Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

An assessment of the global food security index

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Food Security Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Several measures of food insecurity, whether at the household or at the national level, have been introduced during the past two or three decades. Some concentrate on the determinants of food security while other emphasize more the consequences of food insecurity. The main focus of this paper is on the food security indicators introduced by the Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU), the Global Food Security Index (GFSI). The paper has two goals. It first checks whether the set of weights selected by the panel of experts of the EIU plays a crucial role in the ranking of countries by level of food security. Then it examines to what extent the ranking of countries given by the GFSI is sensitive to the list of indicators selected. The empirical analysis conducted, based on statistical techniques such as principal components and efficiency analysis, led us to conclude that both the weights selected and the choice of indicators give a reasonable ranking of countries by level of their food security.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to Google Trends, the GFSI was cited 1407 times during the years 2017–2018, while the GHI, HDDS and FCS were cited 504, 671 and 902 times respectively during the same period.

  2. For principal components analysis we used the first axis only. This is also what is generally done, when attempting to derive a composite index reflecting the wealth of households. The Demographic and Health Surveys, for example, propose, a wealth index derived from the first axis of a principal components analysis. The percentages of the overall variance explained by the first component were respectively 46.4%, 46.9%, 40.7% and 35.0% for the EIU data in 2012 and 2015, and for the FAO data in 1990–1992 and 2009–2011. The Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin measures of sampling adequacy were respectively 0.91, 0.91, 0.79 and 0.78 for the same EIU and FAO data that have just been mentioned.

  3. We decided to base the analysis in this section on the principal components techniques because it remains the most popular approach to derive a composite index in development studies. There are thus more than 400 Demographic and Health Surveys which have been conducted over the years in most developing countries and they provide a measure of the wealth of households derived from principal components analysis.

References

  • Aigner, D., Lovell, C. A. K., & Schmidt, P. (1977). Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. Journal of Econometrics, 6, 21–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G., Crawford, I., & Leicester, A. (2008). Efficiency analysis and the lower convex Hull approach. In N. Kakwani & J. Silber (Eds.), Quantitative Approaches to Multidimensional Poverty Measurement (pp. 176–191).

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G., Crawford, I., & Leicester, A. (2011). Welfare rankings from multivariate data, a nonparametric approach. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 247–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, C. B. (2010). Measuring food insecurity. Science, 327, 825–328.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Battese, G. E., & Corra, G. S. (1977). Estimation of a production frontier model: With application to the pastoral zones of eastern Australia. Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 21, 169–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cafiero, C. (2013). What do we really know about food security. Working paper 18861. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Carletto, C., Zezza, A., & Banerjee, R. (2013). Towards better measurement of household food security: Harmonizing indicators and the role of household surveys. Global Food Security, 2, 30–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charnes, A., W.W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes (1978) "Measuring the efficiency of decision making units 429–44.

  • Coates, J. (2013). Build it back better: Deconstructing food security for improved measurement and action. Global Food Security, 2, 188–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coelli, T. (1992). A computer program for frontier production function estimation: Version frontier 2.0. Economic Letters, 39, 29–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coelli, T., Prasada Rao, D. S., & Battese, G. E. (1998). An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis. Boston: Kluwe Academic Publichers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Coelli, T. J., Rao, D. P., O'Donnell, C. J., & Battese, G. E. (2005). An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis. Heidelberg: Springer Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Haen, H., Klasen, S., & Qaim, M. (2011). What do we really know? Metrics for food security and undernutrition. Food Policy, 36, 760–769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deutsch, J., & Silber, J. (2005). Measuring multidimensional poverty: An empirical comparison of various approaches. Review of Income and Wealth, 51(1), 145–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deutsch, J., Silber, J., & Verme, P. (2012). On social exclusion in Macedonia: Measurement and determinants", chapter 7. In C. Ruggeri Laderchi & S. Savastano editors (Eds.), Poverty and Exclusion in the Western Balkans. New Directions in Measurement and Policy (pp. 99–116). Springer Verlag.

  • Deutsch, J., Dumas, A., & Silber, J. (2013). Estimating an educational production function for five countries of Latin America on the basis of the PISA data. Economics of Education Review, 36, 245–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deutsch, J., Dumas, A., & Silber, J. (2019). School externalities and scholastic performance: An efficiency analysis. International Journal of Manpower, 40(1), 102–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EIU (The Economist Intelligence Unit). (2015). Global food security index 2015. An annual measure of the state of global food security. London: The Economist Intelligence Unit Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, M. J. (1957). The measurement of productive efficiency. Journal of Royal Statistics Society, Series A, CXX, 120, 253–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filmer, D., & Pritchett, L. H. (2001). Estimating wealth effects without expenditure data – Or tears: An application to education enrollments in sates of India. Demography, 38(1), 115–132.

  • Filmer, D., & Scott, K. (2012). Assessing asset indices. Demography, 49, 359–392.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Freudenberg, M. (2003). Composite indicators of country performance: A critical assessment. In OECD science, technology and industry working papers, 2003/16. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, W. H. (1992). LIMDEP version 6.0: User’s manual and reference guide. New York: Econometric Software Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamelin, A.-M., Habicht, J.-P., & Beaudry, M. (1999). Food insecurity: Consequences for the household and broader social implications. The Journal of Nutrition, 129(2), 525S–528S.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Heady, D., & Ecker, O. (2013). Rethinking the measurement of food security: From first principles to best practice. Food Security, 5, 327–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ike, C. U., Jacobs, P. T., & Kelly, C. (2017). A multidimensional approach to measuring household food security in Taraba state, Nigeria: Comparing key indicators. Development in Practice, 27(2), 234–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ivanovic, B. (1977). Classification theory. Belgrade: Institute for Industrial Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, R., P. Smith and M. Goddard (2004) Measuring Performance: An examination of composite performance indicators. Technical paper series 29, Center for Health Economics, University of yok, York, UK.

  • Johnson, R. A., & Wichern, D. W. (1999). Applied multivariate statistical analysis (Fourth ed.). New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River.

  • Jones, A. D., Ngure, F. M., Pelto, G., & Young, S. L. (2013). What are we assessing when we measure food security? A compendium and review of current metrics. Advances in Nutrition, 4(5), 481–505.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Kakwani, N., & Son, H. H. (2015). Measuring food insecurity: Global estimates. ECINEQ (Society for the Study of economic inequality) working paper (pp. 2015–2370).

    Google Scholar 

  • Lovell, C. A. K., Richardson, S., Travers, P., & Wood, L. (1994). Resources and Functionings: A new view of inequality in Australia. In W. Eichhorn (Ed.), Models and measurement of welfare and inequality. Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maričić, M., Bulajic, M., Dobrota, M. and V. Jeremic (2016) “Redesigning the Global Food Security Index: A Multivariate Composite I-Distance Indicator Approach. International Journal of Food and Agricultural Economics 4(1), Special Issue: 69–86.

  • Meeusen, W., & van den Broeck, J. (1977). Efficiency estimates from cobb-Douglas production functions with composed error. International Economic Review, 18, 435–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G. (2012). Choosing aggregation rules for composite indicators. Social Indicators Research, 109, 337–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G., & Nardo, M. (2009). Noncompensatory/nonlinear composite indicators for ranking countries: A defensible setting. Applied Economics, 41(12), 1513–1523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nardo, M., Saisana, M., Saltelli, A., & Tarantola, S. (2005). Tools for composite indicators building. Ispra: European Commission, Joint Research Centre, Institute for the Protection and Security of the Citizen.

    Google Scholar 

  • O.E.C.D. (2008). Handbook on constructing composite indicators. In Methodology and user guide. Paris: O.E.C.D.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2013) PISA 2012 Assessment and Analytical Framework: Mathematics, Reading, Science, Problem Solving and Financial Literacy. Paris: OECD Publishing.

  • Pangaribowo, E. H., Gerber, N., & Torero, M. (2013). Food and nutrition security indicators: A review. Working paper 108. Bonn: Center for Development Research (ZEF).

    Google Scholar 

  • Pérez-Escamilla, R., Gubert, M. B., Rogers, B., & Hromi-Fiedler, A. (2017). Food security measurement and governance: Assessment of the usefulness of diverse food insecurity indicators for policy makers. Global Food Security, 14, 96–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pinstrup-Andersen, P. (2009). Food security: Definition and measurement. Food Security, 1, 5–7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabar, D. (2017). An overview of data envelopment analysis application in studies on the socio-economic performance of OECD countries. Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 30(1), 1770–1784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ram, R. (1982). Composite indices of physical quality of life, basic needs fulfilment and income: A principal components analysis. Journal of Development Economics, 11, 227–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramos, X., & Silber, J. (2005). On the application of efficiency analysis to the study of the dimensions of human development. Review of Income and Wealth, 51(2), 285–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richmond, J. (1974). Estimating the efficiency of production. International Economic Review, 15(2), 515–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saisana, M., A. Saltelli and S. Tarantola (2005) “Uncertainty and sensitivity analysis techniques as tools for the quality assessment of composite indicators. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society A 168, Part 2: 307–323.

  • Santeramo, F. G. (2014). On the composite indicators for food security: Decisions matter! MPRA paper 58955. Germany: University Library of Munich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santeramo, F. G. (2015a). Food security composite indices: Implication for policy and practice. Development in Practice, 25(4), 594–600.

  • Santeramo, F. G. (2015b). On the composite indicators for food security: Decisions matter! Food Reviews International, 31(1), 63–73.

  • Sen, A. K. (1981). Poverty and famines: An essay on entitlement and deprivation. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, M. D., Rabbitt, M. P., & Coleman-Jensen, A. (2017). Who are the World’s Food insecure? New Evidence from the Food and Agriculture Organization’s Food Insecurity Experience Scale. World Development, 93(C), 402–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, A.-C., D’Hombres, B., Casubolo, C., Kayitakire, F., & Saisana, M. (2017). The use of the global food security index to inform the situation in food insecure countries. European Commission, Technical Report of the Joint Research Centre, Luxembourg.

  • Webb, P., Coates, J., Frongillo, E. A., Lorge, B., Swindale, A., & Bilinsky, P. (2006). Measuring household food insecurity: Why It's so important and yet so difficult to do. The Journal of Nutrition, 136(5), 1404S–1408S.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Wineman, A. (2016). Multidimensional household food security measurement in rural Zambia. Agrekon, 55(3), 278–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jacques Silber.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Methodology: the various approaches used

1.1 Principal Component Analysis

Principal components analysis (PCA) posits an underlying structure relating the indicator variables to a set of latent factors:

$$ {x}_{1i}={\sum}_{k=1}^K{b}_{1k}{y}_{ki},\dots .,{x}_{hi}={\sum}_{k=1}^K{b}_{hk}{y}_{ki},\dots, {x}_{Ki}={\sum}_{k=1}^K{b}_{Kk}{y}_{ki} $$
(1)

where xhi refers to the value of variable h in country i; yki is the value of principal component k for the i-th country; and the b’s are coefficients. The coefficients are estimated and the system is inverted to derive

$$ {y}_{fi}={\sum}_{k=1}^K{a}_{fk}{x}_{fi} $$
(2)

for each principal component f.

The first principal component accounts for as much of the variability in the data as possible. Each other principal component has the highest variance possible under the constraint that it is orthogonal to the other components. The principal components are in fact the eigenvectors of the covariance matrix of the original variables. The first principal component therefore gives an index providing maximum discrimination between the countries, the variables varying the most across countries being given a larger weight.

1.2 Efficiency Analysis

1.2.1 On Efficiency analysis and the distance function

Efficiency analysis is largely based on the concepts of duality and input distance functions in production theory.

Let xi = (x1i, ..., xji, ..., xki) denote the vector of levels of food security observed in the various k domains of food security for country i and let yi denote the overall level of food security for country i. A country’s performance, as far as food security is concerned, may hence be represented by the pair (xi, yi), i =1, …I where I is the total number of countries.

A food security index FS can then be estimated using a Malmquist input quantity index:

$$ FS\left(y,{x}^s,{x}^t\right)={D}_{input}\left(y,{x}^s\right)/{D}_{input}\left(y,{x}^t\right) $$
(3)

where xs and xt are two different "food security inputs" vectors and Dinput is an input distance function. The idea behind the Malmquist index is to provide a reference set against which to judge the relative magnitudes of the two vectors of "food security inputs".

To be more precise, let L(y) represent the input set of all input vectors x that can produce the output vector y. That is,

$$ L(y)=\left\{x:x\ \mathrm{can}\ \mathrm{produce}\ y\right\}. $$
(4)

The input distance function Dinput (x,y) involves then (in a way similar to that in which this concept is used in consumption theory) the scaling of the input vector and will be defined as

$$ {D}_{input}\ \left(x,y\right)=\operatorname{Max}\ \left\{\rho :\left(x/\rho \right)\in L(y)\right\} $$
(5)

It may be proven that

  • the input distance function is increasing in x and decreasing in y;

  • it is linearly homogeneous in x;

  • if x belongs to the input set of y (i.e. xL(y)) then Din(x,y) ≥ 1;

  • the input distance function is equal to unity if x belongs to the “frontier” of the input set (the isoquant of y).

1.2.2 Estimation procedures

Corrected ordinary least squares (COLS)

Let us take as a simple illustration the case of a Cobb-Douglas production function. Let ln yi be the logarithm of the output of firm i, i =1 to I, and xi a (N+1) row vector, whose first element is equal to one and the others are the logarithms of the N inputs used by the firm. We may then write that

$$ \mathit{\ln}\ \left({y}_i\right)={x}_i\cdotp \beta -{u}_i\kern0.5em ,\kern0.5em i=1,\dots, I. $$
(6)

One of the methods allowing the estimation of this output-oriented Farrell measure of technical efficiency Ti (see Farrell 1957) is to use an algorithm proposed by Richmond (1974) which has become known as corrected ordinary least squares (COLS). This method starts by using ordinary least squares to derive the (unbiased) estimators of the slope parameters. Here β is a (N+1) column vector of parameters to be estimated and u a non-negative random variable, representing the technical inefficiency in production of firm i.,

The ratio of the observed output of firm i to its potential output will then give a measure of its technical efficiency Ti so that

$$ {T}_i={y}_i/\exp \left({x}_i\cdotp \beta \right)=\exp \left({x}_i\cdotp \beta -{u}_i\right)/\exp \left({x}_i\cdotp \beta \right)=\exp\ \left(-{u}_i\right) $$
(7)

Then in a second stage the (negatively biased) OLS estimator of the intercept parameter β0 is adjusted up by the value of the greatest negative residual so that the new residuals have all become non-negative. Naturally the mean of the observations does not lie any more on the estimated function: the latter has become in fact an upward bound to the observations.

The stochastic production frontier

One of the main criticisms of the COLS method is that it ignores the possible influence of measurement errors and other sources of noise. All the deviations from the frontier have been assumed to be a consequence of technical inefficiency. Aigner et al. (1977) and Meeusen and van den Broeck (1977) independently suggested an alternative approach called the stochastic production frontier method in which an additional random error v is added to the non-negative random variable u.

$$ \ln\ \left({y}_i\right)={x}_i\cdotp \beta +{v}_i-{u}_i $$
(8)

The random error v is supposed to take into account factors such as the weather, the luck, etc. v is assumed to be i.i.d. normal random variables with mean zero and constant variance σv2, independent of u, the latter being taken generally to be i.i.d. exponential or half-normal random variables. In the latter case where u is assumed to be i.i.d truncations (at zero) of a normal variable N(0,σ), Battese and Corra (1977) suggested to proceed as follows. Calling σs2 the sum (σ2 + σv2), they defined the parameter γ = (σ2/σs2) —so that γ has a value between zero and one— and showed that the log-likelihood function could be expressed as

$$ \ln (L)=-\left(N/2\right)\ln \left(\pi /2\right)-\left(N/2\right)\ln \left({\sigma}_s^2\right)+{\sum}_{i=1}^I\left[1-\varPhi \left({z}_i\right)\right]-\left[1/\left(2{\sigma}_s^2\right)\right]{\sum}_{i=1}^I{\left(\ln {y}_i-{x}_i\beta \right)}^2 $$
(9)

where zi = [(ln yi - xi·β)/σs]·√(γ/(1-γ)) and Φ(·) is the distribution function of the standard normal random variable.

The Maximum Likelihood estimates of β, σs2 and γ are obtained by finding the maximum of the log-likelihood function defined previously where this function is estimated for various values of γ between zero and one. More details on this estimation procedure is available in programs such as FRONTIER (Coelli 1992) or LIMDEP (Green 1992). The same methods (COLS and Maximum Likelihood) may naturally be also applied when estimating distance functions.

COLS or the stochastic production frontier have been applied in various areas in Economics. Ramos and Silber (2005) used, for example, this approach to study the dimension of human development, Deutsch and Silber (2005) to measure multi-dimensional poverty and Deutsch et al. (2013) to analyze the performance of pupils taking the PISA (Program for International Student Assessment) test (for more information on the PISA test, see, OECD 2012).

Data envelopment analysis (DEA)

Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) (see, for example, Coelli et al. 2005) is a linear programming methodology to measure the efficiency of multiple decision-making units (DMUs) when the production process includes several inputs and outputs. It has been used by economists to measure the efficiency of production units. Whereas in traditional statistical analyses the performance of producers is compared to that of the average producer, DEA compares each producer (decision making unit in the language of Charnes et al.’s 1978, path breaking paper) with the best one. The idea is to derive a production frontier but this non-parametric approach does not assume a particular functional form for the frontier. The function is in fact determined by the most efficient producers. The idea behind such a frontier is that one assumes that if a firm, using specific levels of inputs, is able to produce a certain output level, another firm of similar scale should be able to reach similar results. In other words if a given producer P1 manages to produce Y(P1) units of output with X(P1) inputs, other producers should also have such a capacity, if they are efficient. The same is true, say, when one considers a producer P2 which produces Y(P2) units of output with X(P2) inputs, etc…As a consequence these producers P1, P2,…, P(N), assuming N producers, can be theoretically “amalgamated” to obtain a kind of virtual producer using a combination of the inputs of the various producers to produce a combination of the outputs they produce. The goal of DEA then turns out to be a search for the best virtual producer for each actual producer. If this virtual producer produces more output than the actual producer with the amount of inputs the latter uses or uses less inputs to produce the output of the actual producer, the latter is assumed to be inefficient.

Data Envelopment Analysis has been applied in various areas in Economics. Rabar (2017) reviews the application of data envelopment analysis to studies that empirically explore socio-economic efficiency of OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development) member countries.

The Anderson et al. (2011) approach: A nonparametric empirical method for deriving food security rankings, based also on data envelopment analysis

This approach has the advantage of not requiring the selection of a particular aggregation function or some weighting scheme. It involves the calculation of a lower bound on the distance function measure of food security. Assume that there are m indicators measuring different aspects of food security for each of the observations (countries) in our dataset. Let xi refer to the ith observation and let X be the m by n matrix of all these observations. Let now FS denote a food security function that aggregates the variables associated with an observation into a single scalar measure. The following two assumptions about FS are made. The first one is monotonicity, which is defined as FS(x) ≥ FS(y) if x ≥ y. Monotonicity hence implies that food security does not fall with an increase in one of the indicators. The second assumption is that of quasi-concavity which we define as FS(x) = FS(y) ≤ FSx + (1 − α)y) with 0 ≤ α ≤ 1. Quasi-concavity therefore implies that for a given distribution of the indicators, food security is (weakly) increasing when there is an inequality reducing reallocation between the observations.

The distance measure function used by Anderson et al. (2011) is then defined as

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}D\left(F{S}_{x_j}\right)= Mi{n}_D\Big\{D\left(F{S}_{x_j}\right)\ \mathrm{with}\ D>0,{x}_j\in X, FS\ \mathrm{satisfying}\ \mathrm{monotonicity}\ \mathrm{and}\ \mathrm{quasi}-\\ {}\mathrm{concavity}\Big\}\end{array}} $$
(10)

Let now LCH(X) refer to the lower convex hull of the data. Then, if the reference level is that of the country in the dataset with the lowest level of food security, we may write that

$$ D\left({FS}_{x_j}\right)={\mathit{\operatorname{Min}}}_D\left\{D\left({FS}_{x_j}\right)\ \mathrm{with}\ D>0\ \mathrm{and}\ D\left({FS}_{x_j}\right)\in LCH(X)\right\} $$
(11)

Let also UMH(X)denote the upper monotone hull of the data.We may then write, if the reference level is that of the country in the dataset with highest level of food security, that

$$ D\left({FS}_{x_j}\right)={\mathit{\operatorname{Min}}}_D\left\{D\left({FS}_{x_j}\right)\ \mathrm{with}\ D>0\ \mathrm{and}\ D\left({FS}_{x_j}\right)\in UMH(X)\right\} $$
(12)

These distance measures correspond therefore to the minimum amount by which one need to scale each observation so that they share an equal ranking with the worse-off or best observations. As stressed by Anderson et al. (2008) “they represent lower bounds on these measures for any and all ways of choosing to weigh the various indicators, as long as the weighting formula is monotone and quasi-concave”.

To apply the approach of Anderson et al. (2011) we used a program originally written by T.W. Leo for their paper.

Combining principal components analysis and data envelopment analysis

In the empirical section of the present paper, we also combine principal components analysis and data envelopment analysis. We proceeded as follows.

In a first stage we applied PCA to each of the domains of food security distinguished by The Economist, namely affordability, availability and quality and safety. After deriving the first principal components xAFFi, xAViand xQSi in each of these three domains for each country i, we transformed these components in such a way that the transformed components would always be positive. This transformation is required because in PCA the value of each component will be negative for some of the countries. We therefore defined these transformed components as

$$ {y}_{AFFi}=\frac{\left({x}_{AFFi}-\mathit{\operatorname{Min}}\left\{{x}_{AFFi}\right\}\right)}{\left(\mathit{\operatorname{Max}}\left\{{x}_{AFFi}\right\}-\mathit{\operatorname{Min}}\left\{{x}_{AFFi}\right\}\right)} $$
(13)
$$ {y}_{AVi}=\frac{\left({x}_{AVi}-\mathit{\operatorname{Min}}\left\{{x}_{AVi}\right\}\right)}{\left(\mathit{\operatorname{Max}}\left\{{x}_{AVi}\right\}-\mathit{\operatorname{Min}}\left\{{x}_{AVi}\right\}\right)} $$
(14)
$$ {y}_{QSi}=\frac{\left({x}_{QSi}-\mathit{\operatorname{Min}}\left\{{x}_{QSi}\right\}\right)}{\left(\mathit{\operatorname{Max}}\left\{{x}_{QSi}\right\}-\mathit{\operatorname{Min}}\left\{{x}_{QSi}\right\}\right)} $$
(15)

Then, in a second stage, we apply a methodology originally proposed by Lovell et al. (1994). The idea is as follows.

Let FSi refer to the level of food security achieved in country i. Then a country’s endowment of inputs and food security achievement may be written as (yAFFi, yAVi, yQSi, FSi), i = 1 to I , I being the number of countries. The relative level of food security in country i, RFSi , may then be estimated using a Malmquist input quantity index by writing

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l} RF{S}_i\left(F{S}^{ref},{y}_{AFF i},{y}_{AV i},{y}_{QS i},{y}_{AFF}^{ref},{y}_{AV}^{ref},{y}_{QS}^{ref}\kern0.50em \right)\\ {}={D}_{inputs}\left(F{S}^{ref},{y}_{AFF i},{y}_{AV i},{y}_{QS i}\right)/{D}_{inputs}\left(F{S}^{ref},{y}_{AFF}^{ref},{y}_{AV}^{ref},{y}_{QS}^{ref}\right)\end{array}} $$
(16)

where \( {FS}^{ref},{y}_{AFF}^{ref},{y}_{AV}^{ref}\ \mathrm{and}\ {y}_{QS}^{ref} \) are respectively the level of food security, of affordability, availability and quality and safety in some hypothetic country of reference and Dinputs is an input distance function.

The idea behind the Malmquist index is to provide a reference set against which to judge the relative magnitudes of the two input vectors. This reference set is some isoquant L(FSref) and the radially further away from this isoquant the point corresponding to the inputs yAFFi, yAVi and yQSi is, the higher the relative level of food security, because these inputs must be reduced more to reach the isoquant of reference L(FSref).

The problem however is that such a Malmquist index is generally a function of this reference isoquant. To solve this issue, Lovell et al. (1994) suggested to proceed as follows (their analysis referred to individuals but we applied their ideas to countries). Treat all countries equally and assume that each country has the same level of food security, namely one unit of food security. Let e refer to such a level of food security so that the isoquant of reference may be written as (e) . This isoquant clearly bounds the input vectors from below because countries whose input vector locates them on L(e) have clearly the lowest possible level of food security and their relative level of food security will be equal to 1. Countries with larger input vectors will then have higher levels of food security and their relative level of food security will be higher than 1.

How can we estimate such a distance function? Lovell et al. (1994) proposed to define a (N − 1) dimensional vector z, N being the number of inputs. In our case N=3 and we define z as zi = (zAVi,  zQSi) with zAVi = (yAVi/yAFFi) and zQSi = (yQSi/yAFFi). We can then define an input distance function Dinputs(e, zi ) as

$$ {D}_{inputs}\left(e,{z}_i\kern0.5em \right)=\left(1/{y}_{AFFi}\right){D}_{inputs}\left(e,{y}_{AFFi},{y}_{AVi},{y}_{QSi}\kern0.5em \right) $$
(17)

and, since Dinputs(e, yAFFi, yAVi, yQSi ) ≥ 1, we may conclude that (1/yAFFi) ≤ Dinputs(e, zi ).

This implies that we may also write that

$$ \left(1/{y}_{AFFi}\right)={D}_{inputs}\left(e,{z}_i\kern0.5em \right)\ \mathit{\exp}\left(\upvarepsilon \right) $$
(18)

with ε ≤ 0.

If we now assume that Dinputs(e, zi ) has a translog functional form, we may write that

$$ \mathit{\ln}\left(1/{y}_{AFFi}\right)={\upalpha}_0+{\upalpha}_1\mathit{\ln}{z}_{AVi}+{\upalpha}_2\mathit{\ln}{z}_{QSi}+\left(1/2\right){\upalpha}_{12}\mathit{\ln}{z}_{AVi}\mathit{\ln}{z}_{QSi}+{\upvarepsilon}_i $$
(19)

Estimates of the coefficients α0, α1, α2 and α12 may be obtained using corrected ordinary least squares (see, Coelli et al. 1998, for more details on this technique) while the input distance function Dinputs(FSref, yAFFi, yAVi, yQSi) for each country i will be obtained via the transformation Dinputs(FSref, yAFFi, yAVi, yQSi) =  exp (Maxi} − εi).

This distance will, by definition, be greater than or equal to one (since its logarithm will be non-negative) and will hence indicate by how much a country’s inputs must be scaled down in order to reach the isoquant of reference. Such a procedure thus guarantees that all input vectors lie on or above the isoquant of reference L(e). The relative level of food security for country i will then be obtained by dividing Dinputs(e, zi ) by the minimum observed distance value, which by definition equals 1.

Another possibility is to use (10) to write that

$$ \mathit{\ln}\left(1/{y}_{AFFi}\right)={\upalpha}_0+{\upalpha}_1\mathit{\ln}{z}_{AVi}+{\upalpha}_2\mathit{\ln}{z}_{QSi}+\left(1/2\right){\upalpha}_{12}\mathit{\ln}{z}_{AVi}\mathit{\ln}{z}_{QSi}+{\upvarepsilon}_i $$
(20)
$$ \left(1/{y}_{AFFi}\right)=f\left({z}_{AVi},{z}_{QSi}\right) $$
(21)

that is, to consider the variable (1/yAFFi) as an output produced with the two inputs zAVi and zQSi and estimate the lower bound of the isoquants defining this production function via Data Envelopment Analysis, assuming evidently constant returns to scale.

This is what we did and in Section 4 we present empirical results derived from such an approach, using the program DEAP. This DEAP program, freely available, was written by Tim Coelli and is used to construct DEA frontiers for the calculation of technical and cost efficiencies and also for the calculation of Malmquist TFP (Total Factor Productivity) Indices.

This two stages analysis has been used in the past. In a paper on social exclusion in Macedonia, Deutsch et al. (2012) used in a first stage correspondence analysis to reduce the number of variables and in a second stage the stochastic production frontier approach The same approach has been used by Deutsch et al. (2013) who used the PISA data to estimate an education production function. In another paper on school externalities and scholastic performance, Deutsch et al. (2019) used correspondence analysis in a first stage and data envelopment analysis in the second stage.

Appendix 2: List of variables taken into account by the database of The Economist in the measurement of food security

1.1 AFFORDABILITY

  • Food consumption as a share of household expenditure

  • Proportion of population under global poverty line

  • Gross domestic product per capita (at PPP)

  • Agricultural import tariffs

  • Presence of food safety net programmers

  • Access to financing for farmers

1.2 AVAILABILITY

  • Sufficiency of supply

  • Average food supply

  • Dependency on chronic food aid

  • Public expenditure on agricultural R&D

  • Agricultural infrastructure

  • Existence of adequate crop storage facilities

  • Road infrastructure

  • Port infrastructure

  • Volatility of agricultural production

  • Political stability risk

  • Corruption

  • Urban absorption capacity

  • Food loss

1.3 QUALITY AND SAFETY

  • Diet diversification

  • Nutritional standards

  • National dietary guideline

  • National nutrition plan or strategy

  • Nutrition monitoring and surveillance

  • Micronutrient availability

  • Dietary availability of vitamin A

  • Dietary availability of animal iron

  • Dietary availability of vegetal iron

  • Protein quality

  • Food safety

  • Agency to ensure the safety and health of food

  • Percentage of population with access to potable water

  • Presence of formal grocery sector

Appendix 3: List of variables taken into account by the FAO to measure food security

1.1 Availability

  • Average dietary energy supply adequacy

  • Average value of food production

  • Share of dietary energy supply derived from cereals, roots and tubers

  • Average protein supply

  • Average supply of protein of animal origin

1.2 Access

  • Percent of paved roads over total roads

  • Road density

  • Rail lines density

  • Gross domestic product per capita (in purchasing power equivalent)

  • Average dietary energy supply adequacy

  • Average value of food production

  • Share of dietary energy supply derived from cereals, roots and tubers

  • Average protein supply

  • Average supply of protein of animal origin

  • Domestic food price index

  • Prevalence of undernourishment

  • Share of food expenditure of the poor

  • Depth of the food deficit

  • Prevalence of food inadequacy

1.3 Stability

  • Cereal import dependency ratio

  • Percent of arable land equipped for irrigation

  • Value of food imports over total merchandise exports

  • Political stability and absence of violence/terrorism

  • Domestic food price volatility

  • Per capita food production variability

  • Per capita food supply variability

1.4 Utilization

  • Access to improved water sources

  • Access to improved sanitation facilities

  • Percentage of children under 5 years of age affected by wasting

  • Percentage of children under 5 years of age who are stunted

  • Percentage of children under 5 years of age who are underweight

  • Percentage of adults who are underweight

  • Prevalence of anemia among pregnant women

  • Prevalence of anemia among children under 5 years of age

  • Prevalence of vitamin A deficiency in the population

  • Prevalence of iodine deficiency

Appendix 4

Table 7 Rankings of all the 105 countries for the various approaches

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Izraelov, M., Silber, J. An assessment of the global food security index. Food Sec. 11, 1135–1152 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12571-019-00941-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12571-019-00941-y

Keywords

Navigation