Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Dependent self-employment as a way to evade employment protection legislation

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines whether the strictness of employment protection legislation encourages employers to contract out work to their own paid employees by the formula of dependent self-employment, while making transitions to independent self-employment less likely by altering the relative valuation of risk between salaried work and self-employment in favour of the former. In conducting this analysis, discrete choice models are applied to data drawn from the European Community Household Panel from 1994 to 2001. To test the hypotheses, a tentative individual measure of the potential severance payment that a worker would receive in the case of dismissal is included as well as aggregated variables that try to capture differences in labour market institutions and macroeconomic conditions. Evidence for a positive impact of the strictness of employment protection legislation and the potential severance payment on transitions to dependent self-employment is found. The opposite effects, however, are detected for individuals becoming independent self-employed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. EPL comprises measures designed to protect the rights of employees at work. As defined by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), employment protection refers to regulations about hiring (e.g. rules favouring disadvantaged groups, conditions for using temporary or fixed-term contracts, and training requirements) and firing (e.g. redundancy procedures, mandated pre-notification periods and severance payments, special requirements for collective dismissals, and short-time work schemes). EPL, in turn, refers to all types of employment protection measures, whether grounded primarily in legislation, court rulings, collectively bargained conditions of employment or customary practice (Parker 2007).

  2. The ECHP data are used with the permission of Eurostat (contract ECHP/2006/09, held with the Universidad de Huelva).

  3. Parker (2002) presents an overview of the modern theory and evidence of credit rationing. Parker (2003a) proposes a model of credit markets under asymmetric information in which individuals differ in abilities that are valued in both entrepreneurship and paid employment.

  4. See van Stel (2005) for details.

  5. See for example, Blau (1987), Parker (1996, 2003b), Robson and Wren (1999), Parker and Robson (2004), Bruce and Schuetze (2004) and Schuetze (2000, 2008).

  6. Examples of microeconometric evaluations of start-up subsidies are Meager et al. (2003) for the UK, Perry (2006) for New Zealand, Cueto and Mato (2006) for Spain, Pfeiffer and Reize (2000), Baumgartner and Caliendo (2008) and Caliendo and Kritikos (2009) for Germany and Carling and Richardson (2004) for Sweden.

  7. For a review of the few studies that evaluate the effects of ALMP from a macro point of view, see Boone and van Ours (2004).

  8. The most extensive issue analysed by empirical studies on this topic has been the effect of unemployment benefit replacement rates on self-employment participation, obtaining a consistent negative impact (e.g. Staber and Bogenhold 1993; Ilmakunnas and Kanniainen 2001; Robson 2003; Parker and Robson 2004; Kanniainen and Vesala 2005; Torrini 2005; Hessels et al. 2007; Robson 2007). In addition, Robson (2007) focusses on the effect of the generosity of old age, disability and death benefits; sickness and health benefits; and unemployment benefits. Finally, attempts to capture the effect of social security contributions of the self-employed are those by Centeno (2000) and Hessels et al. (2007). See Schoukens (1999) for a detailed description of all the European systems.

  9. Supiot (2001), Pedersini (2002), Perulli (2003) and Sciarra (2005) provide a European perspective. For international aspects see OECD (2000) and ILO (2003).

  10. Approaches to DSE are not homogeneous. By using data from the Australian Bureau of Statistics (Forms of Employment Survey for 2000), Waite and Will (2001) distinguish dependent and independent contractors. The dependent contractors are persons employed on a commercial contract but with work arrangements consistent with their being employees. Böheim and Müehlberger (2009) define DSE as self-employed workers who have no employees and only one customer, using data drawn from the British Labour Force Survey between 1999 and 2005. Finally, Müehlberger and Pasqua (2009) make use of individuals that work on the basis of a contract of continuous and coordinated collaboration by means of data from the Italian Labour Force Survey 2004.

  11. Luxembourg and Sweden have to be excluded from our analysis because these countries present missing values in relevant variables.

  12. For instance, to identify a transition from paid employment to DSE, we need the following information from the individual: (i) declaring herself as a paid employee in the 1995 survey; (ii) declaring herself as self-employed in the 1996 survey; and (iii) declaring in both surveys, 1995 and 1996, that she started working for her current employer or at the same business in 1995 or before.

  13. The cyclical position of the economy can be defined as the difference between actual output and the level of potential output that can be sustained without generating inflationary pressures in the economy. We have obtained similar results by considering harmonised unemployment rates and employment rates (OECD) as alternative measure of macroeconomic conditions. Since the output gap presented lower correlations with variables capturing labour market institutional differences, it was included in our final specifications.

  14. For each country, EPL is described using 18 basic items, which can be grouped into three main areas: (i) employment protection of regular workers against individual dismissal; (ii) specific requirements for collective dismissals; and (iii) regulation of temporary forms of employment. For further details on the aggregation of these items, see OECD (1999). More information on the evolution and updating of these indexes is available at OECD (2004).

  15. See Appendix B for further details on the construction of this variable.

  16. See note 22 for further details on the exclusion of this sector from our analysis.

  17. We decided not to include part-time employment in our estimations. This is due to the fact that those individuals doing two jobs at the same time might face short-term problems in one of the two activities, and look for complementary incomes for a certain period of time. That would make the determinants of the transitions of those individuals simultaneously performing both jobs different from the determinants of those who opt for a single activity. We believe, therefore, that part-time self-employment needs to be independently analysed.

  18. The labour force status is observed once per year. Thus, if there are additional changes in status within the year, they are missed. It is assumed that there are few of these and that their exclusion does not affect the results.

  19. Following usual conventions, we model random individual effects and assume this term as a normally distributed random variable with mean 0 and variance u n and independence from all observable characteristics.

  20. The same process has been repeated using a probit and a complementary log–log specification of F(·). These estimations do not alter our empirical conclusions in any significant way.

  21. The robustness of our t-statistics has been checked by re-estimating them from variance–covariance matrixes of the coefficients obtained by bootstrapping.

  22. Comparing our results with those obtained in the existing literature is a difficult task, plausible only to a certain extent. To the best of our knowledge, only Robson (2003) separately analyses the effects of EPL index for regular and temporary employment. However, Robson’s geographical scope, methods and nature of data, number of observations and even the OECD measures of EPL for regular and temporary contracts (which are not time-dependent) are different from those used in the current study.

  23. Within this strategy, a dummy for the agricultural sector and some interactions measuring the effect of institutions for the agricultural sector were included in regressions II and III. These interactions offered some differences in the role of labour market regulation between workers for agriculture and the rest of the economy. However, these results were not robust across both regressions, and we decided to definitively exclude this sector from our analysis.

  24. As hypothesis 3 states, the following subsections will reveal that both ISE and DSE are positively affected by the presence of these incentives.

  25. We compare our results on social security benefits with those of Robson (2007) since he also breaks the SSLI into its three constituent components. However, unlike in our study, Robson includes the agricultural sector in the analysis.

  26. See Carrasco (1999).

  27. Similarly to Robson (2007), as an alternative measure of the unemployment benefits system, we included the OECD unemployment benefit replacement rates in some additional estimations, which are available upon request. By so doing, we obtained a negative effect on individuals entering self-employment, as expected given the robustness of this result in the existing literature.

  28. It may seem surprising that nearly half of the transitions from paid employment to self-employment are of the DSE kind. However, an individual entering DSE must necessarily switch from paid employment, as the existence of a previous employer is required. Taking this into account as we analyse transitions from paid employment, we are able to identify within our sample all the existing transitions to DSE. By contrast, when we focus on ISE, transitions from paid employment are not the only route, and other entrants from unemployment or out of the labour force (discouraged worker or economically inactive) are not captured.

  29. In this sense, specifications II and III report significant results at the 1% level for this variable.

References

  • Autor, D. H. (2003). Outsourcing at will: The contribution of unjust dismissal doctrine to the growth of employment outsourcing. Journal of Labor Economics, 21(1), 1–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumgartner, H. J., & Caliendo, M. (2008). Turning unemployment into self-employment: Effectiveness of two start-up programmes. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 70(3), 347–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C., & Foss, N. J. (2008). Economic freedom and entrepreneurial activity: Some cross country evidence. Public Choice, 134, 307–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, D. M. (1987). A time-series analysis of self-employment in the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 95, 445–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böheim, R., & Müehlberger, U. (2009). Dependent self-employment: Workers between employment and self-employment in the UK. Journal of Labour Market Research, 42(2), 182–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boone, J., & van Ours, J. C. (2004). Effective active labor market policies. IZA Discussion Papers 1335, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).

  • Botero, J., Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). The regulation of labor. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 1339–1382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, D., & Schuetze, H. J. (2004). Tax policy and entrepreneurship. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 2(11), 233–265.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burchell, B., Deakin, S., Honey, S. (1999). The employment status of individuals in non-standard employment. Employment relations Research Series 6. London: Department of Trade and Industry. http://www.dti.gov.uk/files/file11628.pdf.

  • Caliendo, M., & Kritikos, A. S. (2009). Start-ups by the unemployed: Characteristics, survival and direct employment effects. Small Business Economics. doi:10.1007/s11187-009-9208-4.

  • Carling, K., & Richardson, K. (2004). The relative efficiency of labor market programs: Swedish experience from the 1990’s. Labour Economics, 11(3), 335–354.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrasco, R. (1999). Transitions to and from self-employment in Spain: An empirical analysis. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 61(3), 315–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Centeno, M. (2000). Is self-employment a response to labour market rigidity? Economic Bulletin, Banco de Portugal, December, 37–44.

  • Collins, H. (1990). Independent contractors and the challenge of vertical integration to employment protection laws. Oxford Journal of Legal Studies, 10(3), 353–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cueto, B., & Mato, J. (2006). An analysis of self-employment subsidies with duration models. Applied Economics, 38, 23–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delage, B. (2002). Results from the survey of self-employment in Canada. Hull, QC: Human Resources Development Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freedman, J., & Chamberlain, E. (1997). Horizontal equity and the taxation of employed and self-employed workers. Fiscal Studies, 18(1), 87–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubb, D., & Wells, W. (1993). Employment regulation and patterns of work in EC countries. OECD Economic Studies, 21, 7–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M. (2007). Entrepreneurship and institutions. Comparative Labor Law and Policy Journal, 28, 717–742.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M., & Roine, J. (2007). Promoting entrepreneurship in the welfare state. In D. B. Audretsch, I. Grilo, & A. R. Thurik (Eds.), The handbook of research on entrepreneurship policy (pp. 64–93). Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, US: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hessels, J., van Stel, A., Brouwer, P., & Wennekers, S. (2007). Social security arrangements and early-stage entrepreneurial activity. Comparative Labor Law and Policy Journal, 28, 743–774.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas, P., & Kanniainen, V. (2001). Entrepreneurship, economic risks and risk insurance in the welfare state: Results with OECD data 1978–93. German Economic Review, 2, 195–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ILO. (2003). The scope of the employment relationship. Report V. International Labour Conference. 91st Session. Geneva. http://www.ilo.org/public/english/standards/relm/ilc/ilc91/pdf/rep-v.pdf.

  • Kanniainen, V., & Vesala, T. (2005). Entrepreneurship and labour market institutions. Economic Modelling, 22, 828–847.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klapper, L., Laevena, L., & Raghuram, R. (2007). Entry regulation as a barrier to entrepreneurship. Journal of Financial Economics, 82, 591–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kugler, A., & Pica, G. (2008). Effects of employment protection on worker and job flows: Evidence from the 1990 Italian reform. Labour Economics, 15, 78–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meager, M., Bates, P., & Cowling, M. (2003). An evaluation of business start-up support for young people. National Institute Economic Review, 186, 59–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen, D. (1986). Job search and labor market analysis. In O. C. Ashenfelter & R. Layard (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (Vol. II, pp. 849–919). North-Holland, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Müehlberger, U., & Pasqua, S. (2009). Workers on the border between employment and self-employment. Review of Social Economy, 67(2), 201–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nyström, K. (2008). The institutions of economic freedom and entrepreneurship: Evidence from panel data. Public Choice, 136(3), 269–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (1992). The employment outlook (Chap. 4). Paris: OECD.

  • OECD. (1999). The employment outlook (Chap. 2). Paris: OECD.

  • OECD. (2000). The employment outlook (Chap. 5). Paris: OECD.

  • OECD. (2004). The employment outlook (Chap. 2). Paris: OECD.

  • OECD. (2009). The economic outlook 85 database. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (1996). A time-series model of self-employment under uncertainty. Economica, 63, 459–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (1997). The effects of risk on self-employment. Small Business Economics, 9(6), 515–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2002). Do banks ration credit to new enterprises? And should governments intervene? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 49, 162–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2003a). Asymmetric information, occupational choice and government policy. Economic Journal, 113, 861–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2003b). Does tax evasion affect occupational choice? Oxford Economic Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65, 379–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2007). Law and the economics of entrepreneurship. Comparative Labor Law and Policy Journal, 28(4), 695–716.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2010). Contracting out, public policy and entrepreneurship. Scottish Journal of Political Economy (forthcoming).

  • Parker, S. C., & Robson, M. T. (2004). Explaining international variations in self-employment: Evidence from a panel of OECD countries. Southern Economic Journal, 71, 287–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedersini, R. (2002). Economically dependent workers, employment law and industrial relations. European industrial relations observatory (EIRO) comparative study. Dublin: European Foundation for the Improvement of Working and Living Conditions. http://www.eurofound.europa.eu/eiro/2002/05/study/tn0205101s.htm.

  • Perry, G. (2006). Are business start-up subsidies effective for the unemployed: Evaluation of enterprise allowance. Working Paper, Auckland University of Technology.

  • Perulli, A. (2003). Economically dependent/quasi-subordinate (parasubordinate) employment. Legal, social and economic aspects. Report for DG Employment and Social Affairs. European Commission, Brussels.

  • Pfeiffer, F., & Reize, F. (2000). Business start-ups by the unemployed—an econometric analysis based on firm data. Labour Economics, 7, 629–663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson, M. T. (2003). Does stricter employment protection legislation promote self-employment? Small Business Economics, 21, 309–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson, M. T. (2007). Explaining cross-national variations in entrepreneurship: The role of social protection and political culture. Comparative Labor Law and Policy Journal, 28, 863–892.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robson, M. T., & Wren, C. (1999). Marginal average tax rates and the incentive for self-employment. Southern Economic Journal, 65, 757–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scarpetta, S., Hemmings, P., Tressel, T., Woo, J. (2002). The role of policy and institutions for productivity and firm dynamics: Evidence from micro and industry data. OECD Economics Department Working Paper, 329, OECD Publishing.

  • Schoukens, P. (1999). Comparison of the social security law for the self-employed persons in the member-states of the European Union. In D. Pieters (Ed.), EISS yearbook 1999—Work patterns and social protection. Amsterdam: Kluwer Law International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schuetze, H. J. (2000). Taxes, economic conditions and recent trends in male self-employment: A Canada-US comparison. Labour Economics, 7, 507–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schuetze, H. J. (2008). Tax incentives and entrepreneurship: Measurement and data considerations. In E. Congregado (Ed.), Measuring entrepreneurship (pp. 205–225). New York: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sciarra, S. (2005). The evolution of labour law (1992–2003). General report, based on a comparative analysis in 15 Member States of the EU. Luxembourg: OOPEC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinn, H. W. (1996). Social insurance, incentives and risk taking. International Tax and Public Finance, 3(3), 259–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staber, U., & Bogenhold, D. (1993). Self-employment: A study of seventeen OECD countries. Industrial Relations Journal, 24, 126–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Supiot, A. (2001). Beyond employment. Changes in work and the future of labour law in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Torrini, R. (2005). Cross-country differences in self-employment rates: The role of institutions. Labour Economics, 12, 661–683.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Stel, A. (2005). COMPENDIA: Harmonizing business ownership data across countries and over time. International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 1, 105–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Stel, A., Storey, D., & Thurik, A. R. (2007). The effect of business regulations on nascent and young business entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 28(2–3), 171–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • VandenHeuvel, A., & Wooden, M. (1995). Self-employed contractors in Australia: How many and who are they? Journal of Industrial Relations, 37(2), 263–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waite, M., & Will, L. (2001). Self-employed contractors in Australia: Incidence and characteristics. Productivity Commission Staff Research Paper, AusInfo, Canberra.

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would particularly like to thank the editor, Simon Parker, two anonymous referees and María Rochina for their helpful comments and suggestions. They also thank Jolanda Hessels, Juan Máñez, Juan Sanchis, Roy Thurik, Mirjam van Praag, André van Stel, Ingrid Verheul, Sander Wennekers and participants at an EIM Business and Policy Research Seminar (Zoetermeer, 2008), the ERIM Research Workshop on Institutions and Entrepreneurship (Rotterdam, 2008), the XI World Economy Meeting (Huelva, 2009) and the XII Applied Economics Meeting (Madrid, 2009). This research is part of the project PRY115/09, which has been funded by the Fundación Centro de Estudios Andaluces (5th announcement for research projects grants). The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Concepción Román.

Appendices

Appendix A: Data description

See Tables 5, 6, 7.

Table 5 Description of variables
Table 6 Distribution of observations across countries
Table 7 Descriptive statistics of the transitions from paid employment to self-employment

Appendix B: Description of individual potential severance payment

This variable is a person- and time-variant measure of the potential severance payment that the worker would receive in case of dismissal. In particular, following the OECD (1999), the variable is defined as severance pay for individual dismissal of a regular employee with tenure beyond any trial period, dismissed on personal grounds or economic redundancy, but without fault. Information is mainly based on legal regulations, but also, where relevant, on averages found in collective agreements or individual employment contracts. For its construction, information on employment duration, salary, type of contract and age (if necessary) is taken into account. The information considered in calculations is summarised by country in Table 8.

Table 8 Construction of the individual severance payment by country

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Román, C., Congregado, E. & Millán, J.M. Dependent self-employment as a way to evade employment protection legislation. Small Bus Econ 37, 363–392 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-009-9241-3

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-009-9241-3

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation