously differentiable, either z(t, x) = 0 or z(t, x) > 0 is the root of \(\int _0^td_s(p_s(z(t.x)))ds = x\). If z(t, x) = 0, then \(\bar {V}(t,x) = \int _0^t \mathcal {R}_s(0)ds\), so

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial \bar{V}(t,x)}{\partial t} = \mathcal{R}_t(0).\end{aligned}$$

On the other hand, if z(t, x) > 0, then

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial \bar{V}(t,x)}{\partial t} = \mathcal{R}_t(z(t,x)) + [x - \int_0^td_s(p_s(z(t,x))dt] \frac{\partial z(t,x)}{\partial t} = \mathcal{ R}_t(z(t,x))\end{aligned}$$

since the last term cancels on account of \(\int _0^td_s(p_s(z(t,x))dt = x\). Let ∂G(t, x)∕∂x = z(t, x). Then

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial \bar{V}(t,x)}{\partial t} = \mathcal{R}_t\left (\frac{\partial G(t,x)}{\partial t}\right) = \frac{\partial G(t,x)}{\partial t}.\end{aligned}$$

Since the boundary conditions \(\bar {V}(t,0) = G(t, 0) = \bar {V}(0,x) = G(0,x) = 0\), it follows that \(\bar {V}(t,x) = G(t,x)\) as claimed.

Proof of Theorem 9.12

For ease of exposition, we will give the proof of Theorem 9.12 for the case of a single market with Poisson, rather than compound Poisson demands. However, the proof holds as stated. Clearly \(V^h_b(T,c) \leq V_b(T,c) \leq \overline {V}_b(T,c)\). The idea of the proof is to show that the difference \(\overline {V}_b(T,c) -V^h_b(T,c)\) becomes negligible relative to \(V^h_b(T,c)\). First, notice that scaling arrival rates and demands does not change z(T, c) or the bid-price policy P(t, x) = p t(Z(T, c)). To evaluate \(V^h_b(T,c)\) let t = T − s be the time-to-go for each s ∈ [0, T]. The bid-price at time s is q s = P T−s(z(T, c)). The demand intensity at s is γ s = d T−s(P T−s(z(T, c)). Let N s be a Poisson process with intensity \(\varGamma _s = \int _0^s\gamma _s ds\), and let τ c be the first time the process reaches c, i.e. \(\tau _c = \inf \{s \geq 0: N_s = c\}\). The bid-price policy earns revenues at rate q s dN s until time \(\min (T,\tau _c)\), so

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}V^f_b(T,c) = \mathbb E\Bigg\{ \int_0^{\min(T,\tau_c)}q_sdN_s \Bigg\} = \mathbb E\Bigg\{\int_0^{\min(T,\tau_c)}q_s\gamma_sds \Bigg\}\end{aligned}$$

where the equality follows from Watanabe’s characterization of Poisson processes, see Bremaud (1980). Let \(\varTheta _s = \int _0^s \theta _udu\), where θ u = q u γ u, also let \(\bar {\theta } = \max _{0 \leq u \leq T}\theta _u\). Then

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}V^f_b(T,c) = \varTheta_T - \mathbb E[\varTheta_T - \varTheta_{\min(T,\tau_c)}] \geq \varTheta_T - \bar{\theta} {\,} \mathbb E(T-\tau_c)^+.\end{aligned}$$

On the other hand, we can write

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\bar{V}(T,c) = \varTheta_T - (\varGamma_T -c)z(T,c) .\end{aligned}$$

The result follows since the gap between \(\bar {\theta } \mathbb E(T - \tau _c)^+ - (\varGamma _T - c)z(T,c)\) grows as the square root of b while the lower bound grows linearly with b.

Proof of Theorem 9.13

Our plan is to construct a heuristic with expected revenue V m(T, c) such that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{V(T,c)}{\bar{V}(T,c)} \geq \frac{V^m(T,c)}{\bar{V}(T,c)} \geq \frac{1}{2}.\end{aligned}$$

Let

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\bar{\pi} = \bar{V}(T,c) = \min_{z \geq 0}\left(\int_0^T \mathcal{R}_t(z)dt + zc\right),\end{aligned}$$

and set \(z = 0.5\bar {\pi }/c\). Clearly

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\bar{\pi} = \bar{V}(T,c) \leq \int_0^T \mathcal{R}_t(0.5\bar{\pi}/c)dt + 0.5 \bar{\pi},\end{aligned}$$

so

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}0.5 \bar{\pi} \leq \int_0^T \mathcal{R}_t(0.5\bar{\pi}/c)dt.\end{aligned}$$

Consider a heuristic policy that prices at \(p_s(0.5 \bar {\pi }/c), 0 \leq s \leq T\), and let V m(T, x) be its expected revenue. We will show that \(V^m(T,c) \geq 0.5 \bar {\pi }\). Suppose for a contradiction that \(V^m(T,c) < 0.5 \bar {\pi }\). Then,

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}V^m(T,c) < 0.5 \bar{\pi} \leq \int_0^T \mathcal{R}_t(0.5\bar{\pi}/c)dt.\end{aligned}$$

We will show that in fact \(V^m(T,c) \geq \int _{0}^{T} \mathcal {R}_{t}(0.5\bar {\pi }/c)dt\). Notice that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}0.5 \bar{\pi} > V^m(T,c) = \sum_{x=1}^c \varDelta V^m(T,x),\end{aligned}$$

and since ΔV m(T, x) is decreasing in x, it follows that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\varDelta V^m(T,c) \leq V^m(T,c)/c < 0.5 \bar{\pi}/c.\end{aligned}$$

But then

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{array}{rcl} V^m(T,c) &\displaystyle = &\displaystyle \int_0^T R_t(p_t(0.5 \bar{\pi}/c), \varDelta V^m(t,c))dt \pm 0.5 \bar{\pi}/c \int_0^T d_t(p_t(0.5 \bar{\pi}/c))dt\\ {} &\displaystyle = &\displaystyle \int_0^T \mathcal{R}_t(0.5 \bar{\pi}/c)dt + \int_0^T[0.5 \bar{\pi}/c - \varDelta V^m(t,c)]d_t(p_t(0.5 \bar{\pi}/c))dt\\ {} &\displaystyle \geq &\displaystyle \int_0^T \mathcal{R}_t(0.5 \bar{\pi}/c)dt, \end{array} \end{aligned} $$

where the inequality follows because \(0.5 \bar {\pi }/c > \varDelta V^h(t,c)\) for all t, since ΔV h(t, c) is increasing in t and the result holds at T. This shows that the assumption that \(V^m(T,c) <0.5 \bar {V}(T,c)\) leads to a contradiction so it must be that \(V^m(T,c) \geq 0.5 \bar {V}(T,c)\).

Proof of Theorem 9.14

Because d t(p) = d(p) is continuous and o(1∕p), there exists a p t(z) = p(z) for all z ≥ 0 that maximizes R t(p, z) = (p − z)d t(p) for all t ∈ [0, T]. Let \(y = \int _0^T d_t(p(0))dt = T d(p(0))\). If y < c, then z(T, c) = 0 is optimal and the upper bound is \(T\mathcal {R}(0) = y p(0)\). The bid-price heuristic would price at p t = p(0) for all t ∈ (0, T] and would face Poisson demand with parameter y over [0, T], resulting in expected revenue \(\min (c, \mbox{Poisson}(y))p(0)\). The ratio is therefore

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{V^h(T,c)}{V(T,c)} \geq \frac{V^h(T,c)}{\bar{V}(T,c)} = \frac{\mathbb E\min(c,\mbox{Poisson}(y))}{y}\end{aligned}$$

with y < c. On the other hand, if c ≥ y, then the assumed properties of d(p) guarantee the existence of a z = z(T, c) > 0 such that Td(p(z)) = c, so the upper bound yields cp(z) while the lower bound yields \(\mathbb E\min (c,\mbox{Poisson}(c))p(z)\). Thus, the ratio is given by

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned}\frac{V^h(T,c)}{V(T,c)} \geq \frac{V^h(T,c)}{\bar{V}(T,c)} = \frac{\mathbb E\min(c,\mbox{Poisson}(c))}{c}.\end{aligned}$$

It is well known that these ratios are bounded below by 1 − 1∕e.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Gallego, G., Topaloglu, H. (2019). Dynamic Pricing Over Finite Horizons. In: Revenue Management and Pricing Analytics. International Series in Operations Research & Management Science, vol 279. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4939-9606-3_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics