Skip to main content
Log in

Benefit Take-Up and Labor Supply Incentives of Interdependent Means-Tested Benefit Programs for Low-Income Households

  • Published:
Comparative Economic Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using a microsimulation model based on representative panel data, we analyze the outcomes of three major means-tested interdependent benefit programs that are available for low-income households in Germany with respect to benefit take-up and labor supply incentives. The results show a distinct overlap between the programs and high rates of non-take-up, indicating that the effectiveness of the programs in reaching their target groups could be improved. Furthermore, we find that workers from low-income households are confronted with a complex benefit structure and high marginal tax rates, which negatively affects the individual labor supply.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Regarding the targeting effectiveness of means-tested benefit programs, two forms of inefficiencies can be distinguished: Inclusion of non-entitled households (“leakage”) and exclusion of entitled households (“non-take-up”), see Tasseva (2016). We restrict our analysis to non-take-up, because of its obvious negative effect on poverty alleviation.

  2. Additionally, according to the official definition of child poverty, all children living in a household that receives SA are considered poor, while they are not considered poor if their needs are covered by other incomes than SA. Therefore, with the introduction of SCA the government tried to reduce the official measure of child poverty by moving households from receiving SA to receiving SCA.

  3. Until the end of 2005 the minimum income exactly coincided with the parents’ guaranteed income as provided by SA. Since many parents were unable to calculate their guaranteed income, a large share of the applications for SCA was rejected because the parents’ income was below the required minimum income. As a result, the minimum income rules of SCA were simplified at the end of 2005. Since then, the minimum income for SCA is either a gross income of €600 per month for single parents or €900 per month for couples with children. Both minimum incomes are roughly in line with the parents’ guaranteed SA income.

  4. SCA was raised to €160 per month and child on 1. July 2016 and further increased to €170 in 2017.

  5. There is reason to believe that for some households the running (non-pecuniary) costs of receiving SA might be considerably higher than the corresponding costs of receiving HA. The Job Centers responsible for managing SA are constantly putting pressure on the recipients to find a job that, ideally, pays well enough to enable the households to overcome their dependency on SA. Households who do not cooperate sufficiently in the search for a job can be sanctioned by the Job Centers. In contrast, when claiming HA, the administrating municipal housing offices do not exert any pressure on recipients to leave the HA system. HA recipients are only required to renew their application to HA once a year (or whenever their income situation has changed). Additionally, it can be assumed that SA as the last safety net is more stigmatizing than HA.

  6. The administrative districts receive an annual grant from the federal budget for their expenditures for the housing costs of SA recipients. The grant is calculated as a fixed proportion of total expenditure.

  7. For a detailed description of the reform elements, also see Bundesgesetzblatt (2015) and Winkel (2015).

  8. For a documentation of the STSM see Jacobebbinghaus and Steiner (2003).

  9. The legal definition given in § 8(1) SGB II loosely states that a person is employable if illness or disability does not prevent her from working at least 3 h a day under the regular conditions of the labor market for the foreseeable future. In practice, employability is determined by public health officers.

  10. See Haisken-DeNew and Frick (2005) and Wagner et al. (2007) for documentation on the GSOEP.

  11. A calculation for single households and couples without children shows that for these households SA always exceeds HA and that the household would always be better off with SA.

  12. Notice that the regular child benefit is not a means-tested benefit and therefore constant for all gross incomes.

  13. The benefit reduction rate is 100% for incomes above €1500 for families with children. This is not shown in Fig. 3, as the example single parent household loses its SA eligibility before achieving that income threshold.

References

  • Arntz, M., M. Clauss, M. Kraus, R. Schnabel, A. Spermann, and J. Wiemers. 2007. Arbeitsangebotseffekte und Verteilungswirkungen der Hartz-IV-Reform. IAB Forschungsbericht 10/2007.

  • Becker, I. 2012. Finanzielle Mindestsicherung und Bedürftigkeit im Alter. Zeitschrift für Sozialreform 58: 123–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blos, K., M. Feil, H. Rudolph, U. Walwei, and J. Wiemers. 2007. Förderung Existenz sichernder Beschäftigung im Niedriglohnbereich * Schätzung von Angebots-, Verteilungs- und fiskalischen Effekten des SMWA-Vorschlags. IAB Forschungsbericht 07/2007.

  • Blundell, R. 2012. Tax Policy Reform: The Role of Empirical Evidence. Journal of the European Economic Association 10: 43–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., and A. Shephard. 2012. Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Taxation of Low-Income Families. The Review of Economic Studies 2: 481–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., V. Fry, and I. Walker. 1988. Modelling the Take-up of Means-Tested Benefits: The Case of Housing Benefits in the United Kingdom. Economic Journal 98: 58–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BMFSFJ. 2009. Evaluation des Kinderzuschlags. Ergebnisbericht. Bundesministerium für Familie, Senioren, Frauen und Jugend.

  • BMUB. 2015. Hendricks legt Wohngeld- und Mietenbericht vor. Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz, Bau und Reaktorsicherheit. Pressemitteilung Nr. 272/15, Berlin, 28 Oct 2015.

  • Brewer, M., A. Duncana, A. Shepharda, and M.J. Suárez. 2006. Did Working Families’ Tax Credit Work? The Impact of In-work Support on Labor Supply in Great Britain. Labour Economics 13: 699–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruckmeier, K., and J. Wiemers. 2011. A New Targeting—A New Take-Up? Non-Take-Up of Social Assistance in Germany after Social Policy Reforms. IAB Discussion Paper No. 10/2011, Institute for Employment Research, Nuremberg.

  • Bruckmeier, K., and J. Wiemers. 2012. A New Targeting—A New Take-up? Non-take-up of Social Assistance in Germany After Social Policy Reforms. Empirical Economics 43 (2): 565–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruckmeier, K., and J. Wiemers. 2015. Wohngeldreform 2016: Auswirkungen auf Grundsicherungsbezieher. Soziale Sicherheit 64: 442–445.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bundesgesetzblatt. 2015. Jahrgang 2015 Teil 1, Nr. 38 vom 8. Oktober 2015, S. 1610–1663.

  • Currie, J. 2004. The Take Up Of Social Benefits. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 10488.

  • Department for Work and Pensions. 2010, March. Universal Credit: Welfare That Works. DWP Policy Paper, 11 Nov 2010.

  • Eurofound. 2015. Access to Social Benefits: Reducing Non-Take-up. Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedberg, L. 2000. The Labor Supply Effects of the Social Security Earnings Test. Review of Economics and Statistics 82: 48–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haisken-DeNew, J.P., and J.R. Frick. 2005. DTC Desktop Companion to the German Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP). Version 8.0, DIW Berlin.

  • Henger, R. 2015. Reform des Wohngeldes – Stellungnahme zur öffentlichen Anhörung zum Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Reform des Wohngeldrechts und zur Änderung des Wohnraumförderungsgesetzes. Köln, 5 June 2015

  • Hoynes, H.W. 1996. Welfare Transfers in Two-Parent Families: Labor Supply and Welfare Participation Under AFDC-up. Econometrica 64: 295–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobebbinghaus, P., and V. Steiner. 2003. Dokumentation des Steuer-Transfer-Mikrosimulationsmodells STSM - Version 1995-1999. Dokumentation Nr. 03-06, Zentrum für Europäische Wirtschaftsforschung.

  • Keane, M., and R. Moffitt. 1998. A Structural Model of Multiple Welfare Program Participation and Labor Supply. International Economic Review 39 (3): 553–589.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knabe, A. 2006. Warum Zuverdienstregeln und Kinderzuschlag negative Arbeitsanreize setzen. ifo Dresden berichtet 2/2006.

  • Lemieux, T., and K. Milligan. 2008. Incentive Effects of Social Assistance: A Regression Discontinuity Approach. Journal of Econometrics 142: 807–828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meister, W. 2009. Neuer Kinderzuschlag, Wohngeldreform, höhere Hartz-IV-Regelsätze: Insbesondere für Familien deutliche Einkommenssteigerungen. ifo Schnelldienst 62: 19–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, B.D. 2002. Labor Supply at the Extensive and Intensive Margins: The EITC, Welfare and Hours Worked. American Economic Review 92: 373–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moffitt, R. 1983. An Economic Model of Welfare Stigma. American Economic Review 73 (5): 1023–1035.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moffitt, R.A. 2002. Welfare programs and labor supply. In Handbook of Public Economics, ed. Auerbach, A.J., and M. Feldstein., (1st edn.), vol. 4, Chapter 34, 2393–2430. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

  • Riphahn, R.T. 2001. Rational Poverty of Poor Rationality? The Take-Up of Social Assistance Benefits. Review of Income and Wealth 47 (3): 379–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tasseva, I.V. 2016. Evaluating the Performance of Means-Tested Benefits in Bulgaria. Journal of Comparative Economics 44 (4): 919–935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigtländer, M., T. Clamor, R. Henger, and J. Niehues. 2013. Bestandsaufnahme und Wirkungsanalyse des Wohngeldes. Bundesinstitut für Bau-, Stadt- und Raumforschung (BBSR) im Bundesamt für Bauwesen und Raumordnung (BBR) (Hrsg.).

  • Wagner, G.G., J.R. Frick, and J. Schupp. 2007. The German Socio-Economic Panel Study (SOEP)—Scope, Evolution and Enhancement. Journal of Applied Social Studies 127 (1): 139–169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whelan, S. 2010. The Take-Up of Means-Tested Income Support. Empirical Economics 39 (3): 847–875.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiemers, J. 2015. Endogenizing Take-Up of Social Assistance in a Microsimulation Model: A Case Study for Germany. The International Journal of Microsimulation 8 (2): 4–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiemers, J., and K. Bruckmeier. 2009. Forecasting Behavioural and Distributional Effects of the Bofinger–Walwei Model Using Microsimulation. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 229 (4): 492–511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winkel, R. 2015. Wohngeldreform 2016: Die wesentlichen (Neu-)Regelungen beim Wohngeld. Zeitschrift für Soziale Sicherheit (12/2015), 433–438.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the editor and two anonymous referees for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kerstin Bruckmeier.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bruckmeier, K., Wiemers, J. Benefit Take-Up and Labor Supply Incentives of Interdependent Means-Tested Benefit Programs for Low-Income Households. Comp Econ Stud 60, 583–604 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41294-017-0041-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41294-017-0041-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation