Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Communication Cost, Skilled-Unskilled Wage, and Informality

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Quantitative Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper establishes an interesting link between informality and time zone differences in a general equilibrium trade model for small open economy. Trading countries are located in different time zones of the world with non-overlapping working hours. Such differences in timing can be utilized in the production of services, and communication technology is an important factor that helps this trading process. In such a setup due to a reduction in communication cost, both skilled and unskilled workers are benefitted, skilled labour using service sector and formal unskilled sector expand. Interestingly, wage inequality between skilled and unskilled workers is widened under reasonable conditions. Another phenomenon that must draw our attention is the contraction of informality due to such changes. Then we extend the basic model to include capital mobility across all sectors and unionized wage in the formal sector. We find that the reduction in communication cost leads to finite change in the structure of production and one of the four sectors of the system vanishes. Subsequently, informal sector contracts while wage disparity is widened.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. India has emerged as a dominant outsourcing industry in globalized world and India's IT-BPM (Business Process Management) sector accounted for 56% of the world market in 2015 (The IT-BPM Sector in India: Strategic Review 2015).

  2. The country has essentially three options to work : (1) Marjit (2007) has described the discount factor to show time preference as a contributor to trade between two different time zones, \( W_{S} \left( {2 + \delta } \right) = P_{X} \), where \( \delta \) represents time preference; (2) second one is related to night shift work. Generally the wage rate of night workers is higher than day wage due to non-regular work time, \( W_{S} \left( {2 + \omega } \right) = P_{X} \), where \( \omega \) reflects extra cost for night-shift work (Kikuchi et al. 2013); (3) half done work/service of home country can be outsourced to a foreign country, which is located in the non overlapping time zone, to finish the remaining work in the daytime of foreign country. In that case, a communication network cost is to be incurred, i.e. \( \rho \). \( W_{S} \left( {2 + \rho } \right) = P_{X} \). Therefore, a country will outsource only when the loss of delayed delivery and night shift disutility is more than communication cost. Thus, the following condition holds \( \delta > \omega > \rho \). See Mandal et al. (2018) for related issues and analysis.

  3. Private capital is defined as money as loan or investment that comes from private money lenders. As the informal sector is beyond the scope of legality or administrative requirements, generally they face complications while borrowing loans from government financial institutions. This is precisely why they have to rely on non-institutional sources.

  4. Formal unskilled wage is determined through a Nash Bargaining mechanism.

  5. Y uses capital more intensively than M.

References

  • Anderson, E. 2014. Time Differences, communication and trade: Longitude matters II. Review of World Economics 150 (2): 337–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christen, E. 2012. Time zones matter: The impact of distance and time zones on services trade. The World Economy 40 (3): 612–631.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dettmer, B. 2014. International service transactions: Is time a trade barrier in a connected world ? International Economic Journal 28 (2): 225–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A.K., and G.M. Grossman. 1982. Trade and Protection with Multistage Production. Review of Economic Studies 49: 583–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, M., S. Kar, and S. Marjit. 2013. Product variety, finite changes and wage inequality. CSSSC: Mimeo.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Findlay, R., and R.W. Jones. 2000. Factor Bias and Technical Progress. Economic Letters 68: 303–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R.W. 1965. The Structure of Simple General Equilibrium Models. Journal of Political Economy 73 (6): 557–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R.W. 1971. A three-factor model in theory, trade and history. In Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth, ed. J. Bhagwati, 3–21. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R.W. 1974. The Small Country in a Many-Commodity World Duality in International Trade : A Geometrical Note. Australian Economic Papers 13: 225–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R.W., and S. Marjit. 1992. International Trade Theory and Endogenous Production Structures. In Economic Theory and International Trade-Essays in Honor of T. Rader, ed. W. Neuefeind and R. Riezman. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kikuchi, T. 2006. Time Zones, Outsourcing and Patterns of International Trade. Economics Bulletin 6 (15): 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kikuchi, T. 2008. Distribution Costs, International Trade and Industrial Locations. Economics Bulletin 6 (24): 1–5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kikuchi, T. 2009. Time Zones as a Source of Comparative Advantage. Review of International Economics 17 (5): 961–968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kikuchi, T. 2011. Time Zones, Communication Networks, and International Trade. Abingdon: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kikuchi, T., and S. Marjit. 2011. Growth with Time Zone differences. Economic Modelling 28 (1): 637–640.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kikuchi, T., S. Marjit, and B. Mandal. 2013. Trade with Time Zone differences: Factor Market Implications. Review of Development Economics 17 (4): 699–711.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, J. 2007. North, South and Distance in the Gravity Model. European Economic Review 51 (4): 971–991.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandal, B. 2015. Distance, Production, Virtual Trade and Growth. Economics The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 9 (2015–1): 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandal, B., S. Marjit, and N. Nakanishi. 2018. Outsourcing, Factor Prices and Skill Formation in Countries with Non-overlapping Time Zones. Eurasian Economic Review 8 (2): 289–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S. 1987. Trade in Intermediates and the Colonial Pattern of Trade. Economica 54: 173–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S. 2003. Economic Reform and Informal Wage- A general Equilibrium Analysis. Journal of Development Economics 72: 371–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S. 2007. Trade Theory and the Role of Time Zones. International Review of Economics and Finance 16: 153–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit, S., S. Kar (2011), “International Capital Flow, Finite Change and Two-sided Wage Inequality”, mimeo, CSSSC.

  • Matsuoka, Y., and M. Fukushima. 2010. Time Zones, Shift Working and International Outsourcing. International Review of Economics and Finance 19: 769–778.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prasad, A., B. Mandal, and P. Bhattacharjee. 2017. Time Zone Difference, Comparative Advantage and Trade: A Review of Literature. Eurasian Journal of Economics and Finance 5 (3): 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanyal, K. 1983. Vertical Specialization in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Stages of Production. Economica 50 (197): 71–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanyal, K., and R.W. Jones. 1982. The Theory of Trade in Middle Products. American Economic Review 72 (1): 16–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strategic Review. 2015. The IT-BPM Sector in India: Strategic Review.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sujata Ghosh.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Equation (1) yields

$$ \hat{W}_{S} = - \theta_{dX} \hat{\rho } > 0\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(19)

where \( \theta_{dX} = \frac{{W_{S} \rho }}{{P_{X} }} \) indicates communication cost share in X.

Differentiating Eq. (2) and using Envelope condition and substituting the value of Eq. (19), we get

$$ \hat{r} = \frac{{\theta_{SY} \theta_{dX} }}{{\theta_{KY} }}\hat{\rho } < 0\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(20)

Differentiating Eq. (3) and substituting \( \hat{r} \) we get

$$ \hat{W} = - \frac{{\theta_{dX} \theta_{SY} \theta_{KM} }}{{\theta_{KY} \theta_{LM} }}\hat{\rho } > 0\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(21)

The wage gap between skilled and unskilled wages is derived from (19) and (21)

$$ \left( {\hat{W}_{S} - \hat{W}} \right) = - \theta_{dX} \left[ {\frac{{\theta_{KY} \theta_{LM} - \theta_{KM} \theta_{SY} }}{{\theta_{LM} \theta_{KY} }}} \right]\hat{\rho } > 0\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(22)

If, \( \left( {\frac{{\theta_{KY} }}{{\theta_{SY} }} > \frac{{\theta_{KM} }}{{\theta_{LM} }}} \right) \)Footnote 6

Again, differentiating Eq. (4) and substituting \( \hat{W} \) we obtain

$$ \hat{R} = \theta_{dX} \frac{{\theta_{LI} \theta_{KM} \theta_{SY} }}{{\theta_{KY} \theta_{LM} \theta_{TI} }}\hat{\rho } < 0\;\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(23)

Change in output depends on factor substitution owing to changes in factor prices due to change in \( \rho \).

Equation (8) yields

$$ \hat{I} = - \hat{a}_{TI} $$
(24)

By definition, the elasticity of substitution between L and T in sector I is given by

$$ \sigma_{I} = \frac{{\hat{a}_{LI} - \hat{a}_{TI} }}{{\hat{R} - \hat{W}}} $$

Using expression for elasticity of substitution and Envelope theorem between L and T in I we have

$$ \hat{a}_{TI} = - \sigma_{I} (\hat{R} - \hat{W})\theta_{LI} $$

Using the full employment condition for T and plugging the values of \( \hat{W} \) and \( \hat{R} \) we arrive at \( \hat{a}_{TI} = - \sigma_{I} \theta_{dX} \left( {\frac{{\theta_{LI} \theta_{KM} \theta_{SY} }}{{\theta_{KY} \theta_{LM} \theta_{TI} }}} \right)\hat{\rho } \)

Substituting the values in Eq. (24), it becomes

$$ \hat{I} = \sigma_{I} \theta_{dX} \left( {\frac{{\theta_{LI} \theta_{KM} \theta_{SY} }}{{\theta_{KY} \theta_{LM} \theta_{TI} }}} \right)\hat{\rho } < 0\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(25)

Full employment condition of L gives the value

$$ \hat{M} = - \sigma_{I} \theta_{dX} \left( {\frac{{\theta_{LI} \theta_{KM} \theta_{SY} \lambda_{LI} }}{{\theta_{KY} \theta_{LM} \theta_{TI} \lambda_{LM} }}} \right)\hat{\rho } > 0\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(26)

Again, differentiating Eq. (6) and substituting the value of \( \hat{M} \) we obtain

$$ \hat{Y} = \sigma_{I} \theta_{dX} \left( {\frac{{\theta_{LI} \theta_{KM} \theta_{SY} \lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KM} }}{{\theta_{KY} \theta_{LM} \theta_{TI} \lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KY} }}} \right)\hat{\rho } < 0\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(27)

Similarly, Eq. (5) yields

$$ \hat{X} = - \sigma_{I} \theta_{dX} \left( {\frac{{\theta_{LI} \theta_{KM} \theta_{SY} \lambda_{LI} \lambda_{KM} \lambda_{SY} }}{{\theta_{KY} \theta_{LM} \theta_{TI} \lambda_{LM} \lambda_{KY} \lambda_{SX} }}} \right)\hat{\rho } > 0\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(28)

Appendix 2

Equation (14) and (15) yield

$$ \hat{r} = \hat{W} = 0 $$

Differentiating Eq. (12) and using Envelope condition

$$ \hat{W}_{S} = - \frac{{\theta_{dX} }}{{\theta_{SX} + \theta_{dX}^{S} }}\hat{\rho } > 0\;{\text{as}}\;\hat{\rho } < 0 $$
(29)

Where, \( \theta_{dX} = \frac{{(W_{S} + r)\rho }}{{P_{X} }} \) indicates communication cost share in X.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mandal, B., Ghosh, S. Communication Cost, Skilled-Unskilled Wage, and Informality. J. Quant. Econ. 18, 927–939 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-019-00192-w

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-019-00192-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation