Skip to main content
Log in

Coercion and equity with centralization of government: how the unification of Italy impacted the southern regions

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Italy was created in 1861 through military annexation by the Kingdom of Savoy (with capital city Torino in Piedmont) of other Italian territories. Immediately thereafter, the new national government started to extend Piedmontese laws to the new nation’s southern regions, introducing conscription and heavy taxation. The institutions and body politics of the pre-unification Italian states differed considerably. The new state centralized governmental power to level those differences. The southern people, were subjected to heavy-handed coercion, if not exploitation. The paper focuses on the coercion imposed by fiscal policies on the South. It asks whether coercion from the center was attenuated by redistribution operated at the regional and, especially, at the personal level with a focus on the poor. The answers confirm that fiscal coercion was indeed formidable. The Italian state imposed a heavy tax burden on the poor of all regions. When public expenditure also is brought in the picture, the poor in the southern regions remained disadvantaged, but less than they were before unification.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The economic differences between North and South at the time of unification are the subject of major debate. According to Felice (2016), the gap in per capita income emerging from reading the best literature should be between 5 and 15%. The GDP figures reported in Table 1 show a gap of 30%. The discrepancy is explained by the fact that, in 1861, economic activities were still disrupted by the war of 1860 and by political events.

  2. After assisting in 1850, in Naples, at the trial of a liberal politician, Carlo Poerio, who received a prison sentence of 24 years imprisonment, Gladstone, the English liberal politician, wrote to Lord Aberdeen (Peel’s former foreign secretary), “This [the Bourbons] is the negation of Good erected into a system of government” (Magnus 1954, p. 99).

  3. Not in terms of sheer size, but of organization and armament. The Piedmontese army had waged war against Austria in 1848 and 1859 and was sustained by a greater tax capacity, while the army of the Bourbons showed weakness even when confronted with popular revolts.

  4. Readers interested to an up to date accurate analysis of the concept of coercion from a distinct social sciences approach will greatly benefit from reading the collective volume edited by Martinez-Vazquez and Winer (2014).

  5. Law n° 2248 of March 20 1865.

  6. The Kingdom of the Two Sicilies introduced a similar discipline in the 1830s (Gargano 2012).

  7. Reported by Cappelli (2016).

  8. The name was given by historians to distinguish it from the rightwing parties and movements of the Twentieth century.

  9. Marongiu (2010) provides a detailed recounting.

  10. Speech to the Chamber of Deputies by Ruggero Bonghi, June 29, 1861. Quoted by Parravicini (1958, p.14). Original source: A.P. Camera dei Deputati. Leg. VIII. Sess. I Discussioni, p. 894.

  11. In the first election of 1861, voters represented 1.92% of the population (Istat 1878, p. 147).

  12. As for the Historical Right, historians to distinguish that reformist coalition from the leftwing groups of the Twentieth century, created the name of Historical Left.

  13. The numbers for taxes and GDP used for the graph are reported in Table 11.

  14. (At least) three ways are possible for determining the fiscal residuum. The first one is called in the literature the administration or cash-flow approach. The second one, called in the literature the monetary income support approach, looks at the income-generating impact of revenue and expenditure and their balance. The third one, called in the literature the welfare or real income approach, looks more closely at the impact of central government policies on the welfare of the residents of various regions.

  15. Ministero di agricoltura. industria e commercio (1882).

  16. More specifically, they are: the very accurate budget of a Tuscan sharecropper recorded for 1878–1879 by Assirelli (1896); the four illustrative budgets referred to families of sharecroppers in Romagna sampled by Pasolini (1890, 1892). Santangelo Spoto (1891) provides the accurate budget of a proprietor family of Puglia in 1879. Einaudi (1898) calculates the incidence of local taxes on the budgets of a small sample of industrial workers in Torino a few years later. Finally, Mira (1970) provides an accurate account of the incidence of income and wealth taxes on the earnings of a notary of Pavia for the period stretching from 1867 to 1900.

  17. The benefits of expenditure are assumed to be the same in Sicily as in the whole of the South, but taxes are different, as we saw.

References

  • Agresta, S. (2004). Istruzione e scolarita’ nella Sicilia del primo Ottocento. Messina: Societá Messinese di Storia Patria.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amendola, N., Salsano, F., & Vecchi, G. (2011). Povertá. In Ricchezza e povertá’. Il benessere degli Italiani dall’Unita’ a oggi. Bologna: Il Mulino.

  • Assirelli, J. P. (1896). Paysan metayer de la commune de Roccasancasciano (Romagne—Toscane-Italie). In Les Ouvriers des Deux Mondes. Serie 2. n. 85. Paris.

  • Brosio, G. (2014). Fiscal coercion in federal systems, with special attention to highly divided societies. In J. Martinez-Vazquez & S. Winer (Eds.), Coercion and social welfare in public finance: Economic and political perspectives (pp. 248–270). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Brosio, G., Cassone, A., & Ricciuti, R. (2002). Tax evasion across Italy: Rational noncompliance or inadequate civic concern? Public Choice, 112(3–4), 259–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1986). The constitution of economic policy. Lecture to the memory of Alfred Nobel. December 8, 1986; Available at https://www.nobelprize.org.

  • Cappelli, G. (2016). Escaping from a human capital trap? Italy’s regions and the move to centralized primary schooling. 1861–1936. European Review of Economic History, 20(1), 46–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carano-Donvito, G. (1909). Dati sulle finanze locali del Mezzogiorno (p. 224). Tipografia nazionale Bertero- XII: Roma.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, C. J. (1988). Conflict and control. Law and order in nineteenth-century Italy. London: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • De Meo, G. (1960). Sul carico tributario erariale del Regno delle due Sicilie nel 1856. In Archivio economico dell’Unificazione Italiana. Vol. I. fascicolo 6.

  • De Meo, G., Percuoco, A. (1856). Le entrate delle province napoletane (Domini di qua’ dal faro) dal 1831 al 1860. In Archivio Economico dell’Unificazione Italiana. Volume I Fascicolo 1. Torino: ILTE.

  • Einaudi, L. (1898). Il partito socialista a Torino e la riforma tributaria. La Riforma Sociale. Fasc. 1.anno V.

  • Federico, G. (2009). Always on the brink: Italy. 1861–1914. In J. L. Cardoso & P. Lains (Eds.), Paying for the liberal state: The rise of public finance in nineteenth century Europe (pp. 186–213). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Felice, E. (2013). Perche’ Il Sud e’ rimasto indietro. Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Felice, E. (2016). On the reconstruction and interpretation of regional inequality in Italy in the long-run: main results and future lines of research. Universitat Autonoma de Barcelonan MPRA Paper No. 66310.

  • Fortunato, G. (1920). La questione meridionale e la riforma tributaria. La voce Roma; Available online at http://bd.fondazionegramsci.org/digital-gramsci/detail/IT-GRAMSCI-BIB00002-0000474/La-questione-meridionale-e-la-riforma-tributaria.html.

  • Gargano, A. (2012). Maestri e scuola elementare nel Mezzogiorno durante la crisi dell’unificazione. In Archivio storico per le province napoletane della Societa’ di storia patria. (Vol. 130, pp. 87–126). Napoli.

  • Genovesi, G. (1998). Storia della scuola in Italia dal settecento a oggi. Laterza: Bari.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gini, C. (1914). L’ammontare e la composizione della ricchezza delle nazioni. Torino: Fratelli Bocca.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministero di agricoltura. industria e commercio (1882). Notizie sulle condizioni dell’agricoltura negli anni 187879 (vol. 3). Roma.

  • Istat. (1858). Annuario statistico italiano per cura di Cesare Correnti e Pietro Maestri. 1864. Torino: Tipografia letteraria.

    Google Scholar 

  • Istat. (1864). Annuario Statistico Italiano. 1864. Torino: Tipografia Letteraria.

    Google Scholar 

  • Istat. (1878). Annuario Statistico Italiano. 1878. Roma: Tipografia Eredi Botta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Istat. (1881). Annuario Statistico Italiano. 1881. Roma: Tipografia Eredi Botta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Istat. (1886). Annuario Statistico Italiano. 1887. Roma: Tipografia Eredi Botta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Istat. (1884). Annuario Statistico Italiano. 1884. Roma: Tipografia Eredi Botta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Istat. (1991). Annuario Statistico Italiano. 1991. Roma: Tipografia Eredi Botta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magnus, Ph. (1954). Gladstone: A biography. London: John Murray.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marongiu, G. (2010). La politica fiscale dell’italialLiberale dall’unità alla crisi di fine secolo. Firenze: Olschki.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Vazquez, J., & Winer, S. (2014). Coercion and social welfare in public finance: Economic and political perspectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mira, G. (1970). Aspetti di una economia familiare nella seconda meta del secolo scorso. In Ricerche economico storiche in onore di Corrado Barbagallo (Vol. 3, pp. 121–33). Napoli.

  • Nitti, F. S. (1920). Nord e Sud. Prime linee di un’inchiesta sulla ripartizione territoriale delle entrate e delle spese dello stato in Italia. Torino: Roux e Viarengo.

  • Ostuni, N. (1992). Finanza e economia nel regno delle due Sicilie. Napoli: Liguori.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parravicini, G. (1958). La politica fiscale e le entrate effettive del Regno d’Italia. I8601890. Torino: Ilte.

  • Pasolini, M. (1890). Una famiglia di mezzadri romagnoli nel comune di Ravenna. Giornale degli economisti., 3, 245–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasolini, M. (1892). Monografie di alcuni operai braccianti nel comune di Ravenna. In Giornale degli Economisti (Vol. 5, pp. 311–343, 411–427).

  • Pescosolido, G. (2017). La questione meridionale in breve. Centocinquant’anni di storia (pp. VI–170). Milano: Donzelli.

  • Santangelo Spoto, I. (1891). Paysan agriculteur de Torremaggiore (Province de Foggia—ltalie). In Les Ouvriers des Deux Mondes. Serie 2, n. 68, Paris.

  • Tanzi, V. (2012). Italica: Costi e conseguenze dell’unificazione d’Italia. Torino: Grantorino.

  • Untersuchungen, J. (1958). English translation. A new principle of just taxation. In R. Musgrave & A. T. Peacock (Eds.), Classics in the theory of public finance (pp. 72–118). New York: St. Martin’s Press.

  • Vecchi, G. (1994). I bilanci familiari in Italia: 1860–1960. Rivista di storia economica, 11, 9–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vecchi, G. (2011). In ricchezza e in povertà. Il benessere degli italiani dall'Unità a oggi. Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vecchi, G. (2012). Sviluppo economico. benessere e disuguaglianza: Italia. 1861–2011. Rivista di storia economica, 1, 177–196. https://doi.org/10.1410/36641.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vecchi, G., & Coppola, M. (2003). Nutrizione e poverta’ in Italia 1861–1911. Rivista di Storia Economica, 19(3), 383–401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volpi, F. (1962). Le finanze dei comuni e delle province del regno d’Italia 1860–1890. Archivio economico dell’unificazione italiana. Torino: ILTE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whalley, J., & Trela, I. (1986). Regional aspects of confederation. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winer, S., Tridimas, G., & Hettich, W. (2014). Social welfare and coercion in public finance. In G. Jorge Martinez-Vazquez & S. Winer (Eds.), Coercion and social welfare in public finance., Economic and political perspectives Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, K. (1896). Ein neues Prinzip der gerechten Besteuerung. Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen. Jena. English translation (1958): A new principle of just taxation. In R. Musgrave & A. T. Peacock (Eds.), Classics in the theory of public finance (pp. 72–118). New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Zamagni, V. (2011). Bilancio e finanza pubblica. L’Unificazione. Treccani: Roma.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziblatt, D. (2004). Rethinking the origins of federalism puzzle. Theory and evidence from nineteenth-century Europe. In World Politics (Vol. 57, pp. 70–98).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziblatt, D. (2008). Structuring the state. The formation of Italy and Germany and the puzzle of federalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author is very grateful for the editorial support received by this Journal and for the comments and suggestions made by two anonymous referees, by Silvia Fedeli, Juan Pablo Jimenez, Pier Vincenzo Bondonio and by the participants in the Workshop on Macroeconomics, Rationality and Institutions held in Rome on December 14–15, 2017.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giorgio Brosio.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, and 13.

Table 8 Pre-unification Italy. Structure and incidence of taxes in 1858
Table 9 Post-unification Italy. Structure and incidence of taxes in 1876
Table 10 Post-unification Italy. Structure and incidence of taxes in 1889–1890
Table 11 Incidence of taxes on GDP: Kingdom of the Two Sicilies, 1858–1890
Table 12 The incidence of taxes on poor agricultural households. Sicily 1858
Table 13 Criteria for determining the tax burden on households in Table 5 in the text

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brosio, G. Coercion and equity with centralization of government: how the unification of Italy impacted the southern regions. Public Choice 177, 235–264 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0589-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0589-2

Keywords

Navigation