Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal contest design, closeness and the contest success function

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper considers the optimal design of an asymmetric two-player contest when the designer’s payoff depends not only on performance of the contestants, but also on the closeness of the contest measured by the difference in winning probabilities. In contrast to previous studies, the impact of closeness on the optimal prize depends on the shape of the contest success function. Furthermore, including closeness in the designer’s objective may induce the designer to uniformly increase the contestants’ effort costs. A similar result is obtained in case the designer may handicap the stronger contestant, but an even contest is never optimal.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Amegashie, J.A. (1999). The design of rent-seeking competitions: committees. Preliminary and Final Contests. Public Choice, 99, 63–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amegashie, J.A. (2000). Some results on rent-seeking contests with shortlisting. Public Choice, 105, 245–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baik, K.H. (1994). Effort levels in contests with two asymmetric players. Southern Economic Journal, 61, 367–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baye, M., Kovenock, D., & de Vries, C.G. (1993). Rigging the lobbying process: an application of the all-pay auction. American Economic Review, 83, 289–294.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baye, M., Kovenock, D., & de Vries, C.G. (1996). The all-pay auction with complete information. Economic Theory, 8, 291–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Che, Y.-K., & Gale, I. (1998). Caps on political lobbying. American Economic Review, 88, 643–651.

    Google Scholar 

  • Che, Y.-K., & Gale, I. (2003). Optimal design of research contests. American Economic Review, 93, 646–671.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, A., & Nti, K.O. (1998). Designing an optimal contest. European Journal of Political Economy, 14, 587–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fort, R., & Quirk, J. (1995). Cross subsidization, incentives and outcomes in professional team sports leagues. Journal of Economic Literature, 33, 1265–1299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gavious, A., Moldovanu, B., & Sela, A. (2002). Bid costs and endogenous bid caps. RAND Journal of Economics, 33, 709–722.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, A., & Hassin, R. (1988). Optimal contests. Economic Inquiry, 26, 133–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gradstein, M. (1998). Optimal contest design: volume and timing of rent seeking contests. European Journal of Political Economy, 14, 575–585.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gradstein, M., & Konrad, K.A. (1999). Orchestrating rent-seeking contests. Economic Journal, 109, 536–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohli, I., & Singh, N. (1999). Rent seeking and rent setting with asymmetric effectiveness of lobbying. Public Choice, 99, 275–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leininger, W. (1993). More efficient rent-seeking – a münchhausen solution. Public Choice, 75, 43–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moldovanu, B., & Sela, A. (2001). The optimal allocation of prizes in contests. American Economic Review, 91, 542–558.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nti, K.O. (1997). Comparative statics of contests and rent-seeking games. International Economic Review, 38, 43–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nti, K.O. (1999). Rent-seeking with asymmetric valuations. Public Choice, 98, 415–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nti, K.O. (2004). Maximum efforts in contests with asymmetric valuations. European Journal of Political Economy, 20, 1059–1066.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shachar, R., & Nalebuff, B. (1999). Follow the leader: theory and evidence on political participation. American Economic Review, 89, 525–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, N., & Wittman, D. (1998). Contest design and the objective of the contest designer: sales promotion, sporting events, and patent races. In: Baye, M. (ed.), Advances in Applied Microeconomics Vol. 7, JAI Press, 139–167.

  • Skarperdas, S. (1996). Contest success functions. Economic Theory, 7, 283–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stein, W.E. (2002). Asymmetric rent-seeking with more than two contestants. Public Choice, 113, 325–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stein, W.E., & Rapoport, A. (2004). Asymmetric two-stage group rent-seeking: comparison of two contest structures. Public Choice, 118, 151–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szidarovszky, F., & Okuguchi, K. (1997). On the existence and uniqueness of pure nash equilibrium in rent-seeking games. Games and Economic Behavior, 18, 135–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szymanski, S. (2003). The economic design of sporting contests. Journal of Economic Literature, XLI, 1137–1187.

  • Szymanski, S. (2004). Professional team sports are only a game: the walrasian fixed-supply conjecture model, contest-nash equilibrium, and the invariance principle. Journal of Sports Economics, 5, 111–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent-seeking. In: Buchanan, J.M., Tollison, R.D., & Tullock, G. (eds.), Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, College Station: Texas A& M University Press.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marco Runkel.

Additional information

JEL classification: D72, C72

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Runkel, M. Optimal contest design, closeness and the contest success function. Public Choice 129, 217–231 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-006-9030-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-006-9030-3

Key Words

Navigation