Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Inequality and institutional quality in a growth model

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

By applying a growth model of an occupational choice between being a worker and being a criminal, an institutional Kuznets curve is produced. Using the Gini coefficient derived from the model, we investigate how institutional quality affects wealth inequality across agents. In the case of a relatively higher capital share, an institutional Kuznets curve can emerge. In this case, an improvement in institutional quality decreases the possibility of being stolen but increases the amount of wealth stolen. In the early stage of economic development, since the latter effect dominates the former, inequality widens as institutional quality improves. In contrast, since the converse is true in the late stage, inequality shrinks once institutions have sufficiently matured. In the case of a lower capital share, an institutional Kuznets curve cannot emerge. In this case, inequality monotonically shrinks as institutional quality improves. Furthermore, we present government policies that reduce inequality and achieve the first-best outcome.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The scatter plot in Fig. 1 is based on 123 countries. The data on the Gini coefficient are collected from the dataset developed by Solt (2009, 2019). The index of the “Legal System and Property Rights” in the Economic Freedom of the World in Gwartney et al. (2018) is used as a proxy of institutional quality. Both datasets are averaged over 2000–2017.

  2. As such, the criminal gang plays a role of insurance in our model. Although one can construct a model such that each member of the gang is rewarded as he or she works for the gang, the analysis becomes complicated, while the main result regarding inequality and institutional quality is unchanged.

  3. In our model, a criminal’s earnings are negatively affected by law enforcement, and the opportunity cost of being a criminal is the wage income. As a result, the number of criminals decreases as law enforceability becomes strong. In Japan, the government began to enforce a law that cracks down on gangs’ activities in 1991. According to the report by the National Police Agency in Japan (National Police Agency 2020), the number of gang members and associate members declined from 91, 000 in 1991 to 28,200 in 2019, that is, declined by 69%. This evidence makes it reasonable to assume that the opportunity cost of being a criminal is the wage income.

  4. As in the model of Galor and Moav (2004), Asano (2012) also highlights the role of human capital accumulation and derives a nonmonotonic relationship between inequality and economic growth.

  5. In other words, bequests can be used for investment projects to produce physical capital and/or for the formation of human/knowledge capital. In any case, physical capital and human/knowledge capital are assumed to be perfect substitutes in this paper.

  6. Although knowledge capital or know-how may be sold to the representative firm at a certain price, our model setting can remain unchanged essentially.

  7. One can consider various types of crimes agents face, including robbery, fraud, expropriation, embezzlement, etc.

  8. One can imagine that by laundering money, the criminal gang can access the capital market without being arrested.

  9. It is assumed that if the agent is arrested, the prison term is sufficiently short that the agent is released before his or her lifetime ends.

  10. It is possible to introduce punishment into our model without changing the main results provided that the punishment is proportional to the amount of wealth that criminals try to steal. We assume that there is no punishment in our model for simplicity.

  11. One may consider that the occupational choice would depend on an agent’s wealth, and agents who receive a large bequest would tend not to commit a crime. To focus our analysis on the relationship between institutional quality and inequality in the stationary state, we assume away such a situation that the occupational choice depends on an agent’s wealth, and accordingly, \(l_t\) and \(q_t\) become constant in equilibrium, as seen in Eqs. (14) and (15).

  12. Assumption 1 implies that the labor income share is less than a half. Note that capital includes both physical and human capital as assumed in Sect. 3.1.

  13. Here, we examine relatively high capital income shares. This is because we assume that capital broadly includes both physical and human capital, as explained in Sect. 3.1.1, and Mankiw et al. (1992) suggest that the labor income share is 33% when one takes into account both physical and human capital in production, which is approximately the mean of labor income shares in the cases of panels A and B (17% and 45%, respectively).

References

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2001) The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. Am Econ Rev 91(5):1369–1401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2002) Reversal of fortune: geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Q J Econ 117(4):1231–1294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Bolton P (1997) A theory of trickle-down growth and development. Rev Econ Stud 64(2):151–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P, Violante GL (2002) General purpose technology and wage inequality. J Econ Growth 7(4):315–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Rodrik D (1994) Distributive politics and economic growth. Q J Econ 109(2):465–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asano A (2012) Is there a “double bonus” from reducing inequality? Econ Inquiry 50(2):551–562

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee AV, Newman AF (1993) Occupational choice and the process of development. J Political Econ 101(2):274–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1968) Crime and punishment: an economic approach. J Political Econ 66(2):169–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertola G (1993) Factor shares and savings in endogenous growth. Am Econ Rev 83(5):1184–1198

    Google Scholar 

  • Burdett K, Lagos R, Wright R (2003) Crime, inequality, and unemployment. Am Econ Rev 93(5):1764–1777

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiu WH, Madden P (1998) Burglary and income inequality. J Public Econ 69(1):123–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chong A, Calderón C (2000) Institutional quality and income distribution. Econ Dev Cult Change 48(4):761–786

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chong A, Gradstein M (2007) Inequality and institutions. Rev Econ Stat 89(3):454–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chong A, Gradstein M (2019) Institutional persistence, income inequality, and individual attitudes. J Econ Inequal 17(3):401–413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich I (1973) Participation in illegitimate activities: a theoretical and empirical investigation. J Political Econ 81(3):521–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O (2000) Ability-biased technological transition, wage inequality, and economic growth. Q J Econ 115(2):469–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O (2004) From physical to human capital accumulation: inequality and the process of development. Rev Econ Stud 71(4):1001–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Zeira J (1993) Income distribution and macroeconomics. Rev Econ Stud 60(1):35–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gradstein M (2007) Inequality, democracy and the protection of property rights. Econ J 117(516):252–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney J, Lawson R, Hall J, Murphy R (2018) Economic freedom of the world: 2018 annual report. Fraser Institute, Vancouver

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE, Jones CI (1999) Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Q J Econ 114(1):83–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu Y, Kunieda T, Nishimura K, Wang P (2020) Flying or trapped?. In: NBER working paper 27278

  • İmrohoroğlu A, Merlo A, Rupert P (2000) On the political economy of income redistribution and crime. Int Econ Rev 41(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • İmrohoroğlu A, Merlo A, Rupert P (2004) What accounts for the decline in crime? Int Econ Rev 45(3):707–729

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack S, Keefer P (1995) Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Econ Politics 7(3):207–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw NG, Romer D, David NW (1992) A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Q J Econ 107(2):407–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama K (2002) The rise of mass consumption societies. J Political Econ 110(5):1035–1070

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza EG, Quadrini V, Ríos-Rull J-V (2009) On the welfare implications of financial globalization without financial Development. In: Clarida R, Giavazzi F (eds) NBER international seminar on macroeconomics 2007. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 283–312

    Google Scholar 

  • National Police Agency (2020) The State of Affairs of Organized Crimes in 2020. https://www.npa.go.jp/sosikihanzai/kikakubunseki/sotaikikaku06/R1.sotaijousei.pdf. Accessed 19 Sep 2020 (in Japanese)

  • North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D, Subramanian A, Trebbi F (2004) Institutions rule: the primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. J Econ Growth 9(2):131–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini G (1994) Is inequality harmful for growth? Am Econ Rev 84(3):600–621

    Google Scholar 

  • Solt F (2009) Standardizing the world income inequality database. Soc Sci Q 90(2):231–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solt F (2019) The standardized world income inequality database, version 8. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/LM4OWF. Harvard Dataverse, V2. Accessed 10 Aug 2019

  • United Nations (2013) Humanity divided: confronting inequality in developing countries. United Nations Development Programme Bureau for Development Policy, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to express thanks to two anonymous referees for their invaluable comments and suggestions to improve the paper significantly. The authors are also grateful to Koichi Futagami, Akihisa Shibata, and session participants of “Macroeconomic Policy” in the 2019 SWET for their helpful comments. All remaining errors, if any, are ours. This work is financially supported by Kwansei Gakuin University and the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science, Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research (Nos. 16K03685 and 20K01647).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Takuma Kunieda.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

On behalf of all authors, the corresponding author states that there is no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Lemma 1

Suppose that \(\Gamma _t\) is a set of agents who earn interest income in the second subperiod of period t without being robbed. Then, it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{i\in \Omega }I_{it}{\text {d}}i&=\int _{i\in \Gamma _t}(\omega _{it}+r_tk_{it}){\text {d}}i+\int _{i\in \Omega \setminus \Gamma _t}\omega _{it}{\text {d}}i \nonumber \\&=\int _{i\in \Omega }\omega _{it}{\text {d}}i+r_t\int _{i\in \Gamma _t}k_{it}{\text {d}}i. \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

Define \(\Lambda _t\) as a set of agents who are workers in period t. Then, the first term of the right-hand side of Eq. (A.1) becomes \(\int _{i\in \Omega }\omega _{it}{\text {d}}i=\int _{i\in \Lambda _t}w_{t}{\text {d}}i+\int _{i\in \Omega \setminus \Lambda _t}\tilde{w}_{t}{\text {d}}i\). Furthermore, since \(q_t\) measures the population of agents in \(\Gamma _t\) and since criminals randomly choose targets, the second term of the right-hand side of Eq. (A.1) becomes \(r_t\int _{i\in \Gamma _t}k_{it}{\text {d}}i=r_tq_t\int _{i\in \Omega }k_{it}{\text {d}}i=r_tq_tk_t\), where Eq. (12) has been used to obtain the last equality. Then, using Eqs. (1), (2), (3), (9), (12), and (A.1), we compute \(\int _{i\in \Omega }I_{it}{\text {d}}i\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{i\in \Omega }I_{it}{\text {d}}i&=w_tl_t+\tilde{w}_t(1-l_t)+[1-(1-l_t)(1-p)]r_tk_t \\&=w_tl_t+(1-l_t)(1-p)r_tk_t+[1-(1-l_t)(1-p)]r_tk_t \\&=Ak_t^\alpha l_t^{1-\alpha }. \end{aligned}$$

This is our desired conclusion. \(\square\)

1.2 Proof of Lemma 4

According to Lemma 3, any family becomes a crime victim almost surely. Suppose that family i with \(k_{it}\) is robbed in period \(t\ge 0\). Then, the wealth that family i has in period \(t+1\) is given by \(k_{it+1}=\sigma w_t=:k_{t+1}^{(0)}\). Looking forward from period \(t+1\) onward, we note that Eq. (22) implies that \(k_{it+2}=\sigma w_{t+1}+\sigma ^2 r_{t+1}w_t=:k_{t+2}^{(1)}\) with probability q and \(k_{it+2}=\sigma w_{t+1}=:k_{t+2}^{(0)}\) with probability \(1-q\), \(\ldots\), \(k_{it+j+1}=\sigma w_{t+j}+\sigma ^2r_{t+j}w_{t+j-1}+\cdots +\sigma ^{j+1}\left( \Pi _{s=1}^{j}r_{t+s}\right) w_t=:k_{t+j+1}^{(j)}\) with probability \(q^{j}\) and \(k_{it+j+1}=\sigma w_{t+j}=:k_{t+j+1}^{(0)}\) with probability \(q^{j-1}(1-q)\). Since it holds that \(r_{t+s}\rightarrow \bar{r}\), \(w_{t+s}\rightarrow \bar{w}\), and \(\sigma r_{t+s}\rightarrow \alpha\) for \(s=1,\ldots j\) as \(t\rightarrow \infty\), it follows that \(k^{(0)}:=\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }k_{t+j+1}^{(0)}=\sigma \bar{w}\) for \(j=0, 1, \ldots , \infty\) and \(k^{(j)}:=\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }k_{t+j+1}^{(j)}=\sigma \bar{w}\sum _{s=0}^j\alpha ^s\) for \(j=1, 2, \ldots , \infty\). Therefore, for sufficiently large t, family i’s wealth takes one of the values in \(\{k^{(j)}\}_{j=0}^\infty\). Because this outcome holds for all families in \(\Omega\), the support of the distribution of individual wealth in the stationary state is given by \(\{k^{(j)}\}_{j=0}^\infty\), where \(k^{(j)}=\sigma \bar{w}\sum _{s=0}^j\alpha ^s\). \(\square\)

1.3 Proof of Lemma 5

Suppose that \(P_{t}^{(j)}\) is the population of families that have individual wealth, \(k_t^{(j)}\), in period \(t\ge 1\) (see the proof of Lemma 4 for the definition of \(k_t^{(j)}\)). Equation (22) and the law of large numbers imply that the population of families that become crime victims in period t and have individual wealth, \(k_{t+1}^{(0)}\), in period \(t+1\) is equal to \(P_{t+1}^{(0)}=1-q\). Again, Eq. (22) and the law of large numbers yield \(P_{t+2}^{(1)}=qP_{t+1}^{(0)}=q(1-q)\), \(P_{t+3}^{(2)}=qP_{t+2}^{(1)}=q^2(1-q)\), \(\ldots\), \(P_{t+j+1}^{(j)}=qP_{t+j}^{(j-1)}=q^j(1-q)\), \(\ldots\). Or equivalently, we obtain \(P_{t+j+1}^{(j)}=q^j(1-q)\) for \(j=0, 1, \ldots , \infty\). It follows from the last equation that \(P^{(j)}:=\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }P_{t+j+1}^{(j)}=q^j(1-q)\) for \(j=0, 1, \cdots , \infty\). Conversely, we can verify that \(\sum _{j=0}^\infty P^{(j)}=\sum _{j=0}^\infty q^j(1-q)=1\). This completes the proof. \(\square\)

1.4 Proof of Proposition 3

By definition, the Gini coefficient in the stationary state is given as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} g(q)=1-\sum _{j=0}^{\infty }\left[ G(k^{(j)})-G(k^{(j-1)})\right] \left[ B^{(j)}+B^{(j-1)}\right] , \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

where \(G(k^{(j)})\) is the cumulative distribution function of \(k^{(j)}\), and \(B^{(j)}\) is the cumulative proportion of wealth relative to the total wealth, which is given by \(B^{(j)}:=\sum _{\ell =0}^j(1-q)q^{\ell }k^{(\ell )}/\bar{k}\) according to Eq. (24). In Eq. (A.2), it is assumed for convenience that \(k^{(-1)}=B^{(-1)}=0\). Using Eq. (24) allows \(B^{(j)}+B^{(j-1)}\) to be computed as

$$\begin{aligned} B^{(j)}+B^{(j-1)}=\left( \frac{1-q}{1-\alpha }\right) \left( \frac{\sigma \bar{w}}{\bar{k}}\right) \left[ 2\left( \frac{1-q^{j}}{1-q}-\frac{\alpha (1-(\alpha q)^{j})}{1-\alpha q}\right) +(1-\alpha ^{j+1})q^{j}\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

From Eq. (24), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} G(k^{(j)})-G(k^{(j-1)})=(1-q)q^j. \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

Additionally, from Eqs. (14), (19), and (20), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\sigma \bar{w}}{\bar{k}}=1-\alpha q. \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

Eqs. (A.3)–(A.5) allow \(\left[ G(k^{(j)})-G(k^{(j-1)})\right] \left[ B^{(j)}+B^{(j-1)}\right]\) to be computed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\left[ G(k^{(j)})-G(k^{(j-1)})\right] \left[ B^{(j)}+B^{(j-1)}\right] \nonumber \\&=\frac{(1-q)^2(1-\alpha q)}{1-\alpha }\left[ \frac{2(1-\alpha )}{(1-q)(1-\alpha q)}q^j-\frac{1+q}{1-q}(q^2)^{j}+\frac{\alpha +\alpha ^2 q}{1-\alpha q}(\alpha q^2)^{j}\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

Eq. (A.6) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{\infty }\left[ G(k^{(j)})-G(k^{(j-1)})\right] \left[ B^{(j)}+B^{(j-1)}\right] =2-\frac{1-\alpha q}{1-\alpha }+\frac{\alpha (1+\alpha q)(1-q)^2}{(1-\alpha )(1-\alpha q^2)}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

Eqs. (A.2) and (A.7) lead to our desired conclusion. \(\square\)

1.5 Proof of Proposition 4

From Eq. (25), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} g^\prime (q)=\alpha ^2\left( q-\frac{1-\sqrt{1-\alpha }}{\alpha }\right) \left( q-\frac{1+\sqrt{1-\alpha }}{\alpha }\right) {/}(1-\alpha q^2)^2. \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

It holds that \(g^\prime (0)>g^\prime ((1-\sqrt{1-\alpha })/\alpha )=0>g^\prime (1)\). Therefore, if \((1-\alpha )/\alpha \ge (1-\sqrt{1-\alpha })/\alpha\) and \(\alpha >1/2 \iff 1/2<\alpha \le (-1+\sqrt{5})/2\), it follows that \(g^\prime (q)<0\) in \(((1-\alpha )/\alpha , 1)\), and thus, g(q) monotonically decreases with \(q\in [(1-\alpha )/\alpha , 1)\). If \((1-\alpha )/\alpha < (1-\sqrt{1-\alpha })/\alpha\) and \(\alpha>1/2 \iff \alpha > (-1+\sqrt{5})/2\), it follows that \(g^\prime (q)>0\) in \([(1-\alpha )/\alpha , (1-\sqrt{1-\alpha })/\alpha )\) and \(g^\prime (q)<0\) in \(((1-\sqrt{1-\alpha })/\alpha , 1)\). Therefore, g(q) increases with \(q\in [(1-\alpha )/\alpha , (1-\sqrt{1-\alpha })/\alpha )\), and g(q) decreases with \(q\in [(1-\sqrt{1-\alpha })/\alpha , 1)\). \(\square\)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kunieda, T., Takahashi, M. Inequality and institutional quality in a growth model. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 19, 189–213 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-020-00195-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-020-00195-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation