Appendix A: Legislation
A.1 The institutional framework and the changes in 2002
Social Security regulation during the period covered by the sample selected in this paper experienced two main changes in relation to the framework established in 1985: the reforms introduced in 1997 and in 2002.
Up to 1997 only 8 contributory years were required to be entitled to a retirement pension. The change introduced in 1997 increased such minimum to 15, with the additional requirement that two of them had to have taken place during the last 15 years. Full implementation was expected for 2002, with a progressive timetable set up to that year.
The normal retirement age in Spain, that is the age when a person becomes eligible for the full pension benefit, is 65. Up to 2002, early retirement was possible from the age of 60 only for those who had contributed to the labour mutual funds system (former Social Security System) before January 1, 1967. An early retirement penalty defined by a reduction coefficient, which is detailed below, was in place. The 2002 reform extended early retirement to all workers, from the age of 61, if they complied with certain conditions that are detailed below. On the other hand, the reform also set incentives to promote retirement beyond the age of 65. In particular, the 2002 reform established:
-
Access to early retirement since the age of 61, if : a) the worker’s contributory years were at least 30; b) the termination of his last employment had been involuntary and c) he had spent at least 6 months as involuntarily unemployed and registered as job seeker in the Public Employment Service Offices, during the period immediately preceding the pension claim.
-
Stronger linkages between the contributive effort exerted by workers and the pension received. Workers who wanted to retire between 64 and 61 years of age were charged with a penalty that decreased with both age and total years of contribution.
-
Premium to postponing retirement. Each full year of employment beyond statutory retirement age (65), implied a 2 % increase in the regulatory base to compute retirement benefits, only applicable to those workers with at least 35 years of contributions.
-
Retiring at the age of 64 was also possible without age penalty. Moreover, it did not require a previous period of unemployment, but just the minimum 15 contributory years. However, in this case, the firm had to hire another worker for a minimum period of a year with a substitution contract to replace the retiring worker.
-
It became possible to receive a partial pension from the age of 60 whilst continuing to work part-time. Workers could partially retire if the firm replaced the retiree with another worker (relief contract) to compensate for the retiree’s reduction in work-time. The amount of the pension was then conditioned by the reduction in working hours (between 25 and 85 %).
The database does not provide information about contributions dating from before the seventies, while all men born between 1936 and 1946 could potentially have been working by 1967, as the youngest would have started working at the age of 21. Therefore, the assumption in the empirical part is that all people in the sample contributed to the labour mutual funds system, so that they only need 15 years of contribution to be entitled to retire. In fact, in the sample 34 % of those we observe retiring, do so at 60 and 40 % do so with less than 30 registered years of contribution.
The last two points in the reform are not taken into account in the analysis as they require information from the demand side, which we do not have.
A.2 The pension amount
The amount of the old age pension is defined by the interaction of different elements. On the one hand, the Regulatory Base (Base reguladora, BR) that defines the amount of the pension and it is directly related to the contribution bases received.Footnote 19 The minimum and maximum contributory periods to be considered in its calculation and the inflation correction mechanism to obtain its present value are regulatory defined. Moreover, there are minimum and maximum pensions that are yearly defined and its amount depends on marital status and number of economically dependent people who depend on the person receiving the benefit. A person retiring between 1985 and 1996 had a regulatory base defined as:
$$\begin{aligned} BR_t =\frac{1}{112}\left( {\sum \limits _{j=1}^{24} {w_{t-j} +\sum \limits _{j=25}^{96} {w_{t-j} \frac{I_{t-25} }{I_{t-j} }} } }\right) \end{aligned}$$
where w\(_\mathrm{t-j}\) are covered earnings for the jth month before retiring at t and I\(_\mathrm{t-j}\) is the price index for the jth month before retirement, and where only 8 years were taken into account.
Since 2002, the regulatory base is defined taking into account the last 15 years:
$$\begin{aligned} BR_t =\frac{1}{210}\left( {\sum \limits _{j=1}^{24} {w_{t-j} +\sum \limits _{j=25}^{180} {w_{t-j} \frac{I_{t-25} }{I_{t-j} }} } }\right) \end{aligned}$$
A transitory period was set from 1997 to 2002 such that each year, one additional year was included in the up-rated part of the weighted average and, therefore the 15 years were finally accounted for the definition of the regulatory base in 2002Footnote 20. The relation between the first monthly pension received at time \(t (B_{t})\) and the regulatory base (BR\(_{t})\) calculated at \(t\) can be expressed as \(B_{t} =\alpha _{nt}^T \cdot BR_t \)where \(\alpha _{nt} ^T=\alpha _{nt} ^y\alpha _{nt} ^a\), so that \(\alpha _{nt} ^y\) depends only on contributory years (\(n)\), and \(\alpha _{nt} ^a\) depends on the age of retirement.
If retirement age is equal or larger than 65 then, and up to 1997, \(\alpha _{nt} ^a=1\) and \(\alpha _{nt} ^T\)is expressed as:
$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{nt}^T =\left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} 0,&{}\quad if \,n<15\\ 0.6+0.02( {n-15}),&{}\quad if\, 15\le n <35 \\ 1,&{}\quad if\, 35\le n \\ \end{array}} \right. \end{aligned}$$
The reform introduced in 1997 modified the number of years to define the contributory base and the substitution rate (\(\alpha ^{T}_{n})\) if age of retirement was equal or larger than 65, so that:
$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{nt}^T =\left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} 0,&{}\quad if\, n<15\\ 0\cdot 5+0.03({n-15}),&{}\quad if\, 15\le n<25 \\ 0\cdot 8+0.02({n-25}),&{}\quad if\, 25\le n<35 \\ 1,&{}\quad if\, 35 \le n \\ \end{array}}\right. \end{aligned}$$
That new scheme thus implied a more progressive approach to full benefits. For early retirement, regulation also sets a penalization system linked to age. Mutualistas that retire early were subject to a reduction coefficient equivalent to 8 % for each year in advance of 65 that he/she retires, so that \(\alpha _t^a\, =1-0.08( {65-r})\,\,\,\,where\,\,r>\,=60\). The 1997 reform reduced the reduction coefficient to 7 % for those with more than 40 contributory years, when claiming the pension. This coefficient should be jointly applied with the one corresponding to contributory years.
The 2002 reform changed the penalization mechanism, so as to make the age coefficient (\(\alpha _t^a )\) more linked to the number of contributed years, so that:
$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{nt}^a =\left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} 0 &{}\quad if\, r<61\\ a+k( {r-60}),&{}\quad if\, 61\le r <65\, \\ 1,&{}\quad if\, r\ge 65 \\ \end{array}} \right. \\ where\,\left\{ {\begin{array}{ll} a=0.6;k=0.08\,\quad \qquad if\,\,n<31 \\ a=0.625;k=0.075\,\quad if\,31\le n\le 34 \\ a=0.65;k=0.07\,\quad \quad if\,35\le n\le 37 \\ a=0.675;k=0.065 \quad if\,38\le n\le 39 \\ a=0.7;k=0.06\quad \qquad if\,n\ge 40 \\ \end{array}} \right. \\ \end{aligned}$$
where r is retirement age.
Moreover, the 2002 Amendment introduced a premium for late retirement, so that the pension was increased by 2 % per additional year of work beyond 65, if the worker had more than 35 years of contribution.
$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _n^T =1+0.02( {r-65}) \,\quad if \, r>65 \, and \, n\ge 35 \end{aligned}$$
Appendix B: Data
This appendix contains the definition of the variables included in the different specifications. As already mentioned in the text, the data source is the Continous Sample of Working Histories (CSWH) 2006, “Muestra Continua de Vidas Laborales” in Spanish.
The main descriptive statistics for each variable are presented in Table 5.
B.1 Economic incentive variables
To calculate the Social Security benefits to which individuals in the sample are entitled, we make use of the Social Security covered earnings histories of individual in the CSWH 2006.
SSW\(_\mathrm{it}:\) Value of Social Security Wealth of individual i at time t, at 2006 prices:
$$\begin{aligned} SSW(r)_{it} =\sum \limits _{s=t}^{s=L} {[B_i (s,r)[p(s\vert t)_i } /(1+\rho _i )^{s-t}]], \end{aligned}$$
indicates Social Security Wealth at time t (at age t) if retiring at age r; L is the maximum life length,\(B_i (s,r)\)is the pension benefit in period s (at age s) if retiring at r, p(s\(\vert \) r) is the conditional probability of an individual at time t to be alive at time s where s\(>\)r, \(\rho _i \) is the individual discount rate.
Table 5 Descriptive values To calculate the pension, we make use of data on covered earnings and from it we build the Regulatory Base which is computed, following the regulation, as a moving average of the contribution bases of the 15 years immediately before retirement. The minimum base that has been used to complete job careers has been the one corresponding to contributory group 5, senior administrative (“oficial administrativo”), the group with the largest volume of population. On the other hand, the maximum base has been taken to be the one corresponding to group 1, Engineers and Graduates (“Ingenieros y Licenciados”), the group with the highest base for all the years. The maximum life length (T) is assumed to be 98 years;\(\rho _i \), the individual discount rate is assumed to be fixed at 3 %, p(s\(\vert \) r), the conditional probability of an individual aged r to be alive at age s, has been taken from the National Statistics Institute (INE) demographic projections (scenario 2), based upon 2001 Census data. Pensions and covered earnings are assumed to increase 2 % yearly from 2006, while for previous years we use their actual rate of change. Upper and lower limits on the pension benefits are applied to compute retirment pension (the minimum one corresponds to a worker with a dependent spouse). Not considering heterogeneity on survival probability among individuals with different income levels, as well as on discount rates, could be understood as a limitation on the assumptions behind the incentive variables used in the estimation. However, heterogeneity in official estimates of life expectancy by socioeconomic level are not available in Spain, and though it would be possible to estimate them, presumably they would not differ too much, since the country is not characterized by such remarkable levels of wealth inequality. Maybe additional research would be needed to analyze the impact of considering different discount rates, also linked to income level. Assumed discount rates, and minimum and maximum pension, are homogeneous to ensure simplicity in the analysis.
In order to calculate the different incentive measures, we need to project SSW for the future. Two different situations arise, depending on the age of the individual and whether or not he has retired. For those that are not 66 before 2006, we need to project their pension and their SSW beyond this year. To do so, we assume that their salary and, therefore, their contributory base will be increasing at a 2 % rate every year. For those that have retired before 2006, we project their salaries for the years before 2006 assuming that they keep the purchasing power of their last observed salary (or the following one), so that the contributory base increases by the same amount as the December over December CPI (\(\Pi _{t})\)
SSA\(_\mathrm{it}:\) The accrual rate,
$$\begin{aligned} SSA(r)_{it} =1/(1+\rho _i )SSW(r+1)_{it} -SSW(r)_{it} \end{aligned}$$
and we let
$$\begin{aligned} SSW(r+1)_{it} =\frac{SSW(r+1)_{it+1} }{(1+\Pi _t )} \end{aligned}$$
A limitation of this index is that it does not take into account the comparison that the individual can make between pension benefits and the level of his/her income. It could be argued that the leisure preference is such that wages can fully compensate for the forgone leisure enjoyment from postponing retirement.
PV\(_\mathrm{it}:\) Peak Value computed between the ages of 60 and 65 is defined as,
$$\begin{aligned} PV_i (r)&= \max (SSW(r,r\!+\!1)_i ,SSW(r,r\!+\!2)r_i ,SSW(r,r\!+\!3)_i , \ldots ,SSW(r,66)_i )\\&= SSA_i ,otherwise \end{aligned}$$
where
$$\begin{aligned} SSW(r,r+j)=SSW(r+j)/(1+\rho )^j-SSW(r) \end{aligned}$$
We follow Coile and Gruber (2000) and restrict the peak value to be equal to the accrual rate, if the individual works beyond the highest value for his social security wealth.
RR\(_{ it}\) : Replacement rate, \(RR_i (r)\) is the ratio of the expected pension benefits\(B_i (r)\) at time t over wages \(w_i (r)\) received at time \(\text{ t }-1\) for individual \(i\) at age \(r\), if the person retires at age \(r\).
\(RR_i (r)=E_r (B_i (r)/w_i (r))\) where E is the expectation operator.
B.2. Other variables
disab\(_{\mathrm{it}-1}\): Dummy variable that takes value 1 at age t if the person was receiving any disability benefit while he was a year younger (at age \(\text{ t }-1\)) and zero, otherwise.
univ\(_\mathrm{i}\): Dummy variable that takes value 1 if the contributory group (“grupo de cotización“) of the longest contributory relationship with the Social Security system is the one with the highest academic qualifications (group 1: “Engineers and Graduates“), and zero, otherwise.
numrel\(_\mathrm{i}\): Number of contributory labour relations that have been recorded by the Social Security before becoming entitled to an old age pension and that include those involving the perception of unemployment benefits.
Regional Government (Comunidad Autónoma) where the worker initially registered: Group of 19 dummy variables, each one corresponding to a CA, plus one for Ceuta and one for Melilla, that records the initial worker’s registration.
serv\(_\mathrm{i}\). Dummy variable that takes value 1 if the longest job a person has held has taken place in the following CNAE sector classifications: Trade (50 to 52), Restoration (Hostelería) (55), Transport (60 to 64), other services, including education y health (65 to 67, 70 to 74, 80, 85 and 90)
u\(_{\mathrm{it}-1}\). Dummy variable that takes value 1 at age t if the person was receiving unemployment benefits, either as a subsidy or a contributory transfer, while he was a year younger (at age \(\text{ t }-1\)), and zero, otherwise. (That is, people whose relationship with Social Security is coded as a TRL 751-756 in the administrative files).
l\(_{\mathrm{it}-1}.\) Dummy variable that takes value 1 at age t if the person was working and contributing to Social Security while he was a year younger (at age \(\text{ t }-1\)), and value zero, otherwise.
g_k\(_\mathrm{it}\): Dummy variables that take value 1 if the person is at age t in the k–th period decision and value zero otherwise, where k=[1,6]. That is, g_k takes value 1 if the value of the length of the spell from the year the person becomes entitled to a retirement pension is k.
age_k\(_\mathrm{it}\): Dummy variables that take value 1 if the person is k years old at time t and zero otherwise, where k=[60,65].
cycle\(_\mathrm{t}\): Spanish GDP real growth rate (for years 1997 to 2006)
r2002:Dummy variable that takes value 1 if the year of the observation is greater than 2001.
otherben\(_{\mathrm{it}-1}\): Dummy variable that takes value 1 at time t if the person was receiving any Social Security benefit other than disability, old age or unemployment while he was a year younger (at age \(\text{ t }-1\)) and zero, otherwise.
mlength\(_\mathrm{i}\):Average number of years for the spells that the individual i has had before becoming entitled to a pension.
tr: a linear time trend
low60\(_\mathrm{it}\) : Dummy variable that takes value 1 if the person’s contribution was the regulatory minimum at 60
low61\(_\mathrm{it}\) : Dummy variable that takes value 1 if the person’s contribution was the regulatory minimum at 61
top64\(_\mathrm{it}\) : Dummy variable that takes value 1 if the person’s contribution was the regulatory maximum at 64
low65\(_\mathrm{it}\) : Dummy variable that takes value 1 if the person’s contribution was the regulatory maximum at 65.
See Tables 5, 6, 7, 8.
Table 6 Logit estimates of the effects of pension incentives on retirement behaviour between 60 and 65 years of age
Table 7 Quantitative effects of pension incentives and other variables on the average hazard rate by age
Table 8 Quantitative effects of pension incentives and other variables on the average hazard rate for ages between 60 and 65