Skip to main content
Log in

A Theory of Profit and Competition

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Starting from the observation that surplus-value is almost always due to the collective undertaking of non-additively separable human capital investments, this paper proposes a theory of the institutional structure of production in the Coasean definition of firms and markets. Rather than being based on the extension of the logic of exchange to property rights, however, the paper attempts to combine institutional and evolutionary elements in light of the classic issues of value and distribution. The main result, in effect, is that monopoly profit is not the only meaningful notion of profit besides the value of individual contribution, and consequently that free entry and competition do not wipe it out. The reason is that in this context, the incumbent’s profit does not arise from some form of scarcity but from the collective nature of the production process. Therefore, the entrant has no incentives to undercut because he can earn the same profit by doing exactly the same thing. Naturally, this fairly favourable condition should not be taken for granted since, when non additive separability is combined with wealth effects, this kind of profit may give rise to structurally inefficient conflicts over the terms of both its production and distribution. In particular, this is shown to happen when the type of investments is such that the individual participation constraint ensuring that investments are made is satisfied at minimum cost when expressed in terms of the amount workers can earn from independent participation in the production process (rather than in terms of the value of the product). In this case, it turns out that profit will be appropriated by entrepreneurs (rather than shared), property rights will be concentrated (rather than distributed), and the subsequent development of the techno-economic paradigm of which the investments are meant to form a stylized representation is inhibited (rather than favoured).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Acemoglou, D. (2003) “Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics,” Journal of Comparative Economics 31.4: 620–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A. (1950) “Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory,” Journal of Political Economy 58.3: 211–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A. and H. Demsetz (1972) “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization,” The American Economic Review 62.5: 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. (1832) On the Economy of Machinery and Manufactures, Charles Knight, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (1987) “The Entrepreneur’s Reward for Self-Policing,” Economic Inquiry 25.1: 103–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battistini, A. (2006) The Role of Inter-group Relationships in Institutional Analysis, Quaderni del Dipartimento di Economia Politica, Università di Siena, October, no. 487.

  • Battistini, A. (2011) From Asymmetric Information to Social Knowledge: A Game-Theoretic Example of Strategic vs. Bayesian Beliefs’ Updating, Quaderni del Dipartimento di Economia Politica, Università di Siena, December, no. 630.

  • Battistini, A. (2013) “A Note on the Difference between Human and Non-Human Productive Factors: Comments on ‘Love, War and Culture: An Institutional Approach to Human Evolution’,” Journal of Bioeconomics 15.1: 67–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1962) “Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis,” Journal of Political Economy 70.2: 9–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borgerhoff Mulder, M., S. Bowles, T. Hertz, A. Bell, J. Beise, G. Clark, I. Fazzio, M. Gurven, K. Hill, P. L. Hooper, W. Irons, H. Kaplan, D. Leonetti, B. Low, F. Marlowe, R. McElreath, S. Naidu, D. Nolin, P. Piraino, R. Quinlan, E. Schniter, R. Sear, M. Shenk, E. A. Smith, C. von Rueden and P. Wiessner (2009) “Intergenerational Transmission of Wealth and the Dynamics of Inequality in Small-Scale Societies,” Science 326.5953: 682–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, R. and P. J. Richerson (1985) Culture and the Evolutionary Process, Chicago University Press.

  • Bowles, S. (2004) Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution, Princeton University Press.

  • Bowles, S. and H. Gintis (2011) A Cooperative Species, Princeton University Press.

  • Braverman, H. (1974) Labour and Monopoly Capital. The Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century, Monthly Review Press.

  • Calabresi, G. (1991) “The Pointlessness of Pareto: Carrying Coase Further,” The Yale Law Journal 100.5: 1211–1237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937) “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica 4.16: 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960) “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law Economics and Organization 3.1: 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1992) “The Institutional Structure of Production,” The American Economic Review 82.4: 713–719.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (2000) “The Acquisition of Fisher Body by General Motors,” Journal of Law and Economics 43.1: 15–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eldredge, N. and S. J. Gould (1972) “Punctuated Equilibrium: An Alternative to Philetic Gradualism,” in T. J. M. Schopf (ed.) Models in Paleobiology, Freeman Cooper, San Francisco, pp. 82–115.

  • Elster, J. (1982) Making Sense of Marx, Cambridge University Press.

  • Freeman, C. and F. Louca (2001) As Time Goes By: From the Industrial Revolutions to the Information Revolution, Oxford University Press.

  • Garicano, L. and T. Hubbard (2003) Specialization, Firms, and Markets: The Division of Labour within and between Firms, Mimeo, University of Chicago, Graduate School of Business.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ghiselin, M. T. (1995) “Perspective: Darwin, Progress, and Economic Principles,” Evolution; International Journal of Organic Evolution 49.6: 1029–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilboa, I. and D. Schmeidler (1989) “Maxmin Expected Utility with Non-Unique Priors,” Journal of Mathematical Economics 18.2: 141–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P. A. and D. Soskice (2001) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Oxford University Press.

  • Hart, O. (1995) Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure, Oxford University Press.

  • Hayek, F. A. (1967) Studies in Philosophy, Politics, and Economics, Routledge and Kegan Paul, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, J. (2004) “Cultural Group Selection, Coevolutionary Processes and Large-Scale Cooperation,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 53.1: 3–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgskin, T. (1825) [1969] Labour Defended against the Claims of Capital, A. M. Kelley Publishers, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. (2007) “Meanings of Methodological Individualism,” Journal of Economic Methodology 14.2: 211–2226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. and T. Knudsen (2006) “Why We Need a Generalized Darwinism and Why a Generalized Darwinism is Not Enough,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 61.1: 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, A. (1972) “The Economics and Politics of Consumer Sovereignty,” The American Economic Review 62.3: 258–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, J. and S. Tadelis (2005) “Profit Sharing and the Role of Professional Partnerships,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 120.1: 131–171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (1982) Phases of Capitalistic Development, Cambridge University Press.

  • Marglin, S. A. (1974) “What Do Bosses Do? The Origins and Function of Hierarchy,” The Review of Radical Political Economics 6.2: 60–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marglin, S. A. and J. B. Schor (1992) The Golden Age of Capitalism: Reintepreting the Postwar Experience, Oxford University Press.

  • Marx, K. (1867) [1967] Capital I, International Publishers, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matthews, R. C. O. (1986) “The Economics of Institutions and the Sources of Growth,” The Economic Journal 96.384: 903–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1990a) “Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs, and the Organization of Economic Activity,” in J. E. Alt and K. A. Shepsle (eds.) Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, Cambridge University Press, pp.57–89.

  • Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1990b) “The Economics of Modern Manufacturing: Technology, Strategy, and Organization,” The American Economic Review 80.3: 511–528.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1992) Economics, Organization, and Management, Prentice Hall Inc.

  • Mokyr, J. (2002) The Gifts of Athena. Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy, Princeton University Press.

  • Mokyr, J. (2005) “Long-Term Economic Growth and the History of Technology,” in P. Aghion, S. Durlauf (eds.) Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier, pp. 1113–1178.

  • Pagano, U. (1991) “Property Rights, Asset Specificity, and Division of Labour under Alternative Capitalist Relations,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 15.3: 315–341.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pagano, U. (2007) “Karl Marx after New Institutional Economics,” Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review 4.1: 27–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perez, C. (2002) Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital: The Dynamics of Bubble and Golden Ages, Oxford University Press.

  • Rajan, R. G. and L. Zingales (1998) “Power in a Theory of the Firm,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 113.2: 387–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robertson, D. (1923) The Control of Industry, Cambridge University Press.

  • Romer, P. M. (1990) “Endogenous Technological Change,” Journal of Political Economy 98.5: 7–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1987) “Human Capital,” The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, The Stockton Press, pp. 681–689.

  • Rowthorn, R. (1974) “Neo-Classicism, Neo-Ricardianism, and Marxism,” New Left Review 86: 63–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1957) “Wages and Interest: A Modern Dissection of Marxian Economics,” The American Economic Review 47.5: 884–912.

    Google Scholar 

  • Searle, J. (2001) Rationality in Action, MIT Press.

  • Searle, J. (2005) “What Is an Institution?” Journal of Institutional Economics 1.1: 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sober, E. and D. S. Wilson (1999) Unto Others. The Evolution and Psychology of Unselfish Behavior, Harvard University Press.

  • Screpanti, E. (2011) “Globalization and the Great Crisis,” in E. Brancaccio and G. Fontana (eds.) The Global Economic Crisis: New Perspectives on the Critique of Economic Theory and Policy, London, Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ure, A. (1835) The Philosophy of Manufactures, Charles Knight, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vehrencamp, S. (1983) “A Model for the Evolution of Despotic versus Egalitarian Societies,” Animal Behaviour 31.3: 667–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wald, A. (1950) Statistical Decision Functions, Wiley, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, Free Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alberto Battistini.

Additional information

1) I wish to thank Carlo Beretta, Sam Bowles, Marco Dardi, Michael Ghiselin, Herbert Gintis, Ugo Pagano, Fabio Petri, Bob Rowthorn, Ernesto Screpanti, and two anonymous referees for their useful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimers apply.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Battistini, A. A Theory of Profit and Competition. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 10, 269–294 (2013). https://doi.org/10.14441/eier.A2013014

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.14441/eier.A2013014

Keywords

JEL

Navigation