Review of Economics of the Household

, Volume 16, Issue 2, pp 453–476 | Cite as

Parental child care during and outside of typical work hours

Article

Abstract

It has been argued that child care should be treated separately from leisure or housework when analyzing time use data. This is because child care has a positive income gradient, whereas leisure and housework do not. Using U.S. data from PSID-CDS, this paper computes parental child care during and outside of typical work hours (TWH) by income quintile for two-parent families. The TWH distinction is important because the opportunity cost of spending time with children is first and foremost in terms of forgone earnings during TWH; outside of TWH, leisure or housework mainly constitute this opportunity cost. Indeed, I find that child care decreases with income during TWH and, hence, behaves similarly to leisure and other household chores. While maternal child care also slightly decreases with income outside of TWH, paternal care increases with income outside of TWH. Also, the discrepancy between paternal and maternal child care is smaller outside of TWH than it is during TWH. This is particularly pronounced in high income families. Theoretical implications are derived in a static framework of time allocation and child quality production encompassing the recent literature on the topic. Variation in child care during TWH can be rationalized by assuming a high elasticity of substitution between leisure, consumption and child quality. This is the standard explanation for the patterns observed in leisure and housework. Within this widely used framework, however, the facts outside of TWH point to systematic differences by income in preferences or productivity. Further exploration of child care patterns during and outside of TWH is needed to inform us about the dimensions in which this widely used framework should be extended.

Keywords

Parental child care Opportunity cost Typical work hours Child quality 

Mathematics Subject Classification

D13 J13 

Notes

Acknowledgments

The author thanks David Frisvold, Martin Gervais, Paula Gobbi, Lev Lvovskiy and Michèle Tertilt as well as four anonymous referees for helpful comments.

Supplementary material

11150_2016_9336_MOESM1_ESM.pdf (243 kb)
Supplementary material 1 (pdf 243 KB)

References

  1. Abbott, B. (2015). The effect of parental composition on investments in children. Working paper, Yale UniversityGoogle Scholar
  2. Aguiar, M., & Hurst, E. (Forthcoming). Handbook of macroeconomics. Elsevier, chap The Marcoeconomics of Time Allocation.Google Scholar
  3. Apps, P. F., & Rees, R. (2002). Household production, full consumption and the costs of children. Labour Economics, 8(6), 621–648.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Biddle, J. E., & Hamermesh, D. S. (1990). Sleep and the allocation of time. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 922–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bittman, M., & Craig, L. (2008). The incremental time costs of children: An analysis of children’s impact on adult time use in austalia. Feminist Economics, 14(2), 59–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Bradbury, B. (2008). Time and the cost of children. Review of Income and Wealth, 54(3), 305–323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Cunha, F., & Heckman, J. (2007). The technology of skill formation. American Economic Review, 97(2), 31–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Dahl, G. B., & Lochner, L. (2012). The impact of family income on child achievement: Evidence from the earned income tax credit. American Economic Review, 102(5), 1927–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Del Boca, D., Flinn, C., & Wiswall, M. (2014). Household choices and child development. Review of Economic Studies, 81(1), 137–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Ekert-Jaffé, O., & Grossbard, S. (2015). Time costs of children as parents’ foregone leisure. Mathematical Population Studies, 22(2), 80–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Espenshade, T. J. (1984). Investing in Children: New Estimates of Parental Expenditures. Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press.Google Scholar
  12. Folbre, N. (2008). Valuing children: Rethinking the economics of the family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Folbre, N., & Yoon, J. (2007). What is child care? Lessons from time-use surveys of major English-speaking countries. Review of Economics of the Household, 5(3), 223–248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Folbre, N., Yoon, J., Finnoff, K., & Fuligni, A. S. (2005). By what measure? Family time devoted to children in the united states. Demography, 42(2), 373–390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Gauthier, A. H., Smeedeng, T. M., Furstenberg, J., & Frank, F. (2004). Are parents investing less time in children? Trends in selected industrialized countries. Population and Development Review, 30(4), 647–671.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Gobbi, P. (2013). Childcare and commitment within households. Discussion Paper 2013019, Université Catholique de Louvain, Institut de Recherches Economiques et Sociales (IRES).Google Scholar
  17. Guryan, J., Hurst, E., & Kearney, M. (2008). Parental education and parental time with children. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 22(3), 23–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Gustafsson, B., & Kjulin, U. (1994). Time use in child care and housework and the total cost of children. Journal of Population Economics, 7(3), 287–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Gutiérrez-Domènech, M. (2010). Parental employment and time with children in Spain. Review of Economics of the Household, 8(3), 371–391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Hallberg, D., & Klevmarken, A. (2003). Time for children: A study of parent’s time allocation. Journal of Population Economics, 16(2), 205–226. (contributor).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Hill, R. C., & Stafford, F. P. (1980). Parental care of children: Time diaries estimates of quantity, predictability, and variety. Journal of Human Research, 15(2), 220–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Jones, L. E., Manuelli, R. E., & McGrattan, E. R. (2015). Why are married women working so much? Journal of Demographic Economics, 81(1), 75–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Lazear, E. P., & Michael, R. T. (1980). Family size and the distribution of real per capita income. American Economic Review, 70(1), 91–107.Google Scholar
  24. Lino, M. (2001). Expenditures on children by families, 2000 annual report. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Center for Nutrition Policy and Promotion. Miscellaneous Publication No. 1528-2000.Google Scholar
  25. Ramey, G., & Ramey, V. A. (2010). The rug rat race. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (pp. 129–199).Google Scholar
  26. Sayer, L. C. S., Bianchi, S. M., & Robinson, J. P. (2004). Are parents investing less in children? Trends in mothers’ and fathers’ time with children. American Journal of Sociology, 110(1), 1–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsThe University of IowaIowa CityUSA

Personalised recommendations