Advertisement

The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics

, Volume 41, Issue 3, pp 272–293 | Cite as

Home Price, Time-on-Market, and Seller Heterogeneity Under Changing Market Conditions

  • Ping Cheng
  • Zhenguo Lin
  • Yingchun Liu
Article

Abstract

This paper develops a formal model to examine the effect of changing market conditions and individuals’ selling constraints on selling price and time-on-market. Using the concept of Relative Liquidity Constraint (RLC)—a stochastic variable that captures the randomness of future individual constraints and market conditions—the study presents the first ex ante analysis that extends the investigation of the issue of seller heterogeneity to the point of the buying decision, that is, from the perspective of the buyer’s (future seller’s) point of view. We show that seller constraint, as well as the uncertainty of such a constraint, significantly depresses the expected selling price and increases risk. Our closed-form formulas provide a set of simple quantitative tools that enable buyers and sellers to adjust the “market average” to their ex ante “individual expectations”.

Keywords

Home price Time-on-market Seller heterogeneity Market conditions 

Notes

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank editor James Kau, two anonymous referees at the Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, David Beltran-del-Rio and Paul Obrecht at Fannie Mae for their insightful comments and suggetions. All errors remain our own. The views expressed in this article are our own and do not necessarily represent the views of the authors affiliated organizations.

References

  1. Anglin, P. (2006). Value and liquidity under changing market conditions. Journal of Housing Economics, 15, 293–304. doi: 10.1016/j.jhe.2006.10.003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Arnold, M. (1999). Search, bargaining and optimal asking prices. Real Estate Economics, 27, 453–481. doi: 10.1111/1540-6229.00780.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Barron, J. (1975). Search in the labor market and the duration of unemployment: some empirical evidence. The American Economic Review, 65, 934–942.Google Scholar
  4. Bond, S., Hwang, S., Lin, Z., & Vandell, K. (2007). Marketing period risk in a portfolio context: theory and empirical estimates from the UK commercial real estate market? Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 34, 447–461. doi: 10.1007/s11146-007-9022-1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Cheng, P., Lin, Z., & Liu, Y. (2008). A model of time-on-market and real estate price under sequential search with recall. Real Estate Economics, 36, 813–843. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6229.2008.00231.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Ferreira, E., & Sirmans, G. (1989). Selling price, financing premiums, and days on the market. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 2, 209–222. doi: 10.1007/BF00152349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Forgey, F., Rutherford, R., & Vanbuskirk, M. (1994). Foreclosure status and its effect on residential selling price. The Journal Of Real Estate Research, 9, 313–318.Google Scholar
  8. Forgey, F., Rutherford, R., & Springer, T. (1996). Search and liquidity in single-family housing. Real Estate Economics, 24, 273–392. doi: 10.1111/1540-6229.00691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Genesove, D., & Mayer, C. (1997). Equity and time to sale in the real estate market. The American Economic Review, 87, 255–269.Google Scholar
  10. Glower, M., Haurin, D., & Hendershott, P. (1998). Selling price and selling time: the impact of investor motivation. Real Estate Economics, 26, 719–740. doi: 10.1111/1540-6229.00763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Green, R., & Vandell, K. (1998). Optimal asking price and bid acceptance strategies for residential sales. Working Paper, Center for Real Estate and Urban Land Economics, University of Wisconsin–Madison.Google Scholar
  12. Hardin, W., & Wolverton, M. (1996). The relationship between foreclosure status and apartment price. The Journal of Real Estate Research, 12, 101–109.Google Scholar
  13. Huang, J., & Palmquist, R. (2001). Environmental conditions, reservation prices, and time on the market for housing. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 22, 203–219. doi: 10.1023/A:1007891430162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Kluger, B., & Miller, N. (1990). Measuring residential real estate liquidity. AREUEA Journal, 18(2), 145–159.Google Scholar
  15. Knight, J. (2002). Listing price, time on market, and ultimate selling price: causes and effects of listing price changes. Real Estate Economics, 30, 215–237. doi: 10.1111/1540-6229.00038.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Krainer, J. (2001). A theory of liquidity in residential real estate markets. Journal of Urban Economics, 49, 32–53. doi: 10.1006/juec.2000.2180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Lazear, E. (1986). Retail pricing and clearance sales. The American Economic Review, 76, 14–32.Google Scholar
  18. Lin, Z. (2004). Liquidity and pricing biases in the real estate market. Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Wisconsin–Madison, Real Estate and Urban Land Economics.Google Scholar
  19. Lin, Z., & Vandell, K. (2007). Illiquidity and pricing biases in the real estate market. Real Estate Economics, 35(3), 291–330. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6229.2007.00191.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Lin, Z., & Liu, Y. (2008). Real estate returns and risk with heterogeneous investors. Real Estate Economics, 36, 753–776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Lippman, S., & McCall, J. (1986). An operational measure of liquidity. The American Economic Review, 76, 43–55.Google Scholar
  22. Merlo, A., & Ortalo-Magne, F. (2004). Bargaining over residential real estate: evidence from England. Journal of Urban Economics, 56, 192–216. doi: 10.1016/j.jue.2004.05.004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Miceli, T. (1989). The optimal duration of real estate listing contracts. Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 17, 267–277. doi: 10.1111/1540-6229.00491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Quan, D., & Quigley, J. (1991). Price formation and the appraisal function in real estate markets. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 4, 127–146. doi: 10.1007/BF00173120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Read, C. (1988). Price strategies for idiosyncratic goods—the case of housing. Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 16, 379–395. doi: 10.1111/1540-6229.00462.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Ross, S. (2002). A first course in probability (6th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
  27. Rutherford, R., Springer, T., & Yavas, A. (2005). Conflicts between principals and agents: evidence from residential brokerage. Journal of Financial Economics, 76, 627–665. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.06.006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Shilling, J., Benjamin, J., & Sirmans, C. (1990). Estimating net realizable value for distressed real estate. The Journal of Real Estate Research, 5(1), 129–140.Google Scholar
  29. Sirmans, C., Turnbull, G., & Dombrow, J. (1995). Quick house sales: investor mistake or luck? Journal of Housing Economics, 4, 230–243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Sirmans, S., Macpherson, D., & Zietz, E. (2005). The composition of hedonic pricing models. Journal of Real Estate Literature, 13, 3–43.Google Scholar
  31. Springer, T. (1996). Single-family housing transactions: seller motivations, price and marketing time. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 13, 236–254. doi: 10.1007/BF00217393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Stigler, G. (1962). Information in the labor market. Journal of Political Economy, 70, 94–105. doi: 10.1086/258727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Taylor, C. (1999). Time-on-the-market as a sign of quality. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 555–578. doi: 10.1111/1467-937X.00098.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Turnbull, G., Sirmans, C., & Benjamin, J. (1990). Do corporations sell houses for less? A test of housing market efficiency. Applied Economics, 22, 1389–1398. doi: 10.1080/00036849000000109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Whipple, D. (1973). A generalized theory of job search. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 1170–1188. doi: 10.1086/260112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Yavas, A. (1992). A simple search and bargaining model of real estate markets. Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 20, 533–548. doi: 10.1111/1540-6229.00595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Yinger, J. (1981). A search model of real estate broker behavior. The American Economic Review, 71, 591–605.Google Scholar
  38. Zuehlke, T. (1987). Duration dependence in the housing market. Review of Economics and Statistics, 69, 701–704. doi: 10.2307/1935966.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Industry Study, College of BusinessFlorida Atlantic UniversityBoca RatonUSA
  2. 2.Fannie MaeWashingtonUSA

Personalised recommendations