Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The energy efficiency model under the market response and the evolutionary path under its regulation policy in China

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Energy Efficiency Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

According to the causal relationship among energy efficiency, energy price, and economic growth in China, a network structure of mutual transmission is constructed and a novel model of nonlinear dynamic system is also established. With the help of numerical simulation, the impacts of the parameters on the motion state of the system and the subsystem are analyzed. Then, the parameters are identified by means of BP neural network, and the model of novel dynamic system is given, which has a practical significance to reflect the actual situation of the system in China. According to the state of the actual evolution, we analyze the regulatory effect of the policy on the state of the system and find that four policies can all make the unstable system become stable. Comparing and analyzing the regulatory effects of the single and combined policy on the system show that the combined policy has a shorter time to reach the stable state and it is more conducive to the reduction of energy price. However, the single policy has a better effect on improving the level of energy efficiency and economic growth. In addition, the evolutionary paths of energy efficiency are analyzed at different regulatory levels under the same policy, and the results show that the higher the regulatory level is and the shorter time it takes to reach steady state for energy efficiency, the lower the level of energy efficiency is.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16
Fig. 17
Fig. 18
Fig. 19
Fig. 20
Fig. 21
Fig. 22
Fig. 23
Fig. 24
Fig. 25
Fig. 26

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Ameena, A., Muhammad, Z., & Xi, J. Y. (2016). Energy prices and economic growth in Pakistan: A macro-econometric analysis. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 55, 25–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, K. H., Yang, H. Y., Lee, J. M., & Chi, C. F. (2016). The impact of energy prices on energy consumption and energy efficiency: Evidence from Taiwan. Energy Efficiency, 9, 1329–1349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, G. C., et al. (2012). Analysis and application of a novel three-dimensional energy-saving and emission-reduction dynamic evolution system. Energy, 40, 291–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, G. C., et al. (2013). The impacts of carbon tax on energy intensity and economic growth - a dynamic evolution analysis on the case of China. Applied Energy, 110, 17–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, G. C., et al. (2014). Government control or low carbon lifestyle?-analysis and application of a novel selective-constrained energy-saving and emission-reducing dynamic evolution system. Energy Policy, 68, 495–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Istemi, B., & Hakan, Y. (2014). Energy prices and economic growth in the long run: Theory and evidence. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 36, 228–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jang, C. J., et al. (2009). Energy prices, energy conservation, and economic growth: Evidence from the postwar United States. International Review of Economics and Finance, 18, 691–699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohler, M. (2014). Differential electricity pricing and energy efficiency in South Africa. Energy, 64, 524–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicholas, M. O. (2010). Energy consumption, prices and economic growth in three SSA countries: A comparative. Energy Policy, 38, 2463–2469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicola, C., Massimiliano, C., & Dirk, W. T. V. (2016). Does energy efficiency improve technological change and economic growth in developing countries? Energy Policy, 92, 279–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qin, F., & Rajah, R. (2014). Electricity consumption, technological innovation, economic growth and energy prices: Does energy export dependency and development levels matter? Energy Procedia, 61, 1142–1145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renuka, M., & John, A. A. (2007). Energy consumption, economic growth and prices: A reassessment using panel VECM for developed and developing countries. Energy Policy, 35, 2481–2490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, F. L., & Du, W. (2014). An analysis of the effects of economic growth, industrial structure and energy efficiency on carbon emission of Jilin Province. Applied Mechanics and Materials, 675, 1789–1792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, M., Tian, L. X., Fu, Y., & Qian, W. (2007). Dynamics and adaptive synchronization of the energy resource system. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals, 31, 879–888.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, M., Tian, L. X., & Zeng, C. Y. (2009). The energy resources system with parametric perturbations and its hyperchaos control. Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications, 10, 2620–2626.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Tian, R. J. (2017). Study on the promotion of natural gas-fired electricity with energy market reform in China using a dynamic game-theoretic model. Applied Energy, 185, 1832–1839.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vacim, A., et al. (2016). Energy efficiency, low-carbon energy production, and economic growth in CIS countries. IOP Conference Series: Earth and Environmental Science, 43, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, M. G., & Tian, L. X. (2015). Regulation effect of energy market-theoretical and empirical analysis based on a novel energy prices-energy supply-economic growth dynamic system. Applied Energy, 155, 526–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Q., Zhao, Z., Zhou, P., & Zhou, D. (2013). Energy efficiency and production technology heterogeneity in China: A meta-frontier DEA approach. Economic Modelling, 35, 283–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Q., Zhang, C., & Cai, W. (2017). Factor substitution and energy productivity fluctuation in China: A parametric decomposition analysis. Energy Policy, 109, 181–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, J. (2009). Energy efficiency and economic growth of China: 1953-2006. Ecological Economy, 5, 122–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, W. B., et al. (2016). The evolution model of electricity market on the stable development in China and its dynamic analysis. Energy, 114, 344–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, L. C. (2015). Energy prices, energy consumption intensity and economic growth. Enterprise Economy, 11, 166–170.

Download references

Funding

This research is supported by grants from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No: 71690242, 91546118, 11731014) and Postgraduate Research & Practice Innovation Program of Jiangsu Province (KYCX18_2256).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lixin Tian.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Appendix 1

Appendix 1

Verify

The subsystem (5) has a unique stable equilibrium point when \( \left\{\begin{array}{c}\frac{a_2{b}_1}{a_1{b}_2}>{E}^2- EC\\ {}\frac{a_1}{b_2}<\frac{E}{E-C}\end{array}\right., \) which has only one unstable equilibrium point when \( \frac{a_2{b}_1}{a_1{b}_2}<{E}^2- EC \) or \( \left\{\begin{array}{c}\frac{a_2{b}_1}{a_1{b}_2}>{E}^2- EC\\ {}\frac{a_1}{b_2}\ge \frac{E}{E-C}\end{array}\right.. \)

Proof

For the subsystem (5), there is a coefficient matrix \( A=\left(\begin{array}{cc}{a}_1E-{a}_1C& {a}_2\\ {}-{b}_1& -{b}_2E\end{array}\right) \), conclusions are as follows when |A| = a2b1 − a1b2E(E − C) ≠ 0.

The characteristic equation of the coefficient matrix A is

$$ {\lambda}^2+\left[{a}_1\left(E-C\right)-{b}_2E\right]\lambda +{a}_2{b}_1-{a}_1{b}_2E\left(E-C\right)=0\kern0.3em $$
(10)

The eigenvalues of the Eq. (10) are

$$ \frac{T\pm \sqrt{\Delta}}{2}. $$

Where \( \frac{T\pm \sqrt{\Delta}}{2},T={a}_1\left(E-C\right)-{b}_2E,D={a}_2{b}_1-{a}_1{b}_2E\left(E-C\right),\Delta ={T}^2-4D. \)

According to the equilibrium point, stability theorem and classification of differential equations:

  1. (1)

    When D = a2b1 − a1b2E(E − C) < 0, i.e. \( \frac{a_2{b}_1}{a_1{b}_2}<{E}^2- EC, \) then there is bound to be: \( \Delta ={T}^2-4D>0\Rightarrow \left\{\begin{array}{c}{\lambda}_1=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}>0\\ {}{\lambda}_2=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}<0\end{array}\right., \) so the equilibrium point is the unstable saddle point.

  2. (2)

    When \( \left\{\begin{array}{c}D={a}_2{b}_1-{a}_1{b}_2E\left(E-C\right)>0\kern0.1em \\ {}T={a}_1\left(E-C\right)-{b}_2E<0\kern2.1em \end{array}\right., \) i.e. \( \left\{\begin{array}{c}\frac{a_2{b}_1}{a_1{b}_2}>{E}^2- EC\\ {}\frac{a_1}{b_2}<\frac{E}{E-C}\kern0.1em \end{array}\right., \) there are three situations:

  3. 1)

    When \( \Delta ={T}^2-4D>0\Rightarrow \left\{\begin{array}{c}{\lambda}_1=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}<0\\ {}{\lambda}_2=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}<0\end{array}\right., \) so the equilibrium point is the node.

  4. 2)

    When \( \Delta ={T}^2-4D=0\Rightarrow {\lambda}_1={\lambda}_2=\frac{T}{2}<0, \) so the equilibrium point is an abnormal node or a critical node.

  5. 3)

    When \( \Delta ={T}^2-4D<0\Rightarrow \left\{\begin{array}{c}{\lambda}_1=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}\\ {}{\lambda}_2=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}\end{array}\right., \) the real parts of the eigenvalues are \( \frac{T}{2}<0, \) so the equilibrium point is a focus point.

  6. (3)

    When \( \left\{\begin{array}{c}D={a}_2{b}_1-{a}_1{b}_2E\left(E-C\right)>0\\ {}T={a}_1\left(E-C\right)-{b}_2E=0\kern2.1em \end{array}\right., \) i.e. \( \left\{\begin{array}{c}\frac{a_2{b}_1}{a_1{b}_2}>{E}^2- EC\\ {}\frac{a_1}{b_2}=\frac{E}{E-C}\end{array}\right., \) so the equilibrium point is the center and is unstable.

  7. (4)

    When \( \left\{\begin{array}{c}D={a}_2{b}_1-{a}_1{b}_2E\left(E-C\right)>0\\ {}T={a}_1\left(E-C\right)-{b}_2E>0\kern2.1em \end{array}\right., \) i.e. \( \left\{\begin{array}{c}\frac{a_2{b}_1}{a_1{b}_2}>{E}^2- EC\\ {}\frac{a_1}{b_2}>\frac{E}{E-C}\end{array}\right., \) there are three situations:

  8. 1)

    When \( \Delta ={T}^2-4D>0\Rightarrow \left\{\begin{array}{c}{\lambda}_1=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}>0\\ {}{\lambda}_2=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}>0\end{array}\right., \) so the equilibrium point is the node.

  9. 2)

    When \( \Delta ={T}^2-4D=0\Rightarrow {\lambda}_1={\lambda}_2=\frac{T}{2}>0, \) so the equilibrium point is an abnormal node or a critical node.

  10. 3)

    When \( \Delta ={T}^2-4D<0\Rightarrow \left\{\begin{array}{c}{\lambda}_1=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}\\ {}{\lambda}_2=\frac{T+\sqrt{\Delta}}{2}\end{array}\right., \) the real parts of the eigenvalues are \( \frac{T}{2}>0, \) so the equilibrium point is a focus point.

In summary, only when the following conditions are satisfied \( \left\{\begin{array}{l}D={a}_2{b}_1-{a}_1{b}_2E\left(E-C\right)>0\\ {}T={a}_1\left(E-C\right)-{b}_2E<0\kern2.1em \end{array}\right., \) i.e. \( \left\{\begin{array}{c}\frac{a_2{b}_1}{a_1{b}_2}>{E}^2- EC\\ {}\frac{a_1}{b_2}<\frac{E}{E-C}\end{array}\right., \) the equilibrium point is stable.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhang, G., Tian, L., Zhang, W. et al. The energy efficiency model under the market response and the evolutionary path under its regulation policy in China. Energy Efficiency 12, 895–920 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12053-018-9698-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12053-018-9698-5

Keywords

Navigation