Skip to main content
Log in

Lock in and switch: Asymmetric information and new product diffusion

  • Published:
Quantitative Marketing and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many new web-based services are introduced as free services. Depending on the seller’s business model, some remain free in the long run, while others switch to pay mode at some point in time. I characterize the relation between buyers and a new service seller when the former are uncertain about the latter’s business model and need to incur a one-time sunk cost before enjoying the new service. I derive a natural signaling equilibrium where the seller plays a “lock-in-and-switch” strategy, while buyers play a “wait-and-see” strategy. Specifically, a high-cost seller starts by pricing at zero and waits for a sufficient number of consumers to adopt the new service, at which point the seller switches to pay mode. In this gradual separation equilibrium, the signal is given not by the price level (which always starts at zero) but rather by the duration of the introductory offer. Finally, I show the equilibrium entails diffusion even though consumers are identical and equally aware of the new service’s existence.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. AvantGo offers a premium service for a fee. In Section 5, I consider the case when a seller’s set of options extends beyond the choice of free and pay modes.

  2. By contrast, Hitsch (2006), among others, considers the case when the seller is uncertain about demand.

  3. Even if the optimal monopoly price is positive, there may be reasons why zero is a better pricing strategy. See Bawa and Shoemaker (2004), Shampanier et al. (2007).

  4. In some cases, negative prices are feasible and observed in equilibrium. For example, for a while PayPal paid consumers $10 for opening an account; and opentable.com (an online reservation and review site) sometimes provides dollar-off coupons for restaurants as a reward for using their service. The results in this paper follow through if there exists a finite lower bound to price, which may be negative. The important assumptions are that (1) the seller has no commitment to price beyond the current moment; and (2) the seller is unable to make a fixed transfer to the buyer.

  5. Note that, as expected, for p = 0 we get π H (p) = 0 and Eq. 6 reduces to Eq. 2.

  6. http://www.eudora.com/download/, visited on April 16, 2008.

  7. See Bass (1969) and Jensen (1982) for examples of the former approach; and Griliches (1957), David (1969), Davies (1979) for examples of the latter approach. See also Geroski (2000) for a good survey of this literature.

  8. Danaher (2002) considers optimal pricing strategies for a new subscription service. See Essegaier et al. (2002) for a related approach. One important difference with respect to my model is that these papers look at the case of recurrent fixed feeds (e.g., the monthly rental in a cell phone plan), whereas I consider the one-time sunk cost a consumer must incur before beginning to enjoy a new product or service.

  9. (See for example Fudenberg and Tirole 1983; Ghemawat and Nalebuff 1985; Cabral 2004).

  10. See Rosenthal (1982, 1986), Chen and Rosenthal (1996).

  11. See Gerstner and Hess (1990), Lazear (1995), Wilkie et al. (1998). These papers are inconclusive as to the welfare effects of bait-and-switch, a (currently) illegal activity.

  12. See for example Ellison (2005).

  13. See also Bagwell and Riordan (1991), Judd and Riordan (1994). See Dawar and Sarvary (1997) for a (successful) test of some implications of price signaling theory. In addition to price, other variables, such as specialization, may be used as signals. See Kalra and Li (2008)

  14. See also Cabral and Riordan (1994).

References

  • Bagwell, K. (1987). Introductory price as a signal of cost in a model of repeat business. Review of Economic Studies, 54, 365–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell, K., & Riordan, M. H. (1991). High and declining prices signal product quality. American Economic Review, 81, 224–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banks, J., & Sobel, J. (1987). Equilibrium selection in signalling games. Econometrica, 55, 647–662.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bass, F. M. (1969). A new product growth model for consumer durables. Management Science, 15, 215–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bawa, K., & Shoemaker, R. (2004). The effects of free sample promotions on incremental brand sales. Marketing Science, 23, 345–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, L. M. B. (2004). Simultaneous entry and welfare. European Economic Review, 48, 943–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, L. M. B., & Riordan, M.H. (1994). The learning curve, market dominance and predatory pricing. Econometrica, 62, 1115–1140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, L. M. B., Salant, D., & Woroch, G. (1999). Monopoly pricing with network externalities. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 17, 199–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Rosenthal, R. W. (1996). Dynamic duopoly with slowly changing customer loyalties. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14, 269–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho, I.-K., & Kreps, D. (1987). Signalling games and stable equilibria. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 179–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Danaher, P. J. (2002). Optimal pricing of new subscription services: Analysis of a market experiment. Marketing Science, 21, 119–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David, P. A. (1969). A contribution to the theory of diffusion. Research Center in Economic Growth Memorandum (No. 71). Stanford University.

  • Davies, S. (1979). The diffusion of process innovations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press..

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawar, N., & Sarvary, M. (1997). The signalling impact of low introductory price on perceived quality and trial. Marketing Letters, 8(3), 251–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellison, G. (2005). A model of add-on pricing. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 585–637.

    Google Scholar 

  • Essegaier, S., Gupta, S., & Zhang, Z.J. (2002). Pricing access services. Marketing Science, 21, 139–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1983). Learning-by-doing and market performance. Bell Journal of Economics, 14, 522–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1986). A theory of exit in duopoly. Econometrica, 54, 943–960.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geroski, P. (2000). Models of technological diffusion. Research Policy, 29, 603–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerstner, E., & Hess, J. D. (1990). Can Bait and Switch benefit consumers? Marketing Science, 9, 114–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghemawat, P., & Nalebuff, B. (1985). Exit. Rand Journal of Economics, 16, 184–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1957). Hybrid corn: An exploration in the economics of technological change. Econometrica, 25, 501–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hitsch, G. J. (2006). An empirical model of optimal dynamic product launch and exit under demand uncertainty. Marketing Science, 25, 25–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jain, D., Mahajan, V., & Muller, E. (1995). An approach for determining optimal product sampling for teh diffusion of a new product. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 12, 124–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, M. C. W., & Roy, S. (2002). Dynamic trading in a durable good market with asymmetric information. International Economic Review, 43, 257–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, R. (1982). Adoption and diffusion of an innovation of uncertain profitability. Journal of Economic Theory, 27, 182–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judd, K. L., & Riordan, M. H. (1994). Price and quality in a new product monopoly. Review of Economic Studies, 61, 773–789.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalra, A., & Li, S. (2008). Signaling quality through specialization. Marketing Science, 27, 168–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klemperer, P. (1995). Competition when consumers have switching costs: An overview with applications to industrial organization, macroeconomics, and international trade. Review of Economic Studies, 62, 515–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohli, R., & Jedidi, K. (2007). Representation and inference of lexicographic preference models and their variants. Marketing Science, 26, 380–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishnan, T. V., Bass, F. M., & Jain, D. C. (1999). Optimal pricing strategy for new products. Management Science, 45(12), 1650–1663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (1995). Bait and switch. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 813–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. R., & Roberts, J. (1986). Price and advertising signals of product quality. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 796–821.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narasimhan, C., & Sen, S. K. (1983). New product models for test market data. Journal of Marketing, 47, 11–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noldecke, G., & van Damme, E. (1990). Signalling in a dynamic labor market. Review of Economic Studies, 57, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radner, R., & Richardson, T. J. (2003). Monopolists and viscous demand. Games and Economic Behavior, 45, 442–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radner, R. (2003). Viscous demand. Journal of Economic Theory, 112, 189–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riley, J. (1979). Informational equilibrium. Econometrica, 47(1), 331–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, R. W. (1982). A dynamic model of duopoly with customer loyalties. Journal of Economic Theory, 27, 69–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, R. W. (1986). Dynamic duopoly with incomplete customer loyalties. International Economic Review, 27, 399–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shampanier, K., Mazar, N., & Ariely, D. (2007). Zero as a special price: The true value of free products. Marketing Science, 26, 742–757.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence, A. M. (1981). The learning curve and competition. Bell Journal of Economics, 12, 49–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swinkels, J. M. (1999). Education signalling with preemptive offers. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 949–970.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Talukdar, D., Sudhir, K., & Ainslie, A. (2002). Investigating new product diffusion across products and countries. Marketing Science, 21, 97–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van den Bulte, C., & Joshi, Y. V. (2007). New product diffusion with influentials and imitators. Marketing Science, 26, 400–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venkatesan, R., Krishnan, T. V., & Kumar, V. (2004). Evolutionary estimation of macro-level diffusion models using genetic algorithms: An alternative to nonlinear least squares. Marketing Science, 23, 451–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilkie, W. L., Mela, C. F., & Gundlach, G. T. (1998). Does ‘Bait and Switch’ really benefit consumers? Advancing the DiscussionMarketing Science, 17, 290–293.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks Jim Anton, Kyle Bagwell, Yuxin Chen, Judy Chevalier, Tülin Erdem, Mike Katz, Alessandro Lizzeri, Barry Nalebuff, Roy Radner, and seminar participants at NYU and ECARES for useful comments and suggestions with reference to a previous (and substantially different) version of this paper. The usual disclaimer applies, especially considering the differences between this and previous drafts of the paper. The author is also grateful to the Editor and to two referees for helpful comments and suggestions. A previous draft under the same title was circulated as NYU Stern WP EC-07-11.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luís Cabral.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cabral, L. Lock in and switch: Asymmetric information and new product diffusion. Quant Mark Econ 10, 375–392 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-012-9120-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-012-9120-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation