Skip to main content
Log in

A Quality of Growth Index for Developing Countries: A Proposal

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper proposes a new quality of growth index for developing countries. The index encompasses both the intrinsic nature and social dimensions of growth, and is computed for over 90 countries for the period 1990–2011. The approach is premised on the fact that not all growth is created equal in terms of social outcomes, and that it does matter how one reaches from one level of income to another for various theoretical and empirical reasons. The paper finds that the quality of growth has been improving in the vast majority of developing countries over the past two decades, although the rate of convergence is relatively slow. At the same time, there are considerable cross-country variations across income levels and regions. Finally, empirical investigations point to the fact that main factors of the quality of growth are political stability, public pro-poor spending, macroeconomic stability, financial development, institutional quality and external factors such as FDI.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Apart from income levels, the HDI also encompasses important aspects of human development such as education and health.

  2. The social progress index encompasses three main dimensions: (1) the basic human needs, (2) the foundations of wellbeing, and (3) opportunity.

  3. Key trends and countries’ ranks are broadly robust to the direct use of GDP levels instead of GDP per capita.

  4. A more intuitive indicator is the HHI of GDP value added by sector. However, widespread missing data prevent us from using such data. More decisively, output diversification is highly correlated with exports diversification (Papageorgiou and Spatafora 2012).

  5. Net external demand equals to the difference between exports and imports, both as percent of GDP.

  6. This concern is somewhat addressed by accounting for the volatility of growth in the index.

  7. Several other opportunity variables (such as employment, inequality or poverty itself) and socially-friendly policy measures (including public spending allocated to health and education) are relevant candidates for capturing the pro-poor dimension of growth but are not considered in the construction of the QGI because of data limitation. Nevertheless, for the sake of robustness checks, we added the following three inclusiveness-related sub-components to the social dimension of the baseline QGI: educational equality (ratio of female to male primary schooling enrollment), geographical equality (ratio of rural to urban access to improved water), and generational equality (youth employment), using data from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators. The associated QGI is not qualitatively different from the baseline QGI (see “Appendices 10 and 11”). Note, however, that accounting for these variables shrinks the sample size, with the observations falling to 336, down from 372 in the baseline.

  8. Health and education are key components of the very well-known Human Development Index (Klugman et al. 2011).

  9. Note that using average years of primary schooling (instead of primary schooling completion rate does not qualitatively change the computed baseline QGI, though leading to a substantial reduction of the sample, with observations falling to 316, down from 372 in the baseline (see “Appendices 10 and 11”).

  10. Given that the equal weights are somehow arbitrary; we conduct a sensitivity test by using alternative weights in the Sect. 4.

  11. This aggregating approach is also used for the construction of the EVI (Guillaumont 2009).

  12. This assumption underpins the construction of the popular HDI.

  13. The country sub-sampling in terms of income refers to the World Bank’s classification of countries.

  14. The list of fragile countries is drawn upon from IMF (2011) which is based on the World Bank’s criteria of fragility while the list of resource-rich countries is extracted from IMF (2012).

  15. An approximation of the funds effectively transferred to developing countries, is computed by subtracting from total aid technical cooperation because it comprises education or training fees of nationals from recipient countries at home or abroad and payments to consultants or advisors for recipient countries. Furthermore, emergency flows (humanitarian aid, food aid) are subtracted as they are naturally countercyclical.

  16. Less charitably, this may rather reflect the ineffectiveness of foreign aid in improving the quality of growth in the recipient countries.

  17. Appendix 9” depicts signs and significance levels of the QGI’s drivers for different sub-sampling.

  18. For a detailed discussion on the debate on aid effectiveness, see Burnside and Dollar (2000), Collier and Dollar (2001), Guillaumont and Chauvet (2001) or Easterly et al. (2003).

  19. Note that “5” also corresponds to the interval over which the data are averaged in the calculation of the QGI.

References

  • Ames, B., Brown, W., Devarajan, S., & Izquierdo, A. (2001). Macroeconomic policy and poverty reduction. In Sourcebook for Proverty Reduction Strategies. Washington, DC: World Bank.

  • Anand, S., & Sen, A. (2000). Human development and economic sustainability. World Development, 28(12), 2029–2049.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anand, R., Mishra, S., & Peiris, S. (2013). Inclusive growth: Measurement and determinants, IMF Working Paper 13/135. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

  • Badinger, H. (2010). Output volatility and economic growth. Economics Letters, 106(1), 15–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & Lee, J. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman, J., Duryea, S., & Miguel, S. (1999). Schooling investments and macroeconomic conditions: A micro-macro investigation for Latin America and the Caribbean, IDB Working Paper No. 338.

  • Berg, A., Ostry, J., & Zettelmeyer, J. (2008). What makes growth sustained? Journal of Development Economics, 98(2), 149–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bils, M., & Peter, K. (2000). Does schooling cause growth? American Economic Review, 90, 1160–1183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burnside, C., & Dollar, D. (2000). Aid, policies, and growth. American Economic Review, 90(4), 847–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cariolle, J., Goujon, M., & Guillaumont, P. (2016). Has structural economic vulnerability decreased in least developed countries? Lessons drawn from retrospective indices. Journal of Development Studies, 52(5), 591–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Dehn, J. (2001). Aid, Shocks, and Growth. In Working paper 2688. Washington, DC: World Bank, October 2001.

  • Collier, P., & Dollar, D. (2001). Can the world cut poverty in half? How policy reform and effective aid can meet the international development goals? World Development, 29(11), 1787–1802.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Commission on Growth and Development. (2008). Growth report: Strategies for sustained growth and inclusive development. Washington: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diao, X., Rattsø, J., & Stokke, H. E. (2006). Learning by exporting and structural change: A ramsey growth model of Thailand. Journal of Policy Modeling, 28, 293–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dollar, D., Kleineberg, T., & Kraay, A. (2013). Growth is Still Good for the Poor. In World bank policy research working paper no. 6568. Washington: World Bank.

  • Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2002). Growth is good for the poor. Journal of Economic Growth, 7(3), 195–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W., Levine, R., & Roodman, D. (2003). New data, new doubts: Revisiting “aid, policies and growth”. In CGD working paper no. 26, June 2003 Washington: Centre for Global Development.

  • Guillaumont, P. (2009). An economic vulnerability index: Its design and use for international development policy. Oxford Development Studies, 37(3), 193–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guillaumont, P., & Chauvet, L. (2001). Aid and performance: A reassessment. Journal of Development Studies, 37(6), 66–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guillaumont, J. S., & Kpodar, R. (2006). Financial development, financial instability and poverty. CERDI Etudes et Documents E.2006.7.

  • Ianchovichina, E., & Lundstrom Gable, S. (2012) Forthcoming, in Chapter 8. In Arezki et al. (Eds.), Commodity price volatility and inclusive growth in low-income countries.

  • IMF. (2011). Macroeconomic and operational challenges in countries in fragile situations. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF. (2012). Macroeconomic policy frameworks for resource-rich developing countries. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jeanneney, S. G., & Tapsoba, S. J.-A. (2012). Aid and income stabilization. Review of Development Economics, 16(2), 216–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, S., Ostry, J. D., & Subramanian, A. S. (2007). The prospects for sustained growth in Africa: Benchmarking the constraints. In IMF working paper 07/52. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

  • Klugman, J., Rodriguez, F., & Choi, H. J. (2011). The HDI 2010: New controversies, old critiques. Human Development Research Paper 1. UNDP—HDRO, New York. http://hdr.undp.org/en/reports/global/hdr2011/papers/HDRP201101.pdf.

  • Loayza, N., & Raddatz, C. E. (2010). The composition of growth matters for poverty alleviation. Journal of Development Economics, 93(1), 137–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martinez, M., & Mlachila, M. (2013). The quality of the recent high-growth episode in Sub-Saharan Africa. In IMF working paper 13/53 Washington: International Monetary Fund.

  • Papageorgiou, C., & Spatafora, N. (2012). Economic Diversification in LICs: Stylized Facts and Macroeconomic Implications. In IMF staff discussion note no. SDN/12/13. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

  • Ramey, G., & Ramey, V. A. (1995). Cross-country evidence on the link between volatility and growth. American Economic Review, 85, 1138–1151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J. D., & Warner, A. M. (2001). The curse of natural resources. European Economic Review, 45, 827–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i-Martin, X. (2006). The world distribution of income: Falling poverty and… convergence period. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 351–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, P. (1999). Health and schooling investments in Africa. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(3), 67–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott, S., Wares, A., & Orzell, S. (2014). Social progress index 2014 methodological report. In P. O’Sullivan (Eds.), The Social Progress Imperative.

  • Sen, A. (2003). Concepts of Poverty. In Poverty and famines: An essay on entitlement and deprivation, Chapter 2. Oxford: Oxford Scholarship Online.

  • Yang, J. (2008). An Analysis of So-called Export-Led Growth. In IMF working paper 08/220. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank, without implication, Tidiane Kinda, Samba Mbaye, Marco Pani, and attendants at an African Department seminar. A special thank you to Promise Kamanga for excellent research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to René Tapsoba.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Appendix Table 4.

Table 4 Data sources and definition

Appendix 2. Dealing with Missing Observations in the Primary School Completion Rate

Observations for primary school completion rate are missing for some countries. In order to avoid reducing considerably the sample size when using this indicator as a proxy for the social dimension of the quality of growth, we estimate these missing observations according to the following approach:

  1. 1.

    First, we compute for each country the primary completion rate (Complest) by dividing the average years of primary schooling (from Barro and Lee 2013) with the average duration of primary school (from WDI, 2010).

  2. 2.

    Second, to ensure that the computed completion rates (Complest) are consistent with the actual rates, we proceed as follows:

    • For a given country at a given year, if the actual completion rate (Complact) is available, then we keep this Complact as the completion rate (Compl) to be considered for the calculation of the QGI index.

    • For a given country at a given year, if Complact is missing, then we consider Complest adjusted for the average deviation between Complest and Complact (in the neighborhood of the year for which Complact is missing). The neighborhood considered spans from the 5 years preceding the year for which the observation is missing to the 5 years following the year for which the observation is missing.Footnote 19

      $$Compl_{it} = Compl\_est_{it} + \lambda_{it}$$

      where i et t stands for country i and period t, respectively, with \(\lambda_{it} = mean(Compl\_act_{ij} - Compl\_est_{it} ),\quad j = \overline{t - 4,\;t + 4}\).

Appendix 3

See Appendix Table 5.

Table 5 Country ranking using geometric mean-based QGI

Appendix 4

See Appendix Table 6.

Table 6 QGI for the full sample over 1990–2011: descriptive statistics

Appendix 5

See Appendix Table 7.

Table 7 Correlation matrix of the alternative QGIs

Appendix 6

See Appendix Table 8.

Table 8 Spearman’s rank order correlation test (Arithmetic mean-based vs. Geometric mean-based QGI)

Appendix 7

See Appendix Table 9.

Table 9 Spearman’s rank order correlation test

Appendix 8

See Appendix Table 10.

Table 10 Correlation matrix between the benchmark QGI and the region-specific QGI

Appendix 9

See Appendix Table 11.

Table 11 Determinants of quality of growth on different subsamples

Appendix 10

See Appendix Table 12.

Table 12 Descriptive statistics for additional robustness checks-related QGI (full sample over 1990–2011)

Appendix 11

See Appendix Table 13.

Table 13 Correlation matrix for additional robustness checks-related QGI (full sample over 1990–2011)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mlachila, M., Tapsoba, R. & Tapsoba, S.J.A. A Quality of Growth Index for Developing Countries: A Proposal. Soc Indic Res 134, 675–710 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-016-1439-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-016-1439-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation