Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Taxes, corruption, and entry

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Tax policies and corruption are important institutional considerations which can shape entrepreneurship. We investigate how tax rates, and the interaction between corruption and tax rates, influence variations in entry across a panel of 72 countries in the period 2005–2011. We use a series of panel estimations as well as several robustness checks to test these effects, using relevant controls for economic development, the size of the state, and other regulatory and tax policy measures. We find that higher tax rates consistently discourage entry. Further, we find that although the direct influence of corruption on entry is also consistently negative, the interaction influence of corruption and tax rate is positive. This indicates that corruption can offset the negative influence of high taxes on entry. We discuss the implications of our findings for policymakers and future research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Many studies, mostly pre-mid-2000s, proxied entrepreneurship as self-employment (see Ács et al. 2014; Bruce 2000, 2002; Gentry and Hubbard 2000; Parker 1996). Some found a positive relationship between tax rate and self-employment in developed countries. Evans and Leighton (1989a, b) and Blau (1987) studied the US context, and Bacher and Brülhart (2010) studied the Swiss context, both finding a positive relationship of tax progressivity and self-employment. However, some found negative, mixed, or insignificant effects. A negative influence of marginal tax rate on self-employment was found for Canadian microdata (Stabile 2004); similar findings emerged for the US and Canada (Schuetze 2000) and the UK (Parker 1996; Blanchflower and Oswald 1990). For Sweden, Fölster (2002) and Davis and Henrekson (1999) found a negative relationship between tax rates and self-employment, and Hansson (2012) found a negative relationship for both marginal and average tax rates. Another set of studies found no significance for tax rate and self-employment (Baliamoune-Lutz and Garello 2014; Bruce and Mohsin 2006; Parker 2003; OECD 2000). Mixed findings of different measures are not unusual: Robson and Wren (1999) studied OECD countries and found a positive relationship of self-employment with average tax rate, but a negative relationship with marginal tax rate. The distinction between self-employment (labor market trend) versus entry (new firm formation) has emerged, e.g related to educational level (Blanchflower 2004; Parker 2009) or conditions of unemployment and necessity (Arum and Müller 2004a, b). We do not examine self-employment in this study as we concerned with businesses most likely influenced by tax rates: new formal firms. For more on self-employment versus entrepreneurship, see Blanchflower (2004), Parker (2009) and Arum and Müller (2004a, b).

  2. Value-added tax (VAT) is another tax policy tool which could enhance the desirability of corruption. Although many countries have adopted VAT, individuals might not register their business to lower tax liability, or register but submit personal expense invoices as business expense (Alm 2012; Gordon and Li 2009). Another strategy could be to buy or sell from firms owned by the same individual, within a country or overseas.

  3. Two things are noteworthy about our time period, 2005–2011, which was restricted by data availability. First, results could be affected by the global recession, which occurred during this period. We accept this as a limitation which can be illuminated in future research as data availability improves. Second, as we detail in our discussion of the dependent variable, we use formal entry density to measure entrepreneurship. This standardized measure counts limited liability companies in a country using a well-defined process, so our measure captures registered firms which we infer to have been able to pay registration costs (and therefore would comply with tax and other regulations in the future), and are likely to have more financial resources than the self-employed or other entrepreneurs who act because they lack other opportunities (necessity entrepreneurship). The use of this specific measure for entrepreneurship, to some degree, protects our results from being affected drastically by the recession.

  4. We are grateful to one of the reviewers of this paper for this suggestion.

  5. We also conducted a set of checks using a third measure of corruption from the Heritage Foundation’s Index of Economic Freedom. This measure is derived in part with Transparency International (TI) and is correlated with the CPI measure (+92), so we do not report it here and consider the use of CPI adequate for our purposes.

References

  • Ács, Z. J., Autio, E., & Szerb, L. (2014). National systems of entrepreneurship: Measurement issues and policy implications. Research Policy, 43(3), 476–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., Braunerhjelm, P., Audretsch, D. B., & Carlsson, B. (2009). The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 32(1), 15–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., Desai, S., & Klapper, L. F. (2008). What does “entrepreneurship” data really show? Small Business Economics, 31(3), 265–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidis, R., Estrin, S., & Mickiewicz, T. (2012). Size matters: Entrepreneurial entry and government. Small Business Economics, 39, 119–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alm, J. (2012). Measuring, explaining, and controlling tax evasion: Lessons from theory, experiments, and field studies. International Tax and Public Finance, 19(1), 54–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anokhin, S., & Schulze, W. S. (2009). Entrepreneurship, innovation, and corruption. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(5), 465–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Appelbaum, E., & Katz, E. (1996). Corporate taxation, incumbency advantage and entry. European Economic Review, 40, 1817–1828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arum, R., & Müller, W. (2004a). The return of self-employment: A cross-national study of self-employment and social inequality. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arum, R., & Müller, W. (2004b). The reemergence of self-employment: Comparative findings and empirical propositions. In R. Arum & W. Müller (Eds.), The reemergence of self-employment. A comparative study of self-employment dynamics and social inequality (pp. 426–454). Princeton, Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Belitski, M. (2013). The missing pillar: The creativity theory of knowledge spillover entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 41(4), 819–836.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D., Belitski, M., & Desai, S. (2015). Entrepreneurship and economic development in cities. Annals of Regional Sciences, 55(1), 33–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Feldman, M. P. (1996). R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. The American Economic Review, 86, 630–640.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Lehmann, E. E. (2005). Does the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship hold for regions? Research Policy, 34(8), 1191–1202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bacher, H. U., & Brülhart, M. (2010). Progressive taxes and firm births. Working paper, CEPR DP7830. www.cepr.org/pubs/dps/DP7830.asp.

  • Baker, T., Gedajlovic, E., & Lubatkin, M. (2005). A framework for comparing entrepreneurship processes across nations. Journal of International Business Studies, 36(5), 492–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baliamoune-Lutz, M. (2015). Taxes and entrepreneurship in OECD countries. Contemporary Economic Policy, 33(2), 369–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baliamoune-Lutz, M., & Garello, P. (2014). Tax structure and entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 42, 165–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship, productive, unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 893–921.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belitski, M., & Desai, S. (2015). What drives ICT clustering in European cities? The Journal of Technology Transfer. doi:10.1007/s10961-015-9422-y

  • Blanchflower, D. G. (2004). Self-employment: More may not be better. No. w10286. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Blanchflower, D., & Oswald, A. (1990). What makes a young entrepreneur? No. 373.

  • Blau, D. (1987). A time series analysis of self-employment in the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 95, 223–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bologna, J., & Ross, A. (2015). Corruption and entrepreneurship: Evidence from a random audit program. No. 15-05.

  • Braithwaite, J. (2006). Responsive regulation and developing economies. World Development, 34(5), 884–898.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, D. (2000). Effects of the United States tax system on transitions into self-employment. Labour Economics, 7(5), 545–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, D. (2002). Taxes and entrepreneurial endurance, evidence from the self-employed. National Tax Journal, 54(1), 5–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, D., & Mohsin, M. (2006). Tax policy and entrepreneurship: New time series evidence. Small Business Economics, 26(5), 409–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campos, N., Dimova, R., & Saleh, A. (2010). Whither corruption? A quantitative survey of the literature on corruption and growth. CEPR discussion paper no. 8140.

  • Carree, M., van Stel, A., Thurik, R., & Wennekers, S. (2002). Economic development and business ownership: An analysis using data of 23 OECD countries in the period 1976–1996. Small Business Economics, 19, 271–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, R., Holtz-Eakin, D., Rider, M., & Rosen, H. S. (2001). Personal income taxes and the growth of small firms. In J. Poterba (Ed.), Tax policy and the economy (Vol. 15, pp. 121–147). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chowdhury, F., Desai, S., Audretsch, D. B., & Belitski, M. (2015). Does corruption matter for international entrepreneurship? International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 11(4), 959–980.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost (pp. 87–137). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2006). Who cares about corruption? Journal of International Business Studies, 37(6), 807–822.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cullen, J. B., & Gordon, R. H. (2007). Taxes and entrepreneurial risk-taking: Theory and evidence for the US. Journal of Public Economics, 91(7), 1479–1505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Da Rin, M., Di Giacomo, M., & Sembenelli, A. (2011). Entrepreneurship, firm entry, and the taxation of corporate income: Evidence from Europe. Journal of Public Economics, 95(9), 1048–1066.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, S. J., & Henrekson, M. (1999). Explaining national differences in the size and industry distribution employment. Small Business Economics, 12(1), 59–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, S., Acs, Z., & Weitzel, U. (2013). A model of destructive entrepreneurship insight for conflict and postconflict recovery. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(1), 20–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., Ganser, T., McLiesh, C., Ramalho, R., & Shleifer, A. (2010). The effect of corporate taxes on investment and entrepreneurship. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2, 31–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., LaPorta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). The regulation of entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics CXVII, 1, 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doerrenberg, P., & Peichl, A. (2013). Progressive taxation and tax morale. Public Choice, 155(3–4), 293–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domar, E. D., & Musgrave, R. A. (1944). Proportional income taxation and risk-taking. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 58(3), 388–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., & Gassebner, M. (2013). Greasing the wheels? The impact of regulations and corruption on new firm entry. Public Choice, 155(3–4), 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Estrin, S., Korosteleva, J., & Mickiewicz, T. (2013). Which institutions encourage entrepreneurial growth aspirations? Journal of Business Venturing, 28, 564–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Estrin, S., Meyer, K. E., & Bytchkova, M. (2006). Entrepreneurship in transition economies. In M. C. Casson, et al. (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Entrepreneurship. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. S., & Leighton, L. S. (1989a). Some empirical aspects of entrepreneurship. The American Economic Review, 79(3), 519–535.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. S., & Leighton, L. S. (1989b). The determinants of changes in US self-employment, 1968–1987. Small Business Economics, 1(2), 111–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fölster, S. (2002). Do lower taxes stimulate self-employment? Small Business Economics, 19, 135–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fossen, F., & Steiner, V. (2009). Income taxes and entrepreneurial choice: Empirical evidence from two German natural experiments. Empirical Economics, 36, 487–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch, M., & Schroeter, A. (2011). Why does the effect of new business formation differ across regions? Small Business Economics, 36, 383–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gentry, W. M., & Hubbard, R. G. (2000). Tax policy and entrepreneurial entry. The American Economic Review, 90(2), 283–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gentry, W. M., & Hubbard, R. G. (2004). Success taxes, entrepreneurial entry, and innovation (Vol. 10551). NBER working paper.

  • Gordon, R., & Li, W. (2009). Tax structures in developing countries: Many puzzles and a possible explanation. Journal of Public Economics, 93(7), 855–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurley-Calvez, T., & Bruce, D. (2013). Do tax rate cuts encourage entrepreneurial entry? Journal of Entrepreneurship and Public Policy, 2(2), 178–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansson, Å. (2012). Tax policy and entrepreneurship: Empirical evidence from Sweden. Small Business Economics, 38, 495–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M., Johansson, D., & Stenkula, M. (2010). Taxation, labor market policy and high-impact entrepreneurship. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 10(3–4), 275–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2006). Governance matters V: Governance indicators for 19962005. World Bank policy research working paper.

  • Keuschnigg, C., & Nielsen, S. B. (2002). Tax policy, venture capital, and entrepreneurship. Journal of Public Economics, 87(1), 175–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klapper, L., Laeven, L., & Rajan, R. (2006). Entry regulation as a barrier to entrepreneurship. Journal of Financial Economics, 82(3), 591–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klapper, L., & Love, I. (2010). The impact of business environment reforms on new firm registration. World Bank policy research working paper 5493.

  • Kobrin, S. J. (1978). When does political instability result in increased investment risk. Columbia Journal of World Business, 13(3), 113–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korosteleva, J., & Mickiewicz, T. (2011). Startup finance in the age of globalisation. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 47(3), 23–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahagaonkar, P. (2008). Corruption and innovation: A grease or sand relationship? No. 017. Jena economic research papers.

  • McMullen, J. S., Bagby, D., & Palich, L. E. (2008). Economic freedom and the motivation to engage in entrepreneurial action. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 32(5), 875–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Méon, P.-G., & Sekkat, K. (2005). Does corruption grease or sand the wheels of growth? Public Choice, 122(1), 69–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2000). The employment outlook. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. (1996). A time series model of self-employment under uncertainty. Economica, 63(251), 459–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2003). Does tax evasion affect occupational choice? Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65, 379–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2009). The economics of entrepreneurship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pathak, S., Xavier-Oliveira, E., & Laplume, A. O. (2015). Entrepreneurship in transition economies: The role of corruption and individual attributes. Journal of Balkan and Near Eastern Studies, 17(4), 427–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson, M. T., & Wren, C. (1999). Marginal and average tax rates and the incentives for selfemployment. Southern Economic Journal, 65(4), 757–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodríguez-Pose, A., & Storper, M. (2006). Better rules or stronger communities? On the social foundations of institutional change and economic effects. Economic Geography, 82(1), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1994). New goods, old theory, and the welfare cost of trade restrictions. Journal of Development Economics, 43(1), 5–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schuetze, H. J. (2000). Taxes, economic conditions and recent trends in male self-employment: A Canada–US comparison. Labour Economics, 7(5), 507–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), 599–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1994). Politicians and firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 995–1026.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (2002). The grabbing hand: Government pathologies and their cures. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, R. S. (2008). Testing Baumol: Institutional quality and the productivity of entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, 23(6), 641–655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stabile, M. (2004). Payroll taxes and the decision to be selfemployed. International Tax and Public Finance, 11, 31–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stenholm, P., Acs, Z. J., & Wuebker, R. (2013). Exploring country-level institutional arrangements on the rate and type of entrepreneurial activity. Journal of Business Venturing, 28(1), 176–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi, V., & Davoodi, H. R. (2000). Corruption, growth, and public finances, IMF Working Paper No. 00/182.

  • Thai, M. T. T., & Turkina, E. (2014). Macro-level determinants of formal entrepreneurship versus informal entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, 29(4), 490–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tonoyan, V., Strohmeyer, R., Habib, M., & Perlitz, M. (2010). Corruption and entrepreneurship: How formal and informal institutions shape small firm behavior in transition and mature market economies. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34(5), 803–831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Torrini, R. (2005). Cross-country differences in self-employment rates: The role of institutions. Labour Economics, 12(5), 661–683.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Stel, A., Storey, D., & Thurik, A. (2007). The effect of business regulations of nascent and young business entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 28(2–3), 171–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Webb, J. W., Tihanyi, L., Ireland, R. D., & Sirmon, D. G. (2009). You say illegal, I say legitimate: Entrepreneurship in the informal economy. Academy of Management Review, 34(3), 492–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weston, V. F., & Sorge, B. W. (1972). International Managerial Finance. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin Inc.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank David Audretsch, Johan Eklund, Magnus Henrekson, and participants at Academy of International Business for comments. Farzana Chowdhury thanks Erik Stam and Siri Terjesen.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Farzana Chowdhury.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Belitski, M., Chowdhury, F. & Desai, S. Taxes, corruption, and entry. Small Bus Econ 47, 201–216 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-016-9724-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-016-9724-y

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation