Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Intangible Investment and Firm Performance

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We combine survey and administrative data for about 13,000 New Zealand firms from 2005 to 2013 to study intangible investment and firm performance. We find that firm size and moderate competition is associated with higher intangible investment, while firm age is associated with lower intangible investment. Examining firm performance, we find that higher investment is associated with higher labour and capital input, higher revenue, and higher firm-reported employee and customer satisfaction, but not with higher productivity or profitability. The evidence suggests that intangible investment is associated with growth and ‘soft’ performance objectives, but not with productivity or profitability.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. By analogy, the building fires to which the most fire engines are sent are also the ones in which the largest amount of property damage occurs. It is likely that, holding constant the initial intensity of the fire, sending more engines reduces the amount of damage. But that relationship is obscured by the ‘reverse causality’ running from fire damage to number of engines.

  2. The batch of questions also asks about acquiring of machinery and equipment; acquiring of other knowledge (e.g., licenses, patents, or other intellectual property); and marketing the introduction of new goods or services. We exclude the first as it is a measure of tangible investment, and exclude the latter two as firms may see them as innovation-output indicators, rather than measures of intangible investment.

  3. In 2005 the question only asks whether the activities were done to support innovation, meaning there is a systematic difference in our intangible measures between 2005 and the other years. Including year fixed effects in our later regression analysis helps to deal with this issue.

  4. This question comes from the main ‘business operations’ module, and so asks whether R&D occurred in the previous year rather than in the previous 2 years. The question does not ask whether it is done to support innovation, though presumably fostering innovation is an inherent goal of R&D.

  5. We assume the information in these answers is too messy and better dropped. This sets 12% of index values to be missing, though the majority (72%) of these changes come from the 2005 BOS, where non-innovating firms were steered away from the question on intangible investments.

  6. In practice we only use the primary principal component, but present details on the second component for completion. In addition we use tetrachoric correlations between the underlying indicators, which estimate the correlation between two indicator variables, assuming that some normally-distributed latent variable underlies them.

  7. This question was not asked in 2005; our expenditure measures are missing for this year.

  8. The question is slightly rephrased for clarity, but the substance and key words are unchanged.

  9. We also use the alternate firm identifiers developed in Fabling (2011) to fix broken firm identifiers.

  10. The large ratio values of three and above in panel B are driven by firms with very low average index values, which blow up the proportion when used as the denominator.

  11. Appendix Table 5 presents summary statistics of variables appearing in any of the regression tables in this paper.

  12. Average marginal effects are very similar when estimating fractional logit models in columns (1)–(2) and logit models in columns (4)–(6). We show OLS results because of the ease of interpretation and because the estimator is tractable enough to include industry-year interactions.

  13. Equation (2) with MFP as the dependent variable is closely related to a model where the stock of intangible assets is added as a factor of production in the production function (Griliches, 1979). We adopt the approach of first constructing MFP as a residual from the production function, and then regressing this residual on the intangible assets because we have a much larger sample of firms with production data than those for which we have the intangibles data. Thus the other parameters of the production function (e.g. capital and labour elasticities) can be estimated very precisely on this large sample, whereas if we estimated the production function only on the smaller intangibles-data sample the production function would be much less well estimated.

  14. We also ran output-weighted regressions to estimate the association for the average unit of output, rather than the average firm. The results do not change qualitatively.

  15. We also ran regressions where the dependent variable is an indicator for a larger than one and a larger than 15 percentage point increase in MFP. Results are similar, with positive but economically small estimates. Average marginal effects from the logit estimator are also similar.

  16. Note that the very youngest firms (< 2years) cannot be included in this regression because we are looking at productivity as a function of intangible investment 2 years previous.

  17. OLS estimates in columns (5) and (6) are similar to the average marginal effects from logit estimates. We exclude firms with negative or zero profitability in these regressions, both in Table 6 and Table 7, because we use the log transformation in columns (1) and (3). We similarly exclude firms with negative or zero profit in Appendix Table 7, and firms with negative or zero labour productivity in Table 6 and 7 when modelling labour productivity.

  18. In conditional quantile regressions we cluster standard errors at the firm level using the package that was created by Machado et al. (2015).

  19. We drop industry-specific year effects for empirical tractability, but leave in both year and industry fixed effects.

  20. In addition to the models that we report herein, we also explored whether any individual forms of intangible investment or categories of such investment as used by Corrado et al. (2012) have positive associations with productivity. We found none.

References

  • Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., & Howitt, P. (2002). Competition and innovation: An inverted U relationship (Working Paper No. 9269). National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Andrews, D., Criscuolo, C., & Menon, C. (2014). Do resources flow to patenting firms? (OECD Economics Department Working Papers). Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

  • Andrews, D., & de Serres, A. (2012). Intangible assets, resource allocation and growth (OECD Economics Department Working Papers). Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

  • Balasubramanian, N., & Sivadasan, J. (2010). What Happens When Firms Patent? New Evidence from U.S. Economic Census Data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(1), 126–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bontempi, M. E., & Mairesse, J. (2015). Intangible capital and productivity at the firm level: a panel data assessment. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 24(1–2), 22–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corrado, C., Hulten, C., & Sichel, D. (2005). Measuring capital and technology: An expanded framework. In Measuring capital in the new economy (pp. 11–46). University of Chicago Press.

  • Corrado, C., Hulten, C., & Sichel, D. (2009). Intangible Capital and U.S. Economic Growth. Review of Income and Wealth, 55(3), 661–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corrado, C. A., Haskel, J., Iommi, M., & Jona Lasinio, C. (2012). Intangible capital and growth in advanced economies: Measurement and comparative results. Discussion Paper No. 6733, Institute for the Study of Labour (IZA), Bonn.

  • Crass, D., & Peters, B. (2014). Intangible assets and firm-level productivity. Centre for European Research Discussion Paper No. 14-120.

  • Crepon, B., Duguet, E., & Mairessec, J. (1998). Research, Innovation and Productivity: An Econometric Analysis At The Firm Level. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 7(2), 115–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elnasri, A., & Fox, K. J. (2017). The contribution of research and innovation to productivity. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 47(3), 291–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fabling, R. (2011). Keeping it together: Tracking firms on New Zealand’s longitudinal business database. Motu Economic and Public Policy Research Working Papers 11_01.

  • Fabling, R., & Maré, D. C. (2015a). Production function estimation using New Zealand’s longitudinal business database. Motu Economic and Public Policy Research Working Papers 15_15.

  • Fabling, R., & Maré, D. C. (2015b). Addressing the absence of hours information in linked employer-employee data. Motu Economic and Public Policy Research Working Papers 15_17.

  • Fabling, R., & Sanderson, L. (2016.). A rough guide to New Zealand’s longitudinal business database, 2nd edn. Motu Economic and Public Policy Research Working Papers 16_03.

  • Firpo, S., Fortin, N. M., & Lemieux, T. (2009). Unconditional quantile regressions. Econometrica, 77(3), 953–973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1979). Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 92–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, H. L., & Lo, M. L. (2015). The portfolio of intangible investments and their performance: Evidence from Taiwanese Manufacturing Firms. Unpublished manuscript. Retrieved from http://homepage.ntu.edu.tw/~josephw/20151112_Intangible20151106v1.pdf.

  • Maré, D. C. (2016). Urban productivity estimation with heterogeneous prices and labour. Motu Economic and Public Policy Research Working Papers 16_21.

  • Machado, J. A. F., Parente, P. M., & Silva, J. S. (2015). QREG2: Stata module to perform quantile regression with robust and clustered standard errors. Statistical Software Components.

  • Montresor, S., & Vezzani, A. (2016). Intangible investments and innovation propensity: Evidence from the Innobarometer 2013. Industry and Innovation, 1–22.

  • Pakes, A., & Griliches, Z. (1984). Patents and R&D at the firm level: A first look. In Z. Griliches (Ed.), R&D, patents, and productivity (ch. 3). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F. M. (1982). Inter-industry technology flows and productivity growth. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 64, 627–634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F. M. (1983). The propensity to patent. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 1(1), 107–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F. M. (1986). Innovation and growth: Schumpeterian perspectives. MIT Press Books, Cambridge 1.

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research is partially funded by the Productivity Hub under the Productivity Partnership programme, and by Queensland University of Technology. We would like to thank Lawrence J. White and an anonymous referee for valuable feedback. We also thank participants at an internal Motu seminar, as well as participants at a Productivity Commission of New Zealand workshop for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adam Jaffe.

Additional information

Disclaimer: The results in this paper are not official statistics, they have been created for research purposes from the Integrated Data Infrastructure (IDI) managed by Statistics New Zealand. The opinions, findings, recommendations and conclusions expressed in this paper are those of the authors, not Statistics New Zealand or Motu Economy and Public Policy Research.

Access to the anonymised data used in this study was provided by Statistics New Zealand in accordance with security and confidentiality provisions of the Statistics Act 1975. Only people authorised by the Statistics Act 1975 are allowed to see data about a particular person, household, business, or organisation; and the results in this paper have been confidentialised to protect these groups from identification. Careful consideration has been given to the privacy, security, and confidentiality issues that are associated with using administrative and survey data in the IDI. Further detail can be found in the privacy impact assessment for the IDI available from www.stats.govt.nz.

The results are based in part on tax data supplied by Inland Revenue to Statistics New Zealand under the Tax Administration Act 1994. This tax data must be used only for statistical purposes, and no individual information may be published or disclosed in any other form, or provided to Inland Revenue for administrative or regulatory purposes. Any person who has had access to the unit-record data has certified that they have been shown, have read, and have understood Sect. 81 of the Tax Administration Act 1994, which relates to secrecy. Any discussion of data limitations or weaknesses is in the context of using the IDI for statistical purposes, and is not related to the data’s ability to support Inland Revenue’s core operational requirements.

Appendix

Appendix

See Fig. 5, Tables 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17 and 18.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Mean and spread of intangibles principal component, by industry. Notes: Appendix Fig. 5 presents, as dots, the mean intangibles principal component for all firm-years by industry over the period 2005–2013. The bands show all values that fall within one standard deviation of the mean for each industry. Full industry descriptions are given in Appendix Table 13

Table 11 Correlation matrix of intangible indicators
Table 12 Principal components of intangibles indicators
Table 13 ANZSIC 2006 industry codes
Table 14 Intangibles by industry, controlling for firm size
Table 15 Sample statistics of regression variables
Table 16 Characteristics of intangibles-investing firms, robustness check
Table 17 Absolute profits and past intangible investment
Table 18 Intangible investment and customer/employee satisfaction, logit regression

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chappell, N., Jaffe, A. Intangible Investment and Firm Performance. Rev Ind Organ 52, 509–559 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-018-9629-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-018-9629-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation