Advertisement

Journal of Risk and Uncertainty

, Volume 51, Issue 1, pp 79–101 | Cite as

Preferences for life-expectancy gains: Sooner or later?

  • James K. Hammitt
  • Tuba Tunçel
Article

Abstract

We assess individuals’ preferences for time paths of reductions in mortality risk yielding a life-expectancy gain of about 1 month. In a survey of more than 1000 French residents, we find substantial coherence and heterogeneity. We elicit pairwise preferences between three perturbations of age- and gender-specific survival curves: transient (reduce hazard for next 10 years), additive (reduce hazard in all future years by subtracting a constant), and proportional (reduce hazard in all future years by a common fraction). The preference order implied by these pairwise responses is transitive for 85% of respondents. The most common preference orders, accounting for more than half the respondents, are strict indifference, proportional ≻ additive ≻ transient, and the inverse of that ranking. These are consistent with globally risk-neutral, risk-seeking, and risk-averse preferences toward longevity, respectively. Choices between one of these scenarios and a latent version that provides no risk reduction for the first 10 or 20 years are consistent with these risk postures. The mean and median consumption-discount rates are 12 and 5% per year, respectively, and the average coefficient of relative risk aversion with respect to financial gambles is about 0.5. Preferences toward the time path of mortality-risk reduction are not strongly associated with individual characteristics, although respondents who are older or exhibit higher consumption-discount rates tend to exhibit less longevity-risk aversion.

Keywords

Survival Mortality risk Risk aversion Value of statistical life 

JEL Classifications

D6 J17 

Notes

Acknowledgments

We thank Mike Jones-Lee, Sue Chilton, Jytte Nielsen, Kip Viscusi, Rebecca McDonald, Henrik Andersson and other participants at the April 2014 “Event in Honour of Emeritus Professor Michael W. Jones-Lee” and an anonymous referee for helpful comments. For help with survey design, we thank Pierre Dubois, Christoph Rheinberger, Astrid Hopfensitz, Yann Kervinio, Ananya Sen, and 11 TSE doctoral students who served as pretest respondents. Hammitt acknowledges financial support from INRA (the French National Institute for Agricultural Research, which also supported data collection), the European Research Council under the European Community’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007–2013) Grant Agreement no. 230589, and the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation. Tunçel acknowledges financial support from ECOCEP (Economic Modeling for Climate-Energy Policy).

References

  1. Aldy, J. E., & Viscusi, W. K. (2007). Age differences in the value of statistical life: revealed preference evidence. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1, 241–260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Aldy, J. E., & Viscusi, W. K. (2008). Adjusting the value of a statistical life for age and cohort effects. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90, 573–581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2008). Eliciting risk and time preferences. Econometrica, 76, 583–618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Blais, A. R., & Weber, E. U. (2006). A Domain-Specific Risk-Taking (DOSPERT) scale for adult populations. Judgment and Decision Making, 1(1), 33–47.Google Scholar
  5. Carthy, T., Chilton, S., Covey, J., Hopkins, L., Jones-Lee, M., Loomes, G., Pidgeon, N., & Spencer, A. (1999). On the contingent valuation of safety and the safety of contingent valuation: part 2—the CV/SG ‘chained’ approach. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 17, 187–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Chilton, S., Jones-Lee, M., Kiraly, F., Metcalf, H., & Pang, W. (2006). Dread risks. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 33, 165–182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Coller, M., & Williams, M. B. (1999). Eliciting individual discount rates. Experimental Economics, 2, 107–127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Corso, P. S., & Hammitt, J. K. (2001). Preferences for longevity risks: effects of lottery and personal characteristics. Harvard Center for Risk Analysis, working paper.Google Scholar
  9. Delprat, G., Leroux, M.-L., & Michaud, P.-C. (2015). Evidence on individual preferences for longevity risk. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance. doi: 10.1017/S1474747214000523.Google Scholar
  10. Drèze, J. (1962). L’utilitè sociale d’une vie humaine. Revue Française de Recherche Opérationelle, 6, 93–118.Google Scholar
  11. Eeckhoudt, L., & Hammitt, J. K. (2004). Does risk aversion increase the value of mortality risk? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 47, 13–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Frederick, S., Loweinstein, G., & O’Donohue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: a critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351–401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Hammitt, J. K. (2000). Valuing mortality risk: theory and practice. Environmental Science and Technology, 34, 1396–1400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Hammitt, J. K. (2002). QALYs versus WTP. Risk Analysis, 22, 985–1001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Hammitt, J. K. (2007). Valuing changes in mortality risk: lives saved vs. life years saved. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1, 228–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Hammitt, J. K. (2013). Admissible utility functions for health, longevity, and wealth: integrating monetary and life-year measures. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 47, 311–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Hammitt, J. K., & Liu, J.-T. (2004). Effects of disease type and latency on the value of mortality risk. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 28, 73–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Hanemann, W. M. (1991). Willingness to pay and willingness to accept: how much can they differ? American Economic Review, 81, 635–647.Google Scholar
  19. Hanmer, J., Lawrence, W. F., Anderson, J. P., Kaplan, R. M., & Fryback, D. G. (2006). Report of nationally representative values for the noninstitutionalized US adult population for 7 health-related quality-of-life scores. Medical Decision Making, 26, 391–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92, 1644–1655.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Johannesson, M., Johansson, P.-O., & Lofgren, K.-G. (1997). On the value of changes in life expectancy: blips versus parametric changes. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 15, 221–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Jones-Lee, M. W. (1974). The value of changes in the probability of death or injury. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 835–849.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Krupnick, A. (2007). Mortality-risk valuation and age: stated-preference evidence. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1, 261–282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Magat, W. A., Viscusi, W. K., & Huber, J. (1996). A reference lottery metric for valuing health. Management Science, 42, 1118–1130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. McNeil, B. J., Weichselbaum, R., & Pauker, S. J. (1978). Fallacy of the 5-year survival in lung cancer. New England Journal of Medicine, 299, 1387–1401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Menezes, C., Geiss, C., & Tressler, J. (1980). Increasing downside risk. American Economic Review, 70, 921–932.Google Scholar
  27. Nielsen, J. S., Chilton, S., Jones-Lee, M., & Metcalf, H. (2010). How would you like your gain in life expectancy to be provided? an experimental approach. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 41, 195–218.Google Scholar
  28. Pliskin, J. S., Shepard, D. S., & Weinstein, M. C. (1980). Utility functions for life years and health status. Operations Research, 28, 206–224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Rosen, S. (1988). The value of changes in life expectancy. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1, 285–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Rothschild, M., & Stiglitz, J. (1970). Increasing risk: I. A definition. Journal of Economic Theory, 2, 225–243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Shepard, D. S., & Zeckhauser, R. J. (1984). Survival versus consumption. Management Science, 30, 423–439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Van Houtven, G., Sullivan, M. B., & Dockins, C. (2006). Cancer premiums and latency effects: a risk tradeoff approach for valuing reductions in fatal cancer risks. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 36, 179–199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Viscusi, W. K. (2010). The heterogeneity of the value of statistical life: introduction and overview. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 40, 1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Viscusi, W. K., Magat, W. A., & Huber, J. (1991). Pricing environmental health risks: survey assessment of risk-risk and risk-dollar tradeoffs for chronic bronchitis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 21, 32–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Wright, J. C., & Weinstein, M. C. (1998). Gains in life expectancy from medical interventions—standardizing data on outcomes. New England Journal of Medicine, 399, 380–286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Center for Risk AnalysisHarvard UniversityBostonUSA
  2. 2.Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA-INRA)ToulouseFrance
  3. 3.Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA)ToulouseFrance
  4. 4.Aix-Marseille School of EconomicsAix-Marseille University, CNRS & EHESSMarseilleFrance

Personalised recommendations