Skip to main content
Log in

How do generalist consumers coexist over evolutionary time? An explanation with nutrition and tradeoffs

  • ORIGINAL PAPER
  • Published:
Theoretical Ecology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Generalist consumers commonly coexist in many ecosystems. Yet, eco-evolutionary theory poses a problem with this observation: generalist consumers (usually) cannot coexist stably. To provide a solution to this theory-observation dissonance, we analyzed a simple eco-evolutionary consumer resource model. We modeled consumption of two nutritionally interactive resources by species which evolve their resource encounter rates subject to a tradeoff. As shown previously, consumers can ecologically coexist through tradeoffs in resource encounter rates; however, this coexistence is evolutionary unstable. Here, we find that nutritional interactions between resources and the shape of acquisition tradeoffs produce very similar evolutionary outcomes in isolation. Specifically, they produce evolutionarily stable communities composed either of two specialists (concave acquisition tradeoff or antagonistic nutrition) or a single generalist (convex acquisition tradeoff or complementary nutrition). Thus, the generalist-coexistence problem remains. However, the combination of nonlinear resource acquisition tradeoffs with nonlinear resource nutritional relationships creates selection forces that can push and pull against each other. Ultimately, this push-pull dynamic can stabilize the coexistence of two competing generalist consumers—but only when we coupled a convex acquisition tradeoff with antagonistic nutrition. Thus, our model here offers some resolution to the generalist-coexistence problem in eco-evolutionary, consumer-resource theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abrams PA (1987) Alternative models of character displacement and niche shift. I. Adaptive shifts in resource use when there is competition for nutritionally nonsubstitutable resources. Evolution 41:651–661

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abrams PA (2006) Adaptive change in the resource-exploitation traits of a generalist consumer: the coevolution and coexistence of generalists and specialists. Evolution 60:427–439

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Apaloo J, Brown JS, Vincent TL (2009) Evolutionary game theory: ESS, convergence stability, and NIS. Evol Ecol Res 11:489–515

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaver RA (1979) Host specificity of temperate and tropical animals. Nature 281:139–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernays E, Graham M (1988) On the evolution of host specificity in phytophagous arthropods. Ecology 69:886–892

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown JS, Vincent TL (1987) A theory for the evolutionary game. Theor Popul Biol 31:140–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown WL, Wilson EO (1956) Character displacement. Syst Zool 5:49–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chesson P (2000) Mechanisms of maintenance of species diversity. Annu Rev Ecol Syst 31:343–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Couzy F, Keen C, Gershwin ME, Mareschi JP (1992) Nutritional implications of the interactions between minerals. Prog Food Nutr Sci 17:65–87

    Google Scholar 

  • de Mazancourt C, Dieckmann U (2004) Trade‐off geometries and frequency‐dependent selection. Am Nat 164:765–778

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egas M, Dieckmann U, Sabelis MW (2004) Evolution restricts the coexistence of specialists and generalists: the role of trade‐off structure. Am Nat 163:518–531

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Eshel I (1983) Evolutionary and continuous stability. J Theor Biol 103:99–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feng Z, Liu R, DeAngelis DL, Bryant JP, Kieland K, Chapin FS, Swihart RK (2009) Plant toxicity, adaptive herbivory, and plant community dynamics. Ecosystems 12:534–547

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Fox JW, Vasseur DA (2008) Character convergence under competition for nutritionally essential resources. Am Nat 172:667–680

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Freeland WJ (1991) Plant secondary metabolites: biochemical evolution with herbivores. In: Palo R, Robbins CT (eds) Plant defenses against mammalian herbivory. CRC, Boca Raton, pp 61–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Friesen ML, Saxer G, Travisano M, Doebel M (2004) Experimental evidence for sympatric ecological diversification due to frequency‐dependent competition in Escherichia coli. Evolution 58:245–260

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Fussmann GF, Loreau M, Abrams PA (2007) Eco‐evolutionary dynamics of communities and ecosystems. Funct Ecol 21:465–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grover J (1997) Resource competition. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hathcock JN (1985) Metabolic mechanisms of drug-nutrient interactions. Fed Proc 44:124–199

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Huston MA (1994) Biological diversity: the coexistence of species. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Kisdi É (2006) Trade-off geometries and the adaptive dynamics of two co-evolving species. Evol Ecol Res 8:959–973

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawlor LR, Maynard Smith J (1976) The coevolution and stability of competing species. Am Nat 110:79–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levins R (1968) Evolution in changing environments. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • MacArthur RH (1970) Species packing and competitive equilibrium for many species. Theor Popul Biol 1:1–11

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • MacArthur RH (1972) Geographical ecology: patterns in the distribution of species. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J (1976) Evolution and the theory of games: in situations characterized by conflict of interest, the best strategy to adopt depends on what others are doing. Am Sci 64:41–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J (1982) Evolution and the theory of games. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Novotny V, Basset Y (2005) Host specificity of insect herbivores in tropical forests. Proc R Soc B 272:1083–1090

    Article  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak M (1990) An evolutionarily stable strategy may be inaccessible. J Theor Biol 142:237–241

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Polis GA (1991) Complex trophic interactions in deserts: an empirical critique of food-web theory. Am Nat 138:123–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Provenza FD, Villalba JJ, Dziba LE, Atwood SB, Banner RE (2003) Linking herbivore experience, varied diets, and plant biochemical diversity. Small Rumin Res 49:257–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reagan DP, Waide RB (eds) (1996) The food web of a tropical rain forest. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrigues AD (ed) (2013) Drug-drug interactions. CRC Press, Boca Raton

    Google Scholar 

  • Roff DA (2002) Life history evolution. Sinauer Associates, Sunderland

  • Roff DA, Fairbairn DJ (2007) The evolution of trade‐offs: where are we? J Evol Biol 20:433–447

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Rueffler C, Van Dooren TJM, Metz JAJ (2004) Adaptive walks on changing landscapes: Levins’ approach extended. Theor Popul Biol 65:165–178

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Rueffler C, Van Dooren TJM, Metz JAJ (2006) The evolution of resource specialization through frequency‐dependent and frequency‐independent mechanisms. Am Nat 167:81–93

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Rueffler C, Van Dooren TJM, Metz JAJ (2007) The interplay between behavior and morphology in the evolutionary dynamics of resource specialization. Am Nat 169:E34–E52

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Sandström B (2001) Micronutrient interactions: effects on absorption and bioavailability. Br J Nutr 85:S181–S185

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Stearns SC (1992) The evolution of life histories. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas JA (1995) Drug–nutrient interactions. Nutr Rev 53:271–282

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Tilman D (1980) Resources: a graphical-mechanistic approach to competition and predation. Am Nat 116:362–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tilman D (1982) Resource competition and community structure. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasseur DA, Fox JW (2011) Adaptive dynamics of competition for nutritionally complementary resources: character convergence, displacement, and parallelism. Am Nat 178:501–514

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Vincent TL, Brown JS (2005) Evolutionary game theory, natural selection, and darwinian dynamics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vincent TLS, Scheel D, Brown JS, Vincent TL (1996) Trade-offs and coexistence in consumer-resource models: it all depends on what and where you eat. Am Nat 148:1038–1058

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zu J, Wang JL (2013) Adaptive evolution of attack ability promotes the evolutionary branching of predator species. Theor Popul Biol 89:12–23

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the Hall lab staff—Marta Shocket, Alex Strauss, and Jessica Hite—for helpful suggestions on the manuscript. This work was supported by a National Science Foundation grant (0949547).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paul A. Orlando.

Appendix: Evolutionary stability under different resource nutritional interactions and different resource acquisition tradeoffs

Appendix: Evolutionary stability under different resource nutritional interactions and different resource acquisition tradeoffs

Different resource nutritional interactions

Mathematically, evolutionary equilibrium points occur where the derivative of the fitness function with respect to v, evaluated at v = u, is zero. The derivative of the fitness function is given by:

$$ \frac{\partial G}{\partial v}=b{R}_1^{\ast}\left(\mathbf{u}\right)-b{R}_2^{\ast}\left(\mathbf{u}\right)+b\beta {R}_1^{\ast}\left(\mathbf{u}\right){R}_2^{\ast}\left(\mathbf{u}\right)\left[1-2v\right] $$

One can see that the perfect generalist (v = u = 0.5) evaluates to zero and thus is an equilibrium point. Note that the perfect generalist will reduce both resources to the same equilibrium level (assuming resource supply rates are equal).

To evaluate specialist boundaries as equilibrium points, the fitness gradient needs not be 0. Instead, selection can keep a specialist stable if the landscape slopes up toward the specialist. That is, if the landscape has a positive or negative slope when evaluated at u = 1 (resource 1 specialist) or u = 0 (resource 2 specialist), respectively. We find that a specialist strategy is only selected for when resources are strongly antagonistic. When a single species is a specialist, the R * of the resource they specialize on will be m/b (remembering that resource encounter rate is 1 for a specialist). The other resource will be at its supply point (S), since it is not consumed. Plugging in the resource equilibrium values and the value of the evolutionary strategy, and simplifying, shows that a specialist becomes an evolutionary equilibrium point whenever β < 1/S − b/m. Numerical simulations show that this is the same condition for the existence of the two additional interior equilibrium points. Thus, β = 1/S − b/m is a bifurcation point where the stability properties of the model change from a single equilibrium point to three interior equilibrium points.

The curvature of the landscape at an equilibrium point allows us to determine whether the point is invadable or not (ESS). It is evaluated using the second derivative of the G-function with respect to the evolutionary variable v. This is given by

$$ \frac{\partial^2G}{\partial {v}^2}=-2b\beta {R}_1^{\ast}\left(\mathbf{u}\right){R}_2^{\ast}\left(\mathbf{u}\right) $$

Since R *s are always positive, the landscape is concave down (evolutionary maximum) when β > 0 (complementary resources), concave up (evolutionary minimum) when β < 0 (antagonistic resources), and has no curvature (evolutionary neutrality) when β = 0 (substitutable resources).

Whenever β < 0, two specialists are always evolutionarily stable. Substituting R 1 * = R 2 * = m/b and evaluating the derivative of the fitness function gives a negative value (b β (m/b)2) at u = 0 and a positive value (−b β (m/b)2) at u = 1. Recall that β is negative when resources are antagonistic.

Different resource acquisition tradeoffs

In this scenario, the fitness gradient is given by:

$$ \frac{\partial G}{\partial v}=b{R_1}^{\ast}\left(\mathbf{u}\right)-b{R_2}^{\ast}\left(\mathbf{u}\right){\left(1-{v}^{\alpha}\right)}^{\left(1/\alpha -1\right)}{v}^{\alpha -1} $$

The perfect generalist is located at u = (1/2)1/α. At this point, the fitness gradient evaluates to 0, demonstrating that the perfect generalist is an evolutionary equilibrium.

To evaluate the stability of the specialist strategies, we can calculate the derivate at the boundary values (u = v = 0 and u = v = 1). However, since this expression is undefined at these points, we take the limit of this derivative as these values are approached. Evaluating the limit as v = u approaches 1, and the associated R 1 * = m/b and R 2* = S, gives m for α < 1 (selection for specialist), m − bS for α = 1 (selection depends on which resource is more abundant), and –∞ for α > 1 (selection for generalist). Likewise, evaluating the limit of the derivative as u = v approaches 0, and the associated R 1 * = S and R 2 * = m/b, gives –∞ for α < 1 (selection for the specialist), bS − m for α = 1 (selection depends on which resource is more abundant), and bS for α > 1 (selection for generalist).

The second derivative is given by

$$ \frac{\partial^2G}{\partial {v}^2}=b{R}_2^{*}\left(\mathbf{u}\right)\left[\left(\frac{1}{\alpha }-1\right)\alpha {\left(1-{v}^{\alpha}\right)}^{\left(1/\alpha -2\right)}{v}^{2\left(\alpha -1\right)}-\left(\alpha -1\right){v}^{\left(\alpha -2\right)}{\left(1-{v}^{\alpha}\right)}^{\left(1/\alpha -1\right)}\right] $$

All terms in this equation are always positive other than the (1/α − 1) and (α − 1) terms. One can see that if α > 1 (convex tradeoff), the curvature of the adaptive landscape will be negative (evolutionary maximum), if α = 1 (linear tradeoff), it will be zero (neutral evolutionary point), and if α < 1 (concave tradeoff), it will be positive (evolutionary minimum).

To show that two specialists are stable when the tradeoff is concave (α < 1), we can evaluate the limit of the fitness gradient with two resident specialist strategies, as each specialist point is approached. The right hand side (resource 1 specialist) evaluates to m. The left hand side (resource 2 specialist) evaluates to –∞.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Orlando, P.A., Hall, S.R. How do generalist consumers coexist over evolutionary time? An explanation with nutrition and tradeoffs. Theor Ecol 8, 383–398 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12080-015-0257-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12080-015-0257-9

Keywords

Navigation