Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Estimation of cost efficiency without cost data

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

One of the advantages of conduct parameter games is that they enable estimation of market power without total cost data. In line with this, we develop a conduct parameter based model to estimate the firm specific “marginal cost efficiency” and conduct without using total cost data. The marginal cost efficiency is an alternative measure of efficiency that is based on deadweight loss. We illustrate our methodology by estimating firm-route-quarter specific conducts and marginal cost efficiencies of U.S. airlines for Chicago based routes without using route-level total cost data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Perloff et al. (2007) and Bresnahan (1989) for more details on conduct parameter approach.

  2. See Kumbhakar and Lovell (2003) for a book-length survey on SFA and Sickles (2005) for a simulation study examining the performances of some estimators in the SFA literature.

  3. See Comanor and Leibenstein (1969) and Kutlu and Sickles (2012) for more details about calculation of DWL when firms are inefficient.

  4. Kutlu and Sickles (2012) define EFMC as the sum of a shadow cost and efficient marginal cost that is calculated using stochastic frontier analysis techniques. The shadow cost reflects the constraints that the firms face such as capacity or incentive compatibility constraints. Efficient marginal cost is the marginal cost when the firm achieves full efficiency. Although they define the EFMC concept, they calculate EFMC using cost efficiency estimates obtained from a standard stochastic cost frontier model. Hence, while the concept is due to Kutlu and Sickles (2012), arguably, we develop a more proper method that can directly calculate EFMC.

  5. See Berry and Jia (2010) for a paper that is studying airline performance in a different framework.

  6. Weiher et al. (2002) use a similar approach.

  7. Since Kutlu and Sickles (2012) estimate an aggregate model (i.e., route specific market power), they use market share weighted efficiency estimates in their estimations. That is why their route specific efficiency variables are not the same for different routes.

  8. Kutlu and Sickles (2012) use a variation of the distribution free approach proposed by Cornwell et al. (1990). Kutlu (2017b) discusses some of the potential estimation difficulties for such distribution free approaches.

  9. When calculating DWL values, Kutlu and Sickles (2012) used SFA-type efficiency estimates as a proxy for marginal cost efficiency.

  10. Similar to our study, Delis and Tsionas (2009) simultaneously estimate bank conducts and efficiencies. However, their model requires total cost data. Hence, as it stands, their methodology is not applicable to our airline example.

  11. Lee and Johnson (2015) argue that in imperfectly competitive markets inefficiency may in fact be a result of endogenous prices and the effect of output production on price.

  12. Note that perceived marginal revenue must be positive so that the equilibrium makes sense. Hence, we assume that 1 − \(\frac{{s_{it}}}{{E_t}}\theta _{it}\) > 0. So, we have ln \(\left( {1 - \frac{{s_{it}}}{{E_t}}\theta _{it}} \right)\) ≤ 0.

  13. The introduction of the error term enables us to deviate from a single market price. Also, the price may be considered to be a function of firm specific variables, Xd,it.

  14. For details about the identification conditions for conduct parameter models, we direct the reader to Bresnahan (1982), Lau (1982), Perloff et al. (2007), and Perloff and Shen (2012).

  15. Note that a constant marginal cost function does not depend on quantity but it may still depend on variables other than the quantity.

  16. At the end of this section, we provide a discussion about identification condition for stochastic frontier models with endogenous regressors.

  17. In the figure, for the sake of illustrating the ideas better, we rather use market level conduct parameter.

  18. We may replace \(u_{it} = h_{it}\tilde u_{it}\) assumption by \(u_{it} = h_{it}\tilde u_i\) so that \(\tilde u_i\) is a firm specific term. This would be in line with the panel data stochastic frontier models.

  19. This bias correction term is said to be a control function.

  20. See also Guan et al. (2009) and Tran and Tsionas (2013) for GMM based approaches for handling endogeneity in SFA framework.

  21. See Amsler et al. (2016) for further details of identification in SFA models with endogenous variables.

  22. The average is calculated after eliminating the outliers.

  23. The incredible tickets are defined by DB1B data set.

  24. For more information about DOT's dataset see Weiher et al. (2002) and Good et al. (2008).

  25. GEOS is the GENSP variable that is used in Gerardi and Shapiro (2009). GENSP is similar to the GEOSHARE variable of Borenstein and Rose (1994). The difference is that Borenstein and Rose (1994) use average daily enplanements while we use average quarterly enplanements.

  26. Kutlu and Sickles (2012) also assume quantity competition for airlines.

  27. If the airlines are playing a version of dynamic conduct parameters game that is suggested by Puller (2009), route-specific time dummy variables would capture dynamic factors that enter the airlines' optimization problems as well. In this case, the estimates of parameters, conduct parameters, and efficiencies would still be consistent. However, the marginal cost estimates may be downward biased as the prediction of marginal costs include these dynamic factors. Nevertheless, the efficient full marginal cost estimates would be consistent.

  28. Recall that we define E t  = −\(\frac{{\partial Q_t}}{{\partial P_t}}\frac{{P_t}}{{Q_t}}\).

  29. Hence, as we illustrate in the Appendix, our parameter and efficiency estimates are consistent even when the marginal costs are stochastic.

  30. The median of theoretical conduct values for joint profit maximization scenario is 6.77, which is the median of \(\frac{1}{{s_{itr}}}\).

  31. For example, some of them operate only on certain routes in order to reduce costs.

  32. Note that since u has a half normal distribution its mean depends on \(\sigma _u^2\). In particular, the mean of u is an increasing function of \(\sigma _u^2\).

  33. Note that the triangular welfare loss area (shaded area between Q θ and Q C in Fig. 1) for the benchmark model is larger compared to that of full-efficiency model. Therefore, the rectengular area that we estimated is a lower bound for the DWL bias.

  34. Borenstein and Rose (1994), Stavins (2001), Gerardi and Shapiro (2009), and Chakrabarty and Kutlu (2014) examine the relationship between market power and price discrimination.

  35. For expositional purposes, we ignore the two-sided error term.

  36. See Puller (2009) for further details about his model and restrictions. One particular assumption that Puller (2009) makes is that the firms play an efficient super-game equilibrium when they cooperate. That is, they maximize the joint profit subject to incentive compatibility constraints. Hence, the corresponding efficient super-game equilibrium values are benchmark for the full market power case.

  37. In the static setting we don't have this identification issue as the dynamic correction terms are zero.

References

  • Aigner DJ, Lovell CAK, Schmidt PJ (1977) Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. J Econom 6:21–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amsler C, Prokhorov A, Schmidt P (2016) Endogeneity in stochastic frontier models. J Econom 190:280–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amsler C, Prokhorov A, Schmidt P (2017) Endogenous environmental variables in stochastic frontier models. J Econom 199:131–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger A, Hannan TH (1998) The efficiency cost of market power in the banking industry: a test of the “quiet life” and related hypothesis. Rev Econ Stat 80:454–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry S, Jia P (2010) Tracing the woes: an empirical analysis of the airline industry. Am Econ J Microecon 2:1–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borenstein S (1989) Hubs and high fares: dominance and market power in the U.S. airline industry. Rand J Econ 20:344–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borenstein S, Rose NL (1994) Competition and price dispersion in the U.S. airline industry. J Polit Econ 102:653–683

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander JA, Zhang A (1990) Market conduct in the airline industry: an empirical study. Rand J Econ 21:567–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan TF (1982) The oligopoly solution is identified. Econ Lett 10:87–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan TF (1989) Studies of industries with market power, the handbook of industrial organization. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner J, Dyer N, Spiller PT (1992) Fare determination in airline hub-and-spoke networks. Rand J Econ 23:309–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakrabarty D, Kutlu L (2014) Competition and price discrimination in the airline market. Appl Econ 46:3421–3436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comanor WS, Leibenstein H (1969) Allocative efficiency, X-efficiency and the measurement of welfare losses. Economica 36:304–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornwell C, Schmidt P, Sickles RC (1990) Production frontiers with time-series variation in efficiency levels. J Econom 46:185–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corts KS (1999) Conduct parameters and the measurement of market power. J Econom 88:227–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delis MD, Tsionas EG (2009) The joint estimation of bank-level market power and efficiency. J Bank Financ 33:1842–1850

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz H (1973) Industry structure, market rivalry, and public policy. J Law Econ 16:1–9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duygun M, Kutlu L, Sickles RC (2016) Measuring productivity and efficiency: a Kalman filter approach. J Product Anal 46:155–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Genesove D, Mullin W (1998) Testing static oligopoly models: conduct and cost in the sugar industry, 1890–1914. Rand J Econ 29:355–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerardi KS, Shapiro AH (2009) Does competition reduce price dispersion? New evidence from the airline industry. J Political Econ 107:1–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Good D, Sickles RC, Weiher J (2008) A hedonic price index for airline travel. Rev Income Wealth 54:438–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (1980a) Maximum likelihood estimation of econometric frontier functions. J Econom 13:27–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (1980b) On the estimation of a flexible frontier production model. J Econom 3:101–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2003) Simulated likelihood estimation of the normal-gamma stochastic frontier function. J Product Anal 19:179–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2005a) Fixed and random effects in stochastic frontier models. J Product Anal 23:7–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2005b) Reconsidering heterogeneity in panel data estimators of the stochastic frontier model. J Econom 126:269–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffiths WE, Hajargasht G (2016) Some models for stochastic frontiers with endogeneity. J Econom 190:341–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guan Z, Kumbhakar SC, Myers RJ, Lansink AO (2009) Measuring excess capital capacity in agricultural production. Am J Agric Econ 91:765–776

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1935) Annual survey of economic theory: the theory of monopoly. Econometrica 3:1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ito H, Lee D (2007) Domestic code sharing, alliances, and airfares in the U.S. airline industry. J Law Econ 50:355–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iwata G (1974) Measurement of conjectural variations in oligopoly. Econometrica 42:947–966

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karakaplan MU, Kutlu L (2017a) Handling endogeneity in stochastic frontier analysis. Econ Bull 37:889–901

    Google Scholar 

  • Karakaplan MU, Kutlu L (2017b) Endogeneity in panel stochastic frontier models: an application to the japanese cotton spinning industry. Appl Econ 49:5935–5939

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koetter M, Kolari JW, Spierdijk L (2012) Enjoying the quiet life under deregulation? Evidence from adjusted Lerner Indices for US Banks. Rev Econ Stat 94:462–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koetter M, Poghosyan T (2009) The identification of technology regimes in banking: implications for the market power-fragility nexus. J Bank Financ 33:1413–1422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Lovell CAK (2003) Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Kutlu L (2010) Battese-Coelli estimator with endogenous regressors. Econ Lett 109:79–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L (2012a) Price discrimination in Cournot Competition. Econ Lett 117:540–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L (2012b) U.S. banking efficiency, 1984–1995. Econ Lett 117:53–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L (2017a) A conduct parameter model of price discrimination. Scott J Polit Econ 64:530–536

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L (2017b) A constrained state space approach for estimating firm efficiency. Econ Lett 152:54–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L, McCarthy P (2016) US airport governance and efficiency. Transp Res Part E 89:117–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L, Sickles CR (2012) Estimation of market power in the presence of firm level inefficiencies. J Econom 168:141–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L, Sickles CR (2017) Measuring market power when firms price discriminate. Empir Econ 53:287–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L, Tran K, Tsionas EG (2018) A time-varying true individual effects model with endogenous regressors, Working paper. https://ssrn.com/abstract=2721864

  • Lau LJ (1982) On identifying the degree of competitiveness from industry price and output data. Econ Lett 10:93–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee C-Y, Johnson AL (2015) Measuring efficiency in imperfectly competitive markets: an example of rational inefficiency. J Optim Theory Appl 164:702–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerner AP (1934) The concept of monopoly and the measurement of monopoly power. Rev Econ Stud 1:157–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maudos J, Fernandez de Guevara J (2007) The cost of market power in banking: social welfare loss vs. cost efficiency. J Bank Financ 31:2103–2125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meeusen W, van den Broeck J (1977) Efficiency estimation from Cobb-Douglas production function with composed error. Int Econ Rev 8:435–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oum TH, Zhang A, Zhang Y (1993) Inter-firm rivalry and firm-specific price elasticities in deregulated airline markets. J Transp Econ Policy 27:191–192

    Google Scholar 

  • Perloff JM, Karp LS, Golan A (2007) Estimating market power and strategies. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Perloff JM, Shen EZ (2012) Collinearity in linear structural models of market power. Rev Ind Organ 40:131–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puller SL (2007) Pricing and firm conduct in California’s deregulated electricity market. Rev Econ Stat 89:75–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puller SL (2009) Estimation of competitive conduct when firms are efficiently colluding: addressing the Corts critique. Appl Econ Lett 16:1497–1500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sickles RC (2005) Panel estimators and the identification of firm-specific efficiency levels in semi-pcolluding: addressing the Corts critiquearametric and non-parametric settings. J Econom 126:305–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stavins J (2001) Price discrimination in the airline market: the effect of market concentration. Rev Econ Stat 83:200–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson RE (1980) Likelihood functions for generalized stochastic frontier estimation. J Econom 13:57–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tran KC, Tsionas EG (2013) GMM estimation of stochastic frontier model with endogenous regressors. Econ Lett 118:233–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tran KC, Tsionas EG (2015) Endogeneity in stochastic frontier models: copula approach without external instruments. Econ Lett 133:85–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tran KC, Tsionas EG (2016) On the estimation of zero-inefficiency stochastic frontier models with endogenous regressors. Econ Lett 147:19–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiher JC, Sickles RC, Perloff JM (2002) Market power in the US airline industry. In: Slottje DJ (ed) Measuring Market Power. Emerald Group Publishing, North-Holland

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Vivek Ghosal, Giannis Karagiannis, Byung-Cheol Kim, UshaNair-Reichert, Robin Sickles, Jerry Thursby, and Mike Tsionas for their valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Levent Kutlu.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official policy or position of SunTrust Bank.

Appendix: extensions of theoretical model

Appendix: extensions of theoretical model

The theoretical model we presented illustrates how the marginal cost efficiency concept can be incorporated to a simple yet commonly used conduct parameter model. It is possible to apply similar ideas to a variety of different conduct parameter models. In this appendix, we briefly present some alternative frameworks where marginal cost efficiency concept can be used.

1.1 Capacity constraints

Our model can be extended to a setting in which firms have capacity constraints. This extension of our model is inspired by the conduct parameter model proposed by Puller (2007). In the presence of capacity constraints the optimization problem for firm i becomes:

$$\mathop {{{\mathrm{max}}}}\limits_{q_{it}} P_tq_{it} - C_{it}{\kern 1pt} {\mathrm{s}}{\mathrm{.t}}{\mathrm{.}}{\kern 1pt} q_{it} \le K_{it}$$
(13)

where K it is the capacity constraint that firm i is facing at time t. The first order conditions for the corresponding conduct parameter game are:

$$P_t = - \theta _{it}P_t^\prime q_{it} + c_{it} + \lambda _{it}$$
(14)

where λ it  ≥ 0 is the shadow cost of capacity which can be estimated by including variables capturing extent of capacity constraints. For example, Puller (2007) uses a dummy variable, which equals one when a constraint is binding. If we let \(\tilde c_{it}^ \ast = c_{it}^ \ast + \lambda _{it}\) and \(\tilde c_{it} = c_{it} + \lambda _{it}\), as earlier we have:

$${\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} P_{it} = {\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} \tilde c_{it}^ \ast + g_{it} + u_{it} + \varepsilon _{it}^s.$$
(15)

The presence of λ it may make it difficult to estimate this model. A solution may be to use an inefficiency variable, r it  ≥ 0, which enters the equation additively:

$$P_{it} = - \theta _{it}P_t^\prime q_{it} + c_{it}^ \ast + \lambda _{it} + r_{it} + \varepsilon _{it}^s$$
(16)

where \(c_{it} = c_{it}^ \ast + r_{it}\), \(r_{it}\sim N^ + \left( {\mu _r,\sigma _r^2} \right)\), and \(\varepsilon _{it}^s\) is the usual two-sided error term.

In line with the standard stochastic frontier models, in our original model the realized marginal cost (c it ) is assumed to be a multiple of minimum (frontier) marginal cost \(\left( {c_{it}^ \ast } \right)\); and the ratio of efficient marginal cost to realized marginal cost \(\left( {c_{it}^ \ast {\mathrm{/}}c_{it}} \right)\) is defined as marginal cost efficiency. In this setting, the realized marginal cost is assumed to follow \({\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} c_{it} = {\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} c_{it}^ \ast + u_{it}\) where u it  ≥ 0.Footnote 35 Efficiency is calculated using the estimates from this log-transformed multiplicative form by \(Eff_{it} = c_{it}^ \ast {\mathrm{/}}c_{it} = {\mathrm{exp}}\left( { - u_{it}} \right)\). In this example, the inefficiency term, r it , enters the model additively. Hence, r it measures the marginal cost efficiency additively. That is, we model the realized marginal cost by \(c_{it} = c_{it}^ \ast + r_{it}\) where r it  ≥ 0. Similar to its multiplicative counterpart, this model additively measures how large the realized marginal cost is relative to the efficient marginal cost. After estimating the parameters of the additive model, efficiency can be estimated by \(Eff_{it} = c_{it}^ \ast {\mathrm{/}}c_{it}{\mathrm{ = }}c_{it}^ \ast {\mathrm{/}}\left( {c_{it}^ \ast + r_{it}} \right)\). Depending on the structural model used, the researcher may find either multiplicative, u it , or additive, r it , versions of efficiency variable convenient. However, it seems that for the game theoretic models, the additive version may be more frequently needed.

1.2 Stochastic marginal cost

Until now we considered models where the firms have perfect information about the marginal costs. However, firms may not always have perfect information about their marginal costs. In such cases, they would maximize their expected profits. We provide a simple example for how this issue can be handled in our framework. Assume that the marginal costs of the firms are stochastic in the sense that:

$${\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} c_{it} = {\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} c_{it}^ \ast + u_{it} + v_{it}$$
(17)

where the inefficiency level, u it , and the distribution of \(v_{it}\sim N\left( {0,\sigma _v^2} \right)\) is known by the firms but v it is not observed by neither the firms nor the researcher. In this scenario, the perceived marginal revenue would be equal to the expected marginal cost. As earlier, the perceived marginal revenue is given by:

$$PMR\left( {\theta _{it}} \right) = P_t\left( {1 - \frac{{s_{it}}}{{E_t}}\theta _{it}} \right){\mathrm{.}}$$
(18)

The expectation of marginal cost is given by:

$$\begin{array}{*{20}{l}} {E\left[ {c_{it}} \right]} \hfill & = \hfill & {c_{it}^ \ast {\kern 1pt} {\mathrm{exp}}\left( {u_{it}} \right)E\left[ {{\mathrm{exp}}\left( {v_{it}} \right)} \right]} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & = \hfill & {c_{it}^ \ast {\kern 1pt} {\mathrm{exp}}\left( {u_{it}} \right){\mathrm{exp}}\left( {\frac{1}{2}\sigma _v^2} \right) \Rightarrow } \hfill \\ {{\mathrm{ln}}\left( {E\left[ {c_{it}} \right]} \right)} \hfill & = \hfill & {\gamma + {\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} c_{it}^ \ast + u_{it}} \hfill \end{array}$$
(19)

where \(\gamma = \frac{1}{2}\sigma _v^2\). Hence, after adding the error term, the supply equation for firm i is given by:

$${\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} P_{it} = \gamma + {\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} c_{it}^ \ast + g_{it} + u_{it} + \varepsilon _{it}^s.$$
(20)

This supply equation is the same as the deterministic cost function scenario except for the addition of the constant term, γ. If v it is heteroskedastic so that \(v_{it}\sim N\left( {0,\sigma _{vi}^2} \right)\) where \(\sigma _{vi}^2\) is firm specific, the model becomes:

$${\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} P_{it} = \gamma _i + {\mathrm{ln}}{\kern 1pt} c_{it}^ \ast + g_{it} + u_{it} + \varepsilon _{it}^s{\mathrm{.}}$$
(21)

This model can be estimated using the true individual effects model of Kutlu et al. (2018).

1.3 Multi-output firms

Single-output scenario may be restrictive in some contexts such as banking (e.g., Berger and Hannan 1998; Koetter et al. 2012; Kutlu 2012b). Therefore, we provide a conduct parameter model with multi-output firms. Without loss of generality, we assume that there are two outputs and the corresponding demands are represented by P1(Q) and P2(Q) where Q = (Q1, Q2) is the market output vector. The cost function for firm i is C i (q i ) where q i  = (q1i, q2i) represents the firm output vector. The profit function for firm i is given by:

$$\pi _{it} = P_1\left( {Q_t} \right)q_{1it} + P_2\left( {Q_t} \right)q_{2it} - C_{it}\left( {q_i} \right){\mathrm{.}}$$
(22)

Hence, perceived marginal revenues for outputs are:

$$\begin{array}{*{20}{l}} {PMR_1\left( {\theta _{it}} \right)} \hfill & = \hfill & {P_{1t} + \frac{{\partial P_{1t}}}{{\partial Q_{1t}}}\frac{{\partial Q_{1t}}}{{\partial q_{1it}}}q_{1it} + \frac{{\partial P_{2t}}}{{\partial Q_{1t}}}\frac{{\partial Q_{1t}}}{{\partial q_{1it}}}q_{2it}} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & = \hfill & {P_{1t} + \left( {\frac{{\partial P_{1t}}}{{\partial Q_{1t}}}q_{1it} + \frac{{\partial P_{2t}}}{{\partial Q_{1t}}}q_{2it}} \right)\theta _{1it}} \hfill \\ {PMR_2\left( {\theta _{it}} \right)} \hfill & = \hfill & {P_{2t} + \left( {\frac{{\partial P_{1t}}}{{\partial Q_{2t}}}q_{1it} + \frac{{\partial P_{2t}}}{{\partial Q_{2t}}}q_{2it}} \right)\theta _{2it}} \hfill \end{array}$$
(23)

where θ it  = (θ1it, θ2it) = \(\left( {\frac{{\partial Q_{1t}}}{{\partial q_{1it}}},\frac{{\partial Q_{2t}}}{{\partial q_{2it}}}} \right)\) is the vector of conducts for each output. In line with Nash equilibrium solution, we assume that \(\frac{{\partial Q_{2t}}}{{\partial q_{1it}}} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial Q_{1t}}}{{\partial q_{2it}}} = 0\). After adding the error terms, the supply relations become:

$$\begin{array}{l}P_{1t} = - \left( {\frac{{\partial P_{1t}}}{{\partial Q_{1t}}}q_{1it} + \frac{{\partial P_{2t}}}{{\partial Q_{1t}}}q_{2it}} \right)\theta _{1it} + c_{1it}^ \ast + r_{1it} + \varepsilon _{1it}^s\\ P_{2t} = - \left( {\frac{{\partial P_{1t}}}{{\partial Q_{2t}}}q_{1it} + \frac{{\partial P_{2t}}}{{\partial Q_{2t}}}q_{2it}} \right)\theta _{2it} + c_{2it}^ \ast + r_{2it} + \varepsilon _{2it}^s\end{array}$$
(24)

where \(r_{1it}\sim N^ + \left( {\mu _{r_1},\sigma _{r_1}^2} \right)\) and \(r_{2it}\sim N^ + \left( {\mu _{r_2},\sigma _{r_2}^2} \right)\) represent the corresponding marginal cost inefficiencies additively so that \(c_{1it} = c_{1it}^ \ast + r_{1it}\) and \(c_{2it} = c_{2it}^ \ast + r_{2it}\); and \(\varepsilon _{1it}^s\) and \(\varepsilon _{2it}^s\) are the usual two-sided error terms. After estimating the demand equations, these supply equations can be estimated separately using stochastic frontier methods that we described above.

1.4 Dynamic strategic interactions

A formal treatment of conduct parameter games in which the strategic interactions of the firms are dynamic is beyond the scope of this study. However, following Puller (2009), we recommend including time fixed-effects, which may condition out the dynamic effects in firms’ optimization problems.Footnote 36 Even though the estimates of parameters (including parameters of the conduct and efficiency) are consistent in this dynamic game scenario, we cannot separately identify the efficient marginal costs, \(c_{it}^ \ast \), and dynamic correction terms because the time dummies capture not only cost related unobserved factors that change over time but also the dynamic correction terms.Footnote 37 Nevertheless, except for the portion of time fixed-effects that contribute to \(c_{it}^ \ast \), the other parameters of \(c_{it}^ \ast \) are identified. Moreover, many times \(c_{it}^ \ast \) is not the main interest. In our empirical example, we assume a static model, which is not subject to these identification issues.

Finally, it is possible to extend the dynamic model of Kutlu and Sickles (2012) using similar procedures that we presented. However, since their game theoretical model estimates market-time specific conducts, the extension of this model would estimate market-time specific conduct and marginal cost efficiency.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kutlu, L., Wang, R. Estimation of cost efficiency without cost data. J Prod Anal 49, 137–151 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-018-0527-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-018-0527-9

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation