Skip to main content
Log in

Financial development and the growth of cooperative firms

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

An Erratum to this article was published on 30 July 2008

Abstract

The purpose of this article is to empirically assess the relationship existing between local financial development and the growth of firms, with a special focus on cooperatives. Using Italian data, a multiplicative interaction model is specified, so as to allow the impact of local banking development to differ between cooperative and non-cooperative firms. The main finding is that although local banking development represents a determinant of firms’ growth, regardless of their legal structure, it plays a special role in boosting the growth of cooperatives. This result provides evidence in favor to the existence of an institutional complementarity relationship between the development of local banking institutions and cooperative firms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It is worth mentioning that in this literature a large number of contributions have focused on cross-country analysis (see Levine (1997) for a survey of the main studies), while fewer works have investigated within-country differences.

  2. The horizon problem concerns the impossibility for partners to recoup the self-financed capital invested in the company when their expected tenure in the company is shorter than the time it takes for the stream of discounted net returns from the project to equal the initial cost of the investment.

  3. According to Pejovich (1992), two critical variables determining the availability of bank loans are cooperators’ time horizon and the length of bank credit. Members of a cooperative firm would prefer to obtain bank loans when the length of the loan is longer than their time horizon with the firm. By contrast, banks would prefer to extend loans in the opposite case, that is when the length of the loan is shorter than the time horizon of members. Consequently, cooperatives might not be able to obtain bank credit due to the mismatch between members’ time horizon and the length of the bank loan.

  4. An applicable formal model of credit market failures has been proposed by Banerjee and Newman (1993).

  5. A number of studies have, in fact, stressed that the empirical base underlying the traditional theory of the cooperative firm is very thin (see, among others, Stephen 1984; Estrin and Jones 1992; Ménard 2004).

  6. However, Zamagni (2005) argues that the evidence alone does not suffice to invalidate an analytically proved theory. Therefore, future research on cooperation should devote a great deal of effort to promote the making of what he calls an “economic-civil theory of cooperation.”

  7. For a discussion of the European reforms introduced in the 1990s—as the 1991 Belgian Law, the 1992 Italian and French Laws, the 1992 Catalonian Law, and the 1993 Basques Law—see the volume edited by Monzon et al. (1996).

  8. Notice that in this example the system of the rule of law is a governance mechanism, while its justice is an attribute, a characteristic of this governance mechanism.

  9. Amable et al. (2005) argue that the type of financial relationship between the firm and the capital owner or the financial market will set a certain constraint on firm’s profitability, which will partly determine firm’s survival probability. This will in turn shape both management and union strategies, hence influencing the outcome of the bargaining between these two actors.

  10. The Italian corporate law disciplines firms’ legal structures according to the principle of juristic personality. All legal forms recognized by the Italian lawmaker are present in the Capitalia database, under the classification here presented. A first typology is that of sole trader, a business entity having no separate existence from its owner. Basically, under this legal structure a person does business in his own name and under unlimited liability. Second, have partnerships, unincorporated businesses without juristic personality, since their legal personality is not separated from that of their members. These enterprises normally operate under the unlimited liability of partners, although other forms (i.e., societa’ in accomandita semplice) have evolved in which only certain members have unlimited liability, while the others have limited liability. A third legal form is that of corporations, incorporated businesses, which are legal entities effectively recognized as a (fictious) person by law. These enterprises are, in other words, juristic persons and operate under limited liability. Fourth, have cooperative firms, hinging on the principle of mutual aid, which have legal personality and can operate under both limited and unlimited liability. Finally, Capitalia classifies the typologies established lately from the classical forms, so far, presented under the label “other legal structures,” among which figure the s.r.l. unipersonale (an incorporated company having a single owner), societa’ di professionisti (professionals’ company), and societa’ europea (European company).

  11. In this analytical framework, what matters are cooperative firms as a whole, that is as an organizational form having traits that, on one hand, still render it mostly dependent upon banking institutions and, on the other hand, make the bank–firm link complex. Thus, given the purpose of the empirical investigation, possible differentiations in the financial structure of these firms are left aside. Yet, this latter aspect deserves further in depth inquiry, on both theoretical and empirical grounds, in future research.

  12. See Brambol et al. (2006) for an analysis of multiplicative interaction models.

  13. It is worth noting that it has been preferred to control for the sensitivity of sales to inflation, even though in Italy inflation rates are rather contained.

  14. Although Gibrat’s law of proportionate effects (1931) states that firm growth is independent of size, empirical research has not reached unequivocal conclusions. Indeed, while most studies rejected the model (Tschoegl 1983; Evans 1987; Dunne et al. 1989; Dunne et al. 1994; Mata 1994; Weiss 1998; Audretsch et al. 1999; Becchetti and Trovato 2002), others found evidence in favor to Gibrat’s law (Chen et al. 1985; Kumar 1985; Acs and Audretsch 1990; Wagner 1992; Dìaz-Hermelo and Vassolo 2004). In between these conclusions, Lotti et al. (2003) found that in some Italian manufacturing industries the behavior of Gibrat’s law depends on the life cycle of the firm. In particular, the law does not hold in the first year following start-up, when smaller entrants grow faster in order to achieve a size that enhances their survival likelihood. Thereafter, the law is not rejected, as smaller and larger entrants are not found to follow different growth patterns.

  15. Regarding the relationship between firm age and growth, the general pattern suggested by previous research is that young firms are more likely to grow faster (see, for instance, Glancey 1998; Almus and Nerlinger 1999; Wijewardena et al. 1999; Becchetti and Trovato 2002; Davidsson et al. 2002; Niskanen and Niskanen 2005)

  16. The impact of cash flow on firm growth varies with the availability of external sources of financing, as the latter relax the link between growth and internal finance (Carpenter and Petersen 2002).

  17. This classification of the industrial sectors has been proposed by Pavitt (1984).

  18. The correlation matrix for the variables used in the estimations is reported in the Appendix.

  19. An exception to this is represented by the variable COOP and by territorial and industrial dummies.

  20. Yet, the intention for future research is to dispose of a much greater amount of observations on cooperatives.

  21. Regarding the composition of the sub-sample of cooperatives across the surveys considered in the analysis—spanning the triennia 1995–1997, 1998–2000, and 2001–2003—61% firms are present in one wave, 31.6% are included for 6 years, hence in two surveys, and 7.4% firms appear in all three waves. As explained by Attilio Pasetto—in charge for Capitalia’s Indagine sulle imprese manifatturiere—in order to keep in each wave a significant quota of sample units belonging to the preceding surveys, and also to supplement the sample with new units, Capitalia uses the criterion of partial re-sampling of firms (rotation panel design). So that, differences in the firms appearing in the surveys are mainly due to the sampling method adopted. Moreover, as far as non-responding units are concerned, these include firms that did not adhere to initiatives subsequent to the first one, those that run out of business, those whose number of employees fell below 11, and those not belonging to the manufacturing industry anymore.

  22. Following Servèn (2003), the criterion used to operate the outliers correction is to consider as outliers all observations for which any of the variables lies beyond 10 standard deviation away from the mean. It is worth mentioning that sole traders have been excluded from the sample, as the intention is to focus on enterprises. As regards the category “other legal structures,” this has not been considered since it includes very heterogeneous business types (see footnote 10).

  23. The variable PAV2 is not excluded from MOD3, even if not statistically significant, since—as an anonymous referee pointed out—PAV1, PAV2, and PAV3 are to be intended as an integrated set of variables.

  24. Recently, also Fagiolo and Luzzi (2006) found that liquidity constrained firms are those that grow persistently more. The authors show that small and quite dynamic firms are capable to perform well, despite being cash-constrained.

  25. It is important to clarify that it would be erroneous to argue that the more banks are developed, the more firms tend to structure themselves as cooperatives, since this would imply to regard the degree of development of financial intermediaries as driving individuals’ organizational choice. And, indeed, the institutional complementarity approach does not conflict with this, since one of its major implications is that the presence of institutional complementarity does not necessarily lead to the selection of a Pareto improving institutional arrangement. In fact, being a dynamic approach admitting multiple equilibria, institutional complementarity—as mentioned in Sect. 3—does not rule out that the prevailing institutional arrangements may be Pareto sub-optimal, as well as Pareto non-rankable. This is so because, due to their bounded rationality in perception and choice, agents cannot strategically coordinate their choices across domains, even if they participate in them simultaneously (Aoki 2001).

  26. The outliers correction for INV has been operated after having estimated the models 1–3. Results are unchanged when these models have been re-estimated after this correction.

  27. It has been argued that employment is a more informative indicator of organizational complexity than sales, and may be preferable if the focus is on the managerial implications of growth (Greiner 1972; Churchill and Lewis 1983). Moreover, some scholars have claimed that for resource- and knowledge-based views of the firm, which consider firms as bundle of resources, growth analysis should focus on the accumulation of resources, such as employees (Penrose 1959; Kogut and Zander 1992).

  28. These figures regard the models from 3 to 7.

References

  • Acs, Z., & Audretsch, D. B. (1990). Small firms and entrepreneurship: A comparison between West and East countries. Discussion Paper, MIT Press.

  • Alchian, A. A., & Woodward, S. (1988). Review: The firm is dead; long live the firm a review of Oliver E. Williamson’s the economic institutions of capitalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 26(1), 65–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Almus, M., & Nerlinger, E. A. (1999). Growth of new technology-based firms: Which factors matter? Small Business Economics: An Entrepreneurship Journal, 13(2), 141–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amable, B. (2000). Institutional complementarity and diversity of social systems of innovation and production. Review of International Political Economy, 7, 645–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amable, B., Ernst, E., & Palombarini, S. (2005). How do financial markets affect industrial relations: An institutional complementarity approach. Socio-Economic Review, 3(2), 311–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, M. (2001). Toward a comparative institutional analysis. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ardishvili, A., Cardozo, S., Harmon, S., & Vadakath, S. (1998). Towards a theory of new venture growth. Paper presented at the 1998 Babson Entrepreneurship Research Conference, Ghent, Belgium.

  • Audretsch, D. B., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (1999). Start-up size and industrial dynamics: Some evidence from Italian manufacturing. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 17, 965–983.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartlett, W., Cable, G., Estrin, S., Jones, D. C., & Smith, S. C. (1992). Labour-managed cooperatives and private firms in North Central Italy: An empirical comparison. Industrial and Labour Relations Review, 46(1), 103–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A. V., & Newman, A. F. (1993). Occupational choice and the process of development. Journal of Political Economy, 101(2), 274–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basili, M., Duranti, C., & Franzini, M. (2004). Network, trust and institutional complementarities. Rivista di Politica Economica, 1(2), 159–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bayo-Moriones, J. A., Galilea-Salvatierra, P. J., & Merino-Dìaz de Cerio, J. (2002). Participation, cooperatives and performance: An analysis of Spanish manufacturing firms. In T. Kato & J. Pliskin (Eds.), The determinants of the incidence and the effects of participatory organisations (pp. 31–56). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becchetti, L., & Trovato, G. (2002). The determinants of growth for small and medium sized firms. The role of the availability of external finance. Small Business Economics: An Entrepreneurship Journal, 19(4), 291–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Maksimovic, V. (2003). Financial and legal institutions and firm size. Working Paper n. 2997, World Bank Policy Research.

  • Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Maksimovic, V. (2005). Financial and legal constraint to growth. Does size matter? Journal of Finance, 1(2), 137–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert, G., Harvey, C. H., & Lundblad, C. (2005). Does financial liberalization spur growth? Journal of Financial Economics, 77, 3–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bencivenga, V., & Smith, B. (1991). Financial intermediation and endogenous growth. Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 195–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benfratello, L., Schiantarelli, F., & Sembenelli, A. (2006). Banks and innovation: Microeconometric evidence on Italian firms. Working Paper 631, Boston College.

  • Ben-Ner, A. (1988). The life cycle of worker-owned firms in market economies: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 10, 287–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blair, M., Kruse, D. L., & Blasi, J. R. (2000). Employee ownership: An unstable form or a stabilizing force? In M. Blair & T. Hockan (Eds.), The new relationship: Human capital in the American corporation (pp. 241–298). Washington: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bofondi, M., & Gobbi, G. (2003). Bad loans and entry in local credit markets. Banca d’Italia, Tema di discussione n. 509.

  • Bonaccorsi di Patti, E., & Dell’Ariccia, G. (2004). Bank competition and firm creation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 36(2), 225–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonaccorsi di Patti, E., & Gobbi, G. (2001a). The changing structure of local credit markets: Are small businesses special? Journal of Banking and Finance, 25, 2209–2237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonaccorsi di Patti, E., & Gobbi, G. (2001b). The effects of bank consolidation and market entry on small business lending. Banca d’Italia, Tema di discussione n. 404.

  • Bonin, J., Jones, D. C., & Putterman, L. (1993). Theoretical and empirical studies of producer cooperatives: Will ever the twain meet? Journal of Economic Literature, 31, 1290–1320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyer, R. (2005). Coherence, diversity, and the evolution of capitalism: The institutional complementary hypothesis. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 2(1), 43–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brambol, T., Clark, W. R., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analysis. Political Analysis, 14, 63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, R. E., & Petersen, C. (2002). The growth of small firms constrained by internal finance. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 298–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cesarini, F. (2003). Il rapporto banca-impresa. Paper presented at the workshop “Impresa, risparmio e intermediazione finanziaria: Aspetti economici e profili giuridici,” Trieste.

  • Chen, K., Babb, E. M., & Schrader, L. F. (1985). Growth of large cooperative and proprietary firms in the US food sector. Agribusiness, 1, 201–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Churchill, C., & Lewis, V. L. (1983). The five stages of small business growth. Harvard Business Review, 61(3), 30–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, M. L. (1995). The future of U.S. agricultural cooperatives: A neo-institutional approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 77, 1153–1159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidsson, P., & Wiklund, J. (2000). Conceptual and empirical challenges in the study of firm growth. In D. Sexton & H. Landstrom (Eds.), The Blackwell handbook of entrepreneurship (pp. 26–44). Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidsson, P., Kirchhoff, B., Hatemi, J. A., & Gustavsson, H. (2002). Empirical analysis of business growth factors using Swedish data. Journal of Small Business Management, 40(4), 332–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dehejia, R., & Lleras-Muney, A. (2003). Why does financial development matter? The United States from 1900 to 1940. NBER Working Paper n. 955.

  • Delmar, F. (1997). Measuring growth: Methodological considerations and empirical results. In R. Donckels & A. Miettinen (Eds.), Entrepreneurship and SME research: On its way to the next millennium (pp. 199–216). Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delmar, F., Daviddson, P., & Gartner, W. B. (2003). Arriving at the high-growth firms. Journal of Business Venturing, 18, 189–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Maksimovic, V. (1998). Law, finance, and firm growth. The Journal of Finance, 53(6), 2107–2137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Gregorio, J., & Guidotti, P. (1995). Financial development and economic growth. World Development, 23, 433–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dìaz-Hermelo, F., & Vassolo, R. (2004). The determinants of firm’s growth: An empirical examination. Working Paper, Universidad Austral.

  • Dixit, A. K. (2007). Economic governance. In: S. Durlauf & L.E. Blume (Eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, forthcoming, Palgrave Macmillan.

  • Dow, G. (2003). Governing the firm. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drèze, J. (1993). Self-management and economic theory. In P. Bardhan & J. Roemer (Eds.), Market socialism: The current debate (pp. 253–265). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, P., & Hughes, A. (1994). Age, size, growth and survival: UK companies in the 1980s. Journal of Industrial Economics, 42(2), 115–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, T., Roberts, M. J., & Samuelson, L. (1989). The growth and failure of US manufacturing plants. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(4), 671–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ernst, C. E. (2003). Financial systems, industrial relations, and industry specialization. An econometric analysis on institutional complementarities. In Proceedings of the OeNB Workshop “The Transformation of the European Financial System. Where Do We Go? Where Should We Go?,” Vienna.

  • Estrin, S., & Jones, D. C. (1988). The determinants of investments in labor managed firms: Evidence from France. Discussion paper n.87, Centre for economic performance, London School of Economics.

  • Estrin, S., & Jones, D. C. (1992). The viability of employee-owned firms. Evidence from France. Industrial and Labor relations Review, 45(2), 323–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. S. (1987). Tests of alternative theories of firm growth. Journal of Political Economy, 95(4), 657–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo, G., & Luzzi, A. (2006). Do liquidity constraints matter in explaining firm size and growth? Some evidence from the Italian manufacturing industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, 15(1), 1–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, D., & Galetovic, A. (1994). Schumpeter might be right—but why? Explaining the relation between finance, development and growth. Working Paper, School of Advanced International Studies, John Hopkins University.

  • Flamholtz, E. G. (1986). Managing the transition from an entrepreneurship to a professionally managed firm. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furubotn, E. G., & Pejovich, S. (1970). Property rights and the behavior of the firm in a socialist state: The example of Yugoslavia. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, 30(5), 431–454.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibrat, R. (1931). Les Inegalites Economiques. Paris: Librairie Du Recueil Sirey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glancey, K. (1998). Determinants of growth and profitability in small entrepreneurial firms. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behaviour and Research, 1(4), 18–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldsmith, R. (1969). Financial structure and development. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, L. E. (1972). Evolutions and revolutions as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, 50(4), 37–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J., & Jovanovic, B. (1990). Financial development, growth, and the distribution of income. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1076–1107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2004). Does local financial development matter? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 929–969.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P. A., & Gingerich, D. W. (2004). Varieties of capitalism and institutional complementarities in the macroeconomy. An empirical analysis. Discussion Paper n. 04/5, Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies.

  • Hoy, F., McDougall, P. P., & Dsouza, D. E. (1992). Strategies and environments of high growth firms. In D. L. Sexton & J. D. Kasarda (Eds.), The state of the art of entrepreneurship (pp. 341–357). Boston: PWS-Kent Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jayaratne, J., & Strahan, P. E. (1996). The finance-growth nexus: Evidence from bank branch deregulation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111, 639–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. R. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jossa, B., & Cuomo, G. (1997). The economic theory of socialism and the labour-managed firm. Market, socialism and labour management. Edward Elgar Publishers: Cheltenham-Brookfield.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, R., & Levine, R. (1993). Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 717–738.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B., & Zander, U. (1992). Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology. Organization Science, 3(3), 383–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, M. S. (1985). Growth, acquisition activity and firm size: Evidence from the United Kingdom. Journal of Industrial Economics, 33(3), 327–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwast, M., Starr-McCluer, M., & Wolken, J. (1997). Market definition and the analysis of antitrust in banking. The Antitrust Bulletin, 42, 973–995.

    Google Scholar 

  • La Loggia Albanese, E. (2003). Titoli di partecipazione nelle societa’ cooperative. Rivista di diritto dell’economia, dei trasporti e dell’ambiente, 1, 111–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, H. M. (1984). ESOPs and the financing of worker cooperatives. In R. Jackall & H. M. Levin (Eds.), Worker cooperatives in America (pp. 220–245). Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R. (1992). Financial structure and economic development. Working Paper n. 849, the World Bank.

  • Levine, R. (1997). Financial development and economic growth: Views and agenda. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 688–726.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R., & Zervos, S. (1998). Stock markets, banks, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 88, 537–558.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lotti, F., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2003). Does Gibrat’s law hold among young, small firms? Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 13, 213–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mata, J. (1994). Firm growth during infancy. Small Business Economics: An Entrepreneurship Journal, 6(1), 27–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathews, R. (2002). Mondragòn: Past performance and future potential. Paper presented at the Capital Ownership Group Conference, the Kent State University, Washington.

  • Ménard, C. (2004). The economics of hybrid organizations. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 160, 345–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monzon, J. L., Spear-Thomas, A., & Zevi, A. (Eds.) (1996). Cooperatives, Markets and Cooperative Principles. Liège: International Ciriec Association Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers, S. C., & Majluf, N. S. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics, 13(2), 187–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKinnon, R. (1973). Money and capital in economic development. Washington: Brooking Institutions.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicita, A., & Pagano, U. (2004). Institutional complementarities, corporate governance and financial-technological equilibria. Siena memos and papers on law and economics n.28, Università di Siena.

  • Niskanen, M., & Niskanen, J. (2005). The determinants of firm growth in small and micro firms—evidence on relationship lending effects. Working Paper, University of Kuopio.

  • Onida, F. (2004). Se il piccolo non cresce. Piccole e medie imprese italiane in affanno. Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pavitt, K. (1984). Patterns of technical change: Towards a taxonomy and a theory. Research Policy, 13, 343–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pejovich, S. (1969). The firm, monetary policy and property rights in a planned economy. Western Economic Journal, 7(3), 193–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pejovich, S. (1992). Why has the labor-managed firm failed? Cato Journal, 12(2), 461–473.

    Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, E. (1959). The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (2002). Does distance still matter? The information revolution in small business lending. Journal of Finance, 57(6), 2533–2570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L. (1982). Some behavioral perspectives on the dominance of hierarchical over democratic forms of enterprise. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3, 139–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L. (1993). Ownership and the nature of the firm. Journal of Comparative Economics, 17(2), 243–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (1998). Financial dependence and growth. American Economic Review, 88, 559–586.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saint-Paul, G. (1992). Technological choice, financial markets and economic development. European Economic Review, 36(4), 763–781.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salani, M. P. (2005). Le basi istituzionali della forma cooperativa. In E. Mazzoli & S. Zamagni (Eds.), Verso una nuova teoria economica della cooperazione (pp. 141–223). Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlicht, E., von Weizsäcker, C. C. (1977). Risk financing in labour-managed economies: The commitment problem. Zeitschrift für die gesamte staatswissenschaft, 133, 53–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Servèn, L. (2003). Real exchange rate uncertainty and private investment in LDCs. Review of Economic and Statistics, 88(1), 212–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, E. (1973). Financial deepening in economic development. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, S. C. (2001). Blooming together or wilting alone? Network externalities and Mondragòn and La Lega co-operative networks. Discussion Paper n. 2001/27, World Institute for Development Economics Research, United Nations University.

  • Staber, U. (1989). Age dependence and historical effects on the failure rates of worker cooperatives: An event history analysis. Economic and Industrial Democracy, 10(1), 59–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephen, F. H. (1984). The economic analysis of producers’ cooperatives. London: McMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2004). The role of cooperatives in globalization. Working Paper n. 9, University of Genova.

  • Stiglitz, J. E., & Weiss, A. (1981). Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. American Economic Review, 71(3), 393–410.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutton, J. (1997). Gibrat’s legacy. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 40–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tschoegl, A. E. (1983). Size, growth, and transnationality among the world’s largest banks. Journal of business, 56(2), 187–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vanek, J. (1970). The general theory of labor managed market economies. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanek, J. (1977). The labor-managed economy. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vitaliano, P. (1983). Cooperative enterprise: An alternative conceptual basis for analyzing a complex institution. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 65(5), 1078–1083.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, J. (1992). Firm size, firm growth, and persistence of chance: Testing Gibrat’s law with establishment data from Lower Saxony, 1978–1989. Small Business Economics: An Entrepreneurship Journal, 42(2), 125–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss, C. R. (1998). Size, growth, and survival in the upper Austrian farm sector. Small Business Economics: An Entrepreneurship Journal, 10(4), 305–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wijewardena, H., & Tibbits, G. E. (1999). Factors contributing to the growth of small manufacturing firms: Data from Australia. Journal of Small Business Management, 37(20), 38–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1988). Corporate finance and corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 43(3), 576–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zamagni, S. (2005). Per una teoria economico-civile dell’impresa cooperativa. In E. Mazzoli & S. Zamagni (Eds.), Verso una nuova teoria economica della cooperazione (pp. 15–56). Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zevi, A. (2005). Il finanziamento delle cooperative. In E. Mazzoli & S. Zamagni (Eds.), Verso una nuova teoria economica della cooperazione (pp. 293–331). Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

In writing this version I benefited from the comments of Geoffrey M. Hodgson, Avinash K. Dixit, Douglass C. North, Giovanni Dosi, Jesse M. Fried, Francesco Trivieri, the participants to the European School on New Institutional Economics held in Cargese on 21–25 May 2007, and two anonymous referees. I thank Attilio Pasetto from Capitalia for his kind elucidations. I am also grateful to Mariarosaria Agostino, Elena Granaglia, Rosanna Nisticò and the participants to the Centre for Research in Institutional Economics Workshop held at the University of Hertfordshire on 23–24 January 2007, for their valuable comments and suggestions on earlier versions of this article. Of course, all remaining errors and omissions are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francesca Gagliardi.

Additional information

An erratum to this article can be found at http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11187-008-9128-8

 

 

Appendix Correlation matrix

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gagliardi, F. Financial development and the growth of cooperative firms. Small Bus Econ 32, 439–464 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9080-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9080-z

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation