Skip to main content

We’re sorry, something doesn't seem to be working properly.

Please try refreshing the page. If that doesn't work, please contact support so we can address the problem.

Log in

Why noncompetitive states are so important for understanding the outcomes of competitive elections: the Electoral College 1868–2016

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Brams and Kilgour (Public Choice 170:99–113, 2017) begin their recent essay on the Electoral College (EC) by pointing out the obvious, but nonetheless regularly neglected fact that noncompetitive states may have a decisive impact on EC outcomes and shape the electoral strategies of the candidates in the competitive states, especially if there is asymmetry in the partisan balances in the non-competitive states. Their contribution is to offer combinatorics insights into the implications of such asymmetries in the form of three new indicators: Winningness, Vulnerability, and Fragility. They then explore the magnitude and effects of these three measures for the presidential elections of 2000, 2004, 2008 and 2012. The major contribution of this note is to extend their analyses of these measures to an additional 34 elections: every election in the modern two-party post-Civil War era from 1868 to 2016. We find the Winningness measure to predict very well over the entire set of 38 presidential elections. Inspired by their work, we also offer a new and simpler metric for partisan asymmetries in noncompetitive states and show how it can predict the expected closeness of EC outcomes as well or better than the more complex combinatorics measures they propose.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Colored maps (chloropleths) are now an indispensable aspect of election coverage, visually emphasizing how geography matters. CNN and other broadcasters are able, with the push of a button, to display historical comparisons of voting patterns at various levels of electoral geography.

  2. On CNN, on election night in 2016, Wolf Blitzer quipped to Jake Tapper that “Jake, [this is] another presidential race where all eyes right now are on Florida”, to which Tapper responded “It's one of the critical states in this race. Donald Trump himself has said he doesn't see a path to the presidency for himself without the state of Florida, the 29 electoral votes.” Tapper went on to say, “the Clinton campaign knows they need Florida. They have been saying for some time they feel better about Florida than they do about states such as North Carolina,… Ohio, or Iowa”.

  3. We will refer to Brams and Kilgour’s Public Choice paper by their names and with the B–K acronym interchangeably throughout this essay.

  4. For example, in 2012, Brams and Kilgour point out (p. 101): “Because Barack Obama had a 233–191 electoral vote lead over Mitt Romney in the 42 noncompetitive states and the District of Columbia, he needed only 37 of the 114 electoral votes in the competitive states to win with a majority of 270 electoral votes, whereas Romney needed 79”.

  5. In 1984, Ronald Reagan won 49 out of 51 states (including Washington, DC). Norman Ornstein, writing before the election, said “Incumbent presidents don’t often lose, particularly presidents presiding over 6% real growth and low or non-existent inflation” (quoted in CQ Press, http://library.cqpress.com/cqresearcher/document.php?id=cqresrre1984091400).

  6. In races with third parties, a margin of victory no greater than 6%. For the purposes of this note, we concern ourselves only with the two highest vote earners and calculate accordingly.

  7. In the process of replicating Brams and Kilgour’s (2017) analyses, we found a few minor errors that we corrected; those corrections explain the differences in the numbers reported in Table A1 for the elections of 2000 and 2004, and those reported in Table 4 of Brams and Kilgour.

  8. In Table 1, Vulnerability and Fragility are defined in all elections that are competitive (17/38), and because the sample is split for Republicans and Democrats, for years in which that party’s candidate had a Winningness of 1 (Vulnerability and Fragility are always zero in these cases).

  9. While these two elections were very close in two-party vote margin, and thus might be regarded as hard to predict, they were less so electorally. In 1960, John F. Kennedy won the EC vote by 9.1% and, in 1880, James Garfield won by 7.5%. In neither election were third-party candidacies consequential in affecting relative two-party shares.

  10. Because of the frequent occurrence of values of 0 or 1, a perfect linear fit is impossible.

  11. In 1992, Bill Clinton was just seven EC votes shy of having enough a majority in noncompetitive states, and could have lost the election in only five of the more than 130,000 different combinations of electoral outcomes among the competitive states, i.e., Winningness >0.99.

  12. Another reason for choosing the ±3% value is a pragmatic one that we found only after we had done robustness checks; over both recent elections and the longer historical data: ±3% value has (marginally) greater predictive power than the often used ±5% definition of competitive state (see on-line Appendix).

  13. Bartels (1985) has pointed out that campaigns have what he calls both “instrumental” and “ornamental” reasons for staging campaign events. Attending an event in a swing state, where a candidate’s presence could increase turnout is instrumental, while visiting a state to satisfy state parties might be ornamental. Hillary Clinton spent over $600,000 in Arizona, perhaps trying to influence lower ticket races by increasing mobilization efforts. Ultimately, Arizona, a state that has had a strong Republican tradition, became competitive in 2016.

  14. Stromberg (2008) suggests a hockey metaphor; as a game winds down, a trailing team looking to increase the probability of tying the game pulls their goalie to provide more offensive potential, taking the risk of giving up another goal. A leading team would instead probably act to protect its lead, replacing offensive players with defensively skilled players.

  15. This conclusion differs from that of early political science literature on campaign strategies which claimed that the most populous states would receive the bulk of campaign activities. For example, Brams and Davis (1974) offered a model that predicted campaign allocations proportional to the electoral votes of each state raised to the power of 3/2. For an early critique of the view that campaigning would necessarily focus on the most populous states, see Colantoni et al. (1975). See also Wright (2009) and Miller (2012).

  16. Data aggregated from FairVote.org, with original data from CNN: http://www.fairvote.org/presidential_tracker_2012#2012_campaign_events

  17. Older elections also largely conform to these expectations. Detailed campaign activities for the 1976 election are available because they were submitted into evidence for the hearing before the Subcommittee on the Constitution of the Committee on the Judiciary (S.J. Res. 28, 1979) on a bill that would abolish the Electoral College and establish a direct popular vote. The data were first used by Bartels (1985). That election shows a similar pattern of campaign activities focused on the competitive states, though there were many more (25) competitive states in 1976 than in the two most recent elections of 2012 and 2016. In 1976, 78% of all campaign events were held in the 25 battleground states, and 78% of all campaign television and radio ads were broadcast there.

  18. Data compiled from AdAge.com, based on state-specific ad buys between October 21, 2016, and Election Day. http://adage.com/article/campaign-trail/states-where-trump-clinton-spending-most-on-advertising/306377/.

  19. In 1964, the Goldwater campaign treated 23 states as battlegrounds (Shaw and Althaus 2017). The Goldwater campaign focused on the South, seeking to mirror the Dixiecrat revolt and pry southern states from the hands of the Democratic party which, except for the Dixiecrat revolt of 1948, had been winning them by large margins. Goldwater’s campaign went poorly except in the deep South, winning only a handful of states. All but one of the states he won were states his campaign treated as battlegrounds. The one exception was a very narrow win.

  20. We regard both of these assumptions as quite reasonable ones to make for purposes of model tractability, but we might expect them to be falsified if electoral tides sweep in a particular direction and thus create interdependencies in vote outcomes in the competitive states.

  21. Minor party candidacies are likely to be a problem for our analyses only in situations when they receive Electoral College votes. This has not been the case in recent elections, as no minor party candidate has won a state since George Wallace in 1968. In their assessment of minor party impact, Pattie and Johnson (2014) do not find substantial effects, and they also note that such effects have often differed in their partisan impacts. To provide a consistent coding across all elections in our dataset we ignore minor party votes and treat contests as between the two major party candidates in terms of two-party vote share.

References

  • Aldrich, J. H. (1993). Rational choice and turnout. American Journal of Political Science, 37(1), 246–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf, J. F., III. (1968). One man, 3.312 votes: A mathematical analysis of the Electoral College. Villanova Law Review, 13(2), 304–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartels, L. M. (1985). Resource allocation in a presidential campaign. The Journal of Politics, 47(3), 928–936.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams, S. J., & Davis, M. D. (1974). The 3/2′s rule in presidential campaigning. American Political Science Review, 68(1), 113–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams, S. J., & Kilgour, M. (2017). Paths to victory in presidential elections: The setup power of noncompetitive states. Public Choice, 170, 99–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colantoni, C. S., Levesque, T., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1975). Campaign resource allocation under the Electoral College. American Political Science Review, 69(1), 141–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CQ Press. (1984). Editorial research reports 1984 (Vol. II). Washington, DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffy, J., & Matros, A. (2015). Stochastic asymmetric Blotto games: Some new results. Economics Letters, 134, 4–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffy, J., & Tavits, M. (2008). Beliefs and voting decisions: A test of the pivotal voter model. American Journal of Political Science, 52(3), 603–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, G. C., III. (2004). Why the Electoral College is bad for America. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelman, A., & King, G. (1993). Why are American presidential election campaign polls so variable when votes are so predictable? British Journal of Political Science, 23(1), 409–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geys, B. (2006). Explaining voter turnout: A review of aggregate-level research. Electoral Studies, 25(4), 637–663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gimpel, J. G., Kaufmann, K. M., & Pearson-Merkowitz, S. (2007). Battleground states versus blackout states: The behavioral implications of modern presidential campaigns. The Journal of Politics, 69(3), 786–797.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B., Brunell, T., & Campagna, J. (1997). Distinguishing between the effects of swing ratio and bias on outcomes in the U.S. Electoral College, 1900–1992. Electoral Studies, 16(4), 471–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B., & Feld, S. (2005). Thinking about the political impacts of the Electoral College. Public Choice, 123, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, S. (2008). Awarding presidential electors by congressional district: Wrong for California, wrong for the nation. Michigan Law Review First Impressions, 106, 95–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, R., Rossiter, D., & Pattie, C. (2004). Disproportionality and bias in U.S. presidential elections: How geography helped Bush defeat Gore but couldn’t help Kerry beat Bush. Political Geography, 24(8), 952–968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ladewig, J. W., & Jasinski, M. P. (2008). On the causes and consequences of and remedies for interstate malapportionment of the U.S. House of Representatives. Perspectives on Politics, 6(1), 89–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsitz, K. (2009). The consequences of battleground and ‘‘spectator’’ state residency for political participation. Political Behavior, 31(2), 187–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsitz, K., & Teigen, J. M. (2010). Orphan counties and the effect of irrelevant information on turnout in statewide races. Political Communication, 27(2), 178–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N. R. (2012). Why the Electoral College is good for political science (and public choice). Public Choice, 150, 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen, G. (1975). Multilinear extensions and the banzhaf value. Naval Research Logistics, 22(4), 741–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pattie, J., & Johnston, R. J. (2014). The electors shall meet in their respective states: Bias and the U.S. Presidential Electoral College 1960–2012. Political Geography, 40, 35–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, T. (2012). Enlightened democracy: The case for the Electoral College (2nd ed.). Torrance: World Ahead Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, D. R. (1999a). The effect of TV ads and candidate appearances on statewide presidential votes, 1988–1996. American Political Science Review, 93(2), 345–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, D. R. (1999b). The methods behind the madness: Presidential Electoral College strategies, 1988–1996. The Journal of Politics, 61(4), 893–913.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, D. R. (2006). The Race to 270. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, D. R., & Althaus, S. (2017). Electoral College strategies of American presidential campaigns from 1952 to 2012. Working paper. Accessed 19 July 2017.

  • Shirani-Mehr, H., Rothschild, D., Goel, S., & Gelman, A. (2017). Disentangling bias and variance in election polls. Working Paper. Retrieved from http://www.stat.columbia.edu/~gelman/research/unpublished/pollposition_v4.pdf.

  • Soumbatiants, S., Chappell, H. W., Jr., & Johnson, E. (2006). Using state polls to forecast U.S. presidential election outcomes. Public Choice, 127, 207–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokes, S. C. (1999). Political parties and democracy. Annual Review of Political Science, 2(1), 243–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T. (2009). How prices matter in politics: The returns to campaign advertising. Public Choice, 140(3/4), 357–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strömberg, D. (2008). How the Electoral College influences campaigns and policy: The probability of being Florida. American Economic Review, 98(3), 769–807.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, J. R. (2009). Pivotal states in the Electoral College, 1880–2004. Public Choice, 139(1), 21–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Daron Shaw and Scott Althaus for their data and helpful comments. They would also like to express gratitude to the journal editors William F. Shughart II and Keith Dougherty, along with the two anonymous reviewers for their constructive comments. Work on this project was supported by the Jack W. Peltason Center of the Study of Democracy at the University of California, Irvine. The first named author is a Ph.D. candidate in Political Science at the University of California, Irvine. The second named author is a Professor of Political Science at UCI and the Jack W. Peltason Chair of Democracy Studies. Replication material can be found at https://github.com/jcervas/Non-Competitive-Advantage.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jonathan R. Cervas.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 99 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cervas, J.R., Grofman, B. Why noncompetitive states are so important for understanding the outcomes of competitive elections: the Electoral College 1868–2016. Public Choice 173, 251–265 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-017-0474-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-017-0474-4

Keywords

Navigation