Skip to main content
Log in

The Equilibrium Real Funds Rate: Past, Present, and Future

  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine the behavior, determinants, and implications of the equilibrium level of the real federal funds rate, interpreted as the long run or steady state value of the real funds rate. We draw three main conclusions. First, the uncertainty around the equilibrium rate is large, and its relationship with trend GDP growth much more tenuous than widely believed. Our narrative and econometric analysis using cross-country data and going back to the 19th century supports a wide range of plausible estimates for the current level of the equilibrium rate, from a little over 0 per cent to the pre-crisis consensus of 2 per cent. Second, a bivariate vector error correction model that looks only to U.S. and world real rates well captures the behavior of U.S. real rates. The model treats real rates as cointegrated unit root processes. As of the end of our sample (2014), the model forecasts the real rate in the U.S. will asymptote to an equilibrium value of a little less than half a percent by 2021. Consistent with our first point, however, confidence intervals around this point estimate are huge. Third, the uncertainty around the equilibrium rate argues for more “inertial” monetary policy than implied by standard versions of the Taylor rule. Our simulations using the Fed staff’s FRB/US model show that explicit recognition of this uncertainty results in a later but steeper normalization path for the funds rate compared with the median “dot” in the FOMC’s Summary of Economic Projections.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6
Figure 7
Figure 8
Figure 9

Note: This figure plots the quarterly data in Table 4.

Figure 10

Note: This figure plots the annual data in Table 4.

Figure 11

Note: The two digit label identifies the observation corresponding to the fourth quarter of that year. For example, “08” labels the 2008:4 observation: over the 40 quarter period 1999:1–2008:4, the average value of r and GDP growth were average r = 1.08, average GDP growth = 2.14. See notes to Table 6.

Figure 12

Note: See notes to Table 6.

Figure 13

Note: This exhibit plots the data listed in Table 7. See notes to Table 7. Mnemonics for country names are given in Table 2.

Figure 14
Figure 15
Figure 16
Figure 17
Figure 18

Note: Dashed: 1 per cent critical value if test were only performed at a single date (6.63). Solid: 1 per cent critical value if the maximal statistic over the range 1900–1976 were used (11.28, from Andrews (2003)). Top panel: U.S. real interest rate \( r_{US,t} ; \) middle panel: long-run world rate \( \ell_{t} ; \) bottom panel: difference between U.S. real rate and long-run world rate \( (r_{US,t} - \ell_{t} ). \)

Figure 19
Figure 20
Figure 21
Figure 22
Figure 23
Figure 24
Figure 25
Figure 26

Note: Arrows indicate optimal inertia coefficients. *Relative to no-misperception optimum.

Figure 27

Note: Arrows indicate optimal inertia coefficients. *Relative to no-misperception optimum.

Figure 28

Note: Arrows indicate optimal inertia coefficients. *Relative to no-misperception optimum.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Values of the 3 separate U.S. series are very close to each other at the dates at which they were spliced together.

  2. Our data set is largely identical to Hatzius et al. (2014) and mainly comes from the Global Financial Data Inc. database, supplemented with information from Haver Analytics. In most cases, the short-term interest rate series is a central bank discount rate (known as bank rate in UK parlance) or an overnight cash or repo rate. When more than one series is used for the same country because of changes over time in definitions and market structure, we splice the series using the discount rate as the basis.

  3. In preliminary work, we also experimented with keeping the window size fixed at 40 quarters through the whole sample. This led to a very similar series; the correlation was 0.98 between the expected inflation series with a 40 quarter window and the Eq. (2.3) version that we actually used.

  4. Using a different approach, Leduc and Rudebusch (2014) also conclude the link in the U.S. is weak.

  5. This is consistent with the formal econometric work of Clark and Kozicki (2005, p. 403), who conclude that the link between trend growth and the equilibrium real rate is “quantitatively weak.”

  6. Indeed, in “Implications for Future Real Rates” section we use a model that relies on a conventional link between real rates and growth.

  7. Elliott and Müller (2006) noted that departures from stationarity, whether in the form of structural breaks, unit roots, or time-varying parameters, can be embedded into a single unifying framework, and that, from the perspective of efficient tests of the null hypothesis, the seemingly different approaches are in fact equivalent. In most of what follows we will be using a finite number of structural breaks as specification of the alternative hypothesis against which the null of stationarity is being tested.

  8. Using a second-order autoregression for levels allows us to include as a special case a first-order autoregression for growth rates as one of the possible specifications that we will be considering.

  9. The test statistic using 5 lags and a constant is 0.55 for a p value of 0.025.

  10. The null hypothesis of a single structural break is rejected in favor of the alternative of two structural breaks with a p value less than 0.01 using the test described in Table 2 of Bai and Perron (1998).

  11. Our measure of the long-run real rate is very similar to an average value of r over the preceding 30 years. In fact, if (5.2) were estimated by OLS instead of with ARCH(2) residuals, and if the interest rate in year t was identical to the interest rate in year t -30, our estimate would be identical to the average rate over the 30 years ending in t. One can see this from the OLS identity that \( \overline{r} = \widehat{b} + \widehat{\psi }\overline{r}_{ - 1} \) and the fact that if \( r_{t} = r_{t - 30} \) then \( \overline{r} = \overline{r}_{ - 1} \) meaning that \( \widehat{b}/(1 - \widehat{\psi }) = \overline{r} . \) If \( r_{t} > r_{t - 30} \) then \( \ell_{t} \) will tend to be a little above the average rate over the 30 years ending in t. Also, since we estimate (5.2) allowing for ARCH errors, our estimate tends to down-weight observations that appear to be outliers in calculating the long-run real rate.

  12. The forward rates implied by yields as of December 20, 2014 were calculated as in Gürkaynak et al. (2010) using the spreadsheet available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2008/200805/200805abs.html. Note that the forward rate cannot be reliably calculated by this method for a horizon less than 2 years into the future, which is why the plotted curve only begins in 2016. We do not attempt to correct for risk premia and use these calculations only as a rough guideline.

  13. OW also consider uncertainty around u* and therefore also include a potential response to the change in the unemployment rate. We set aside this issue in our formal analysis but touch on it at the end of this section.

  14. For example, Chairman Bernanke said in the September 2013 FOMC press conference that the equilibrium rate would likely still be depressed by the end of 2016—the point at which the committee expected to hit its mandate at that time—and that it “…looks like it will be lower for a time because of these headwinds that will be slowing aggregate demand growth.”

  15. This assumption lies in between the very low aversion to changes in the funds rate in OW and the higher aversion in Yellen (2012). We explore the implications of varying it below.

  16. A different baseline for r* (e.g. resulting from a different assumption about the baseline policy reaction function) would generate different optimal values for a 0 . However, it would not change the result that greater uncertainty around r* increases the optimal value for a 0 .

  17. Haldane (2015) also concludes that delayed normalization is preferred.

References

  • Ang, Andrew A., and Geert Bekaert, 2002, “Regime Switches in Interest Rates,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 20, pp. 163–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, Donald W. K., 1993, “Parameter Instability and Structural Change with Unknown Change Point,” Econometrica, Vol. 61, No. 4, pp. 821–856.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, Donald W.K., 2003, “Tests for Parameter Instability and Structural Change with Unknown Change Point: A Corrigendum,” Econometrica, Vol. 71, No. 1, pp. 395–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angry Bear, 2009, “Current Recession vs the 1980–82 Recession,” http://angrybearblog.com/2009/06/current-recession-vs-1980-82-recession.html

  • Bai, Jushan and Pierre Perron, 1998, “Testing for and Estimation of Multiple Structural Changes,” Econometrica, Vol. 66, No. 1, pp. 47–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai, Jushan, and Pierre Perron, 2003, “Computation and Analysis of Multiple Structural Change Models,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 18, pp. 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balke, Nathan and Robert J. Gordon, 1989, “The Estimation of Prewar GNP: Methodology and New Evidence,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 97, pp. 38–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barsky, Robert B., 1987, “The Fisher Hypothesis and the Forecastability and Persistence of Inflation,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 19, pp. 3–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barsky, Robert, Alejandro Justiniano, and Leonardo Melosi, 2014, “The Natural Rate of Interest and Its Usefulness for Monetary Policy,” American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, Vol. 104, No. 5, pp. 37–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brayton, Flint, Thomas Laubach, and David Reifschneider, 2014, “The FRB/US Model: A Tool for Macroeconomic Policy Analysis,” FEDS Notes (http://www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/notes/feds-notes/2014/a-tool-for-macroeconomic-policy-analysis.html).

  • Campbell, John Y. and John Cochrane, 1999, “By Force of Habit: a Consumption-based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107, No. 2, pp. 205–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canzoneri, Matthew B., Robert E. Cumby, Behzad T. Diba, 2007, “Euler Equations and Money Market Interest Rates: a Challenge for Monetary Policy Models,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 54, pp. 1863–1881.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caporale, Tony, and Kevin B. Grier, 2000, “Political Regime Change and the Real Interest Rate,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 32, pp. 320–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin Eichenbaum and Charles L. Evans, 2005, “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 113, pp. 1–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida, Richard, 2014, “Navigating the New Neutral,” Economic Outlook, PIMCO, November.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarida, Richard, Jordi Galí and Mark Gertler, 2002, “A Simple Framework for International Monetary Policy Analysis,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 49, pp. 879–904.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, Gregory, 2005, “The Interest Rate in the Very Long Run: Institutions, Preferences, and Modern Growth,” working paper, U.C. Davis.

  • Clark, Todd E. and Sharon Kozicki, 2005, “Estimating equilibrium real interest rates in real time,” North American Journal of Economics and Finance, Vol. 16, pp. 395–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cúrdia, Vasco, Andrea Ferrero, Ging Cee Ng, and Andrea Tambalotti, 2015, “Has U.S. Monetary Policy Tracked the Efficient Interest Rate?,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 70, pp. 72–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Paoli, Bianca and Pawel Zabczyk, 2013, “Cyclical Risk Aversion, Precautionary Saving, and Monetary Policy,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 45, No. 1, pp. 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dennis, Richard, 2009, “Consumption Habits in a New Keynesian Business Cycle Model,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 41, No. 5, pp. 1015–1030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott, Graham, and Ulrich K. Müller, 2006, “Efficient Tests for General Persistent Time Variation in Regression Coefficients,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 73, pp. 907–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson Jr., Roger W., 2004, “Equilibrium Real Interest Rate: Theory and Application,” http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/20041029/.

  • Feroli, Michael E., Ethan S. Harris, Amir Sufi and Kenneth D. West, 2012, “Housing, Monetary Policy, and the Recovery,” Proceedings of the US Monetary Policy Forum, Vol. 2012, pp. 3–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galí, Jordi, 2008, Monetary Policy, Inflation and the Business Cycle, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garcia, Rene, and Pierre Perron, 1996, “An Analysis of the Real Interest Rate Under Regime Shifts,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 78, pp. 111–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, Robert J., 2012, “Is U.S. Economic Growth Over? Faltering Innovation Confronts the Six Headwinds,” NBER Working Paper No. 18315.

  • Gordon, Robert J., 2014, “The Demise of U.S. Economic Growth: Restatement, Rebuttal, and Reflections,” NBER Working Paper No. 19895.

  • Gürkaynak, Refet S., Brian Sack, and Jonathan H. Wright, 2010, “The TIPS Yield Curve and Inflation Compensation,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2, 70-92.Hansen, Alvin, 1939, “Economic Progress and Declining Population Growth.” American Economic Review, Vol. 29, No. 1, pp. 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haldane, Andy, 2015, “Stuck,”www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/2015/828.aspx

  • Hamilton, James D., 2009, “Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of 2007–08,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2009, pp. 215–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, James D., Ethan S. Harris and Jan Hatzius and Kenneth D. West, 2015, “The Equilibrium Real Funds Rate: Past, Present and Future,” Proceedings of the US Monetary Policy Forum, 2015.

  • Hatzius, Jan, Sven Jari Stehn, and Jose Ursua, 2014, “Some Long-Term Evidence on Short-Term Rates,” Goldman Sachs US Economics Analyst, 14/25, June 20.

  • Justiniano, Alejandro and Giorgio E. Primiceri, 2010, “Measuring the Equilibrium Real Interest Rate,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives, Vol. 34, No. 1, pp. 14–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kocherlakota, Narayana R., 1996, “The Equity Premium: It’s Still a Puzzle,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 34, No. 1, pp. 42–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, Paul R., Kathryn M. Dominquez and Kenneth Rogoff, 1998, “Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1998, No. 2, pp. 137–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, Paul R., 2013, “Secular Stagnation, Coalmines, Bubbles, and Larry Summers,” New York Times, http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/11/16/secular-stagnation-coalmines-bubbles-and-larry-summers.

  • Kwiatkowski, Denis, Peter C.B. Phillips, Peter Schmidt, and Yongcheol Shin, 1992, “Testing the Null Hypothesis of Stationarity Against the Alternative of a Unit Root: How Sure Are We that Economic Time Series Have a Unit Root?,” Journal of econometrics, Vol. 54, No. 1, pp. 159–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laubach, Thomas and John C. Williams, 2003, “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 85, No. 4, pp. 1063–1070

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leduc, Sylvain and Glenn D. Rudebusch, 2014, “Does Slower Growth Imply Lower Interest Rates?,” FRBSF Economic Letter 2014-33.

  • Martin, Alberto and Jaume Ventura, 2012, “Economic Growth and Bubbles,” American Economic Review, Vol. 102, No. 6, pp. 3033–3058.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCulley, Paul, 2003, “Needed: Central Bankers with Far Away Eyes,” PIMCO, Global Central Bank Focus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehra, Rajnish and Edward C. Prescott, 2003, “The Equity Premium in Retrospect,” 889-938 in G. Constantinides, M. Harris and R. Stultz, (eds) Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Vol. 1B, Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, Casey, 2009, “Worse Than 1982?,” http://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/06/03/worse-than-1982/?_r=0.

  • Orphanides, Athanasios and John C. Williams, 2002, “Robust Monetary Policy Rules with Unknown Natural Rates,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 2002, No. 2, pp. 63–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides, Athanasios and John C. Williams, 2006, “Monetary Policy with Imperfect Knowledge,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 4, Nos. 2–3, pp. 366–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides, Athanasios and John C. Williams, 2007, “Robust Monetary Policy with Imperfect Knowledge,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 54, pp. 1406–1435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapach, David E., and Mark E. Wohar, 2005, “Regime Changes in International Real Interest Rates: Are They a Monetary Phenomenon?,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 37, No. 5, pp. 887–906.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2009, This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2014,” Recovery from Financial Crises: Evidence from 100 Episodes,” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 104, No. 5, pp. 50–55.

  • Rey, Hélène, forthcoming, “International Channels of Transmission of Monetary Policy and the Mundellian Trilemma,” IMF Economic Review.

  • Romer, Christina D., 1989, “The Prewar Business Cycle Reconsidered: New Estimates of Gross National Product, 1869–1908,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 97, pp. 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smets, Frank and Raf Wouters, 2003, “An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 1, No. 5, pp. 1123–1175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Summers, Lawrence, 2013a, “Reflections on the ‘New Secular Stagnation Hypothesis,” 27–39 in C. Teulings and R. Baldwin (eds.), Secular Stagnation: Facts, Causes, and Cures, (eBook, www.voxeu.org/sites/default/files/Vox_secular_stagnation.pdf), CEPR.

  • Summers, Lawrence, 2013b, “Larry Summers Remarks at IMF Annual Research Conference,” https://www.facebook.com/notes/randy-fellmy/transcript-of-larry-summers-speech-at-the-imf-economic-forum-nov-8-2013/585630634864563.

  • Summers, Lawrence, 2014, “U.S. Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero Lower Bound,” Business Economics Vol. 49, No. 2.

  • Taylor, John B., 1993, “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 39, pp. 195–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, John B., 1999, “A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules,” 319–341 in J. B. Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy Rules, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Weil, Philippe, 1989, “The Equity Premium Puzzle and the Risk-free Rate Puzzle,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 24, pp. 401–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wieland, Johannes, 2014, “Are Negative Supply Shocks Expansionary at the Zero Lower Bound?,” working paper, University of California, San Diego.

  • White, Halbert, 1980, “A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity,” Econometrica, Vol. 48, pp. 817–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zarnowitz, Victor, 1997, “Appendix”, 731–ss737 in Glasner, D. (ed.) Business Cycles and Depressions: An Encyclopedia, New York: Garland Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kenneth D. West.

Additional information

* James Hamilton is Robert F. Engle Professor of Economics at the University of California, San Diego (email: jhamilton@ucsd.edu). Ethan Harris is Head of Global Economics Research at Bank of America Merrill Lynch Global Research (email: ethan.harris@baml.com). Jan Hatzius is Chief Economist and Head of Global Economics and Markets Research at Goldman Sachs (email: jan.hatzius@gs.com). Kenneth West is John D. MacArthur and Ragnar Frisch Professor of Economics at the University of Wisconsin, Madison (email: kdwest@wisc.edu).

We thank Jari Stehn and David Mericle for extensive help with the modeling work in “Implications for Monetary Policy” sections. We also thank Chris Mischaikow, Alex Verbny, Alex Lin, and Lisa Berlin for assistance with data and charts and for helpful comments and discussions. We also benefited from comments on earlier drafts of this paper by Mike Feroli, Peter Hooper, Anil Kashyap, Rick Mishkin, Pau Rabanal, Kim Schoenholtz, Amir Sufi, and two anonymous referees. This is a substantially revised version of Hamilton et al. (2015). West thanks the National Science Foundation for financial support.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hamilton, J.D., Harris, E.S., Hatzius, J. et al. The Equilibrium Real Funds Rate: Past, Present, and Future. IMF Econ Rev 64, 660–707 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-016-0015-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-016-0015-z

Navigation