Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Intangible investment in people and productivity

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Organizational activity, information and communication technology work, and research and development (R&D) can be classified as work that creates intangible capital. We measure the returns to these three types of labor input by accounting for differences in their productivity compared with other labor inputs using Finnish firm-level data from 1998 to 2008. We apply a novel idea to use hiring as one proxy for productivity and demand shocks. We find that organizational workers increase total factor productivity and improve the profitability of high-productivity firms. R&D workers account for a large share of intangible capital; however, the returns to R&D are low. Investments in organizational competence are more likely to result in more rapid productivity growth. Firms with performance-related pay or domestically owned firms with extensive foreign activities have been among the highest performers with respect to the use of organizational work.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Piekkola (2011) reports that in Finland, Norway, the UK, Germany, Czech Republic and Slovenia, the share of workers devoted to these occupations was approximately around 18 %.

  2. In our approach, we do not need actual measures of intangible investments. The expenditure-based approach (e.g., Görzig et al. 2010) evaluates the combination of labor, intermediate inputs, and capital that is necessary to produce intangible assets. Using this approach, Piekkola (2010) reports that at the company level, organizational, R&D, and ICT own-account business investments were approximately 7 % of the business value added in Finland.

  3. The labor input measure is the headcount (i.e., the total number of employees). In the robustness analysis of our empirical results, we examine hours as an alternative measure.

  4. The works of Abowd and Kramarz (2005) and Iranzo et al. (2007) are examples of studies in which this type of measure, which is obtained from an individual-level wage equation, has been included in a firm-level production function.

  5. Note that hiring that is reversed during the year is not observed. Therefore, the hiring rate is greater than or equal to zero but cannot exceed two (which would be the case in the entry of a new firm).

  6. The Stata code that is used in the estimation is extended based on that used in Yasar et al. (2008).

  7. Suomen Asiakastieto is the leading business and credit information company in Finland.

  8. The original data are from the years 1995–2008; however, the observations from 1995 to 1997 are incomplete, and those from 1998 to 1999 are used for calculating some of the variables. The employee data and balance sheet data have been collected from two different sources that have somewhat different coverage. The number of employees in the balance sheet data is approximately 20 % higher than in the employee data primarily because of temporary workers who are not observed in the sample firms in the last quarter.

  9. In contrast to that study, however, we use a linear approximation rather than a nonlinear estimation.

  10. Data collected by the Talouselämä magazine from the 500 largest firms in Finland provide similar figures. For large firms with employees abroad, the average domestic employment is 4,400, and the average employment abroad is 2,200.

  11. PRP remunerations are paid based on the achievement of established targets. PRP is a relatively recent form of compensation covering <10 % of firms in 1995 but extending to more than 60 % of firms among those with more than 30 employees by 2006. The average PRP compensation is <5 % of annual salaries (Confederation of Finnish Employers).

  12. Because the data are obtained from selected samples, we also experiment with selection models in which the choice of intangible-capital-related employees was first estimated. The results are essentially the same as those obtained with OLS. In any case, it is difficult to find variables that would convincingly affect the choice to have intangible capital but not its productivity contribution.

References

  • Abowd J, Kramarz F (2005) Human capital and worker productivity: direct evidence from linked employer–employee data. Ann Econ Stat 79(80):323–338

    Google Scholar 

  • Abowd JM, Kramarz F, Margolis DN (1999) High wage workers and high wage firms. Econometrica 67:251–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abowd JM, Creecy RH, Kramarz F (2002) Computing person and firm effects using linked longitudinal employer–employee data. Unpublished manuscript

  • Ackerberg D, Benkard CL, Berry S, Pakes A (2007) Econometric tools for analyzing market outcomes. In: Heckman JJ, Leamer EE (eds) Handbook of econometrics, vol 6. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 4171–4276

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloom N, Sadun R, Van Reenen J (2007) Americans do I.T. better: US multinationals and the productivity miracle. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 6291. Centre for Economic Policy Research, London

  • Bond S (2002) Dynamic panel data models: a guide to micro data methods and practice. Portuguese Econ J 1:141–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan TF, Greenstein S (1999) Technological competition and the structure of the computer industry. J Ind Econ 47:1–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson E, Hitt LM (2000) Beyond computation: information technology, organizational transformation and business performance. J Econ Perspect 14:23–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson E, Hitt LM, Yang S (2002) Intangible assets: computers and organizational capital. Brookings papers on economic activity, no. 2002-1, pp 137–181

  • Corrado CA, Hulten CR, Sichel DE (2005) Measuring capital and technology: an expanded framework. In: Corrado C, Haltiwanger J, Sichel D (eds) Measuring capital in the new economy. National Bureau of Economic Research: studies in income and wealth, vol 65. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

  • Corrado C, Hulten C, Sichel DE (2006) Intangible capital and economic growth. Finance and economics discussion paper series no. 24: Federal Reserve Board, Washington

  • Foster L, Haltiwanger J, Syverson C (2008) Reallocation, firm turnover, and efficiency: selection on productivity or profitability? Am Econ Rev 98:394–425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görzig B, Piekkola H, Riley R (2010) Production of intangible investment and growth: methodology in INNODRIVE. Innodrive Working Paper No. 1

  • Griliches Z (1967) Production functions in manufacturing: some preliminary results. In: Brown M (ed) The theory and empirical analysis of production. Columbia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z, Mairesse J (1998) Production functions: the search for identification. In: Strom S (ed) Econometrics and economic theory in the twentieth century: the Ragnar Frisch Centennial Symposium. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 169–203

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hellerstein JK, Neumark D, Troske KR (1999) Wages, productivity, and worker characteristics: evidence from plant-level production functions and wage equations. J Labor Econ 17:409–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas P, Maliranta M (2005) Technology, worker characteristics, and wage-productivity gaps. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 67:623–645

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iranzo S, Schivardi F, Tosetti E (2007) Skill dispersion and productivity: an analysis with matched data. J Labor Econ 26:247–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ito T, Krueger AOE (1996) Financial deregulation and integration in East Asia. NBER-East Asia Seminar on economics, vol 5. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

  • Jona-Lasinio C, Iommi M (2011) Intangible and productivity growth in EU area. Mimeo. Innodrive project

  • Lev B, Radhakrishnan S (2005) The valuation of organisational capital. In: Corrado C, Haltiwanger J, Sichel D (eds) Measuring capital in the new economy. NBER studies in income and wealth 65. University Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 73–99

  • Levinsohn J, Petrin A (2003) Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Rev Econ Stud 70:317–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olley GS, Pakes A (1996) The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica 64:1263–1298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ouazad A (2008) A2REG: Stata module to estimate models with two fixed effects. Statistical software components S456942. Boston College, Department of Economics

  • Piekkola H (2010) Intangible capital: can it explain the unexplained? University of Vaasa Innodrive Working Paper No. 2. University of Vaasa, Vaasa

  • Piekkola H (2011) Intangible capital: the key to growth in Europe. Intereconomics 46:222–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2006) Where is the wealth of nations? Measuring capital for the 21st century. World Bank, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Yasar M, Raciborski R, Poi B (2008) Production function estimation in Stata using the Olley and Pakes method. Stata J 8:221–231

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This paper is part of the Innodrive project financed by the EU 7th Framework Program No. 214576. The project studied intangible capital using micro data from six countries. We would like to thank the three anonymous referees for their helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hannu Piekkola.

Appendices

Appendix 1: production function

We assume a constant-returns-to-scale production function in which labor input is quality adjusted:

$$Y = b_{0} (QL)^{{b_{1} }} K^{{b_{2} }} \exp (\varepsilon ) $$
(4)

where Y is the value added; QL is the quality-adjusted labor input (L is the total number of employees, and Q is the labor quality index); K is the net plant, property, and equipment; and ɛ is an error term. For the labor input, we separate the organizational (OC), R&D, and ICT workers, and the other workers serve as the reference group. Following the approach used by Griliches (1967) and Hellerstein et al. (1999) in another setting, the quality-adjusted labor input is written as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} QL &= a_{OC} OC + a_{RND} RND + a_{ICT} ICT + \left( {L - OC - RND - ICT} \right) \\ &= L\left[ {1 + \left( {a_{OC} - 1} \right)\frac{OC}{L} + \left( {a_{RND} - 1} \right)\frac{RND}{L} + \left( {a_{ICT} - 1} \right)\frac{ICT}{L}} \right] \\ \end{aligned} $$
(5)

where OC, RND, and ICT are the total number of organizational, R&D, and ICT workers, respectively, in each firm. We allow the productivity of OC, R&D, and ICT workers to vary from that of the other workers by the factors a OC , a RND , and a ICT , respectively. In logarithmic form, we can approximately write the following:

$$\ln \left[ {1 + \left( {a_{OC} - 1} \right)\frac{OC}{L} + \left( {a_{RND} - 1} \right)\frac{RND}{L} + \left( {a_{ICT} - 1} \right)\frac{ICT}{L}} \right] \approx \left( {a_{OC} - 1} \right)\frac{OC}{L} + \left( {a_{RND} - 1} \right)\frac{RND}{L} + \left( {a_{ICT} - 1} \right)\frac{ICT}{L} $$
(6)

because the second, third, and fourth terms in the brackets are not too far from zero. The reason for using the approximation (6) is that a functional form that is nonlinear in parameters and variables would not be compatible with the estimation approach (proxy variable estimation) that we use. Further, using a more general production function than the Cobb-Douglas form (4), such as the translog function, would also complicate the estimation, as the number of variables would increase.

The production function can be written in logarithmic form as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln Y &= c_{0} + c_{OC} \frac{OC}{L} + c_{RND} \frac{RND}{L} + c_{ICT} \frac{ICT}{L} \\ & \quad + \,b_{1} \ln L + b_{2} \ln K + \varepsilon \\ \end{aligned} $$
(7)

where c 0 = lnb 0, c OC  = b 1(1 − a OC ), c RND  = b 1(1 − a RND ), and c ICT  = b 1(1 − a ICT ). Equation (7) can now be expressed in terms of TFP as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln TFP &= c_{0} + c_{OC} \frac{OC}{L} + c_{RND} \frac{RND}{L} + c_{ICT} \frac{ICT}{L} + \varepsilon \\ &= c_{0} + c^{\prime } X + \varepsilon \\ \end{aligned} $$
(8)

where

$$\ln TFP = \ln Y - b_{1} \ln L - b_{2} \ln K $$
(9)

and where, in the right-hand side of (8), X = (OC/L, RND/L, ICT/L)′ is a vector of the ratios of the three types of employees to the total number of employees, and c is a vector of the respective productivity parameters (to be estimated subsequently). b 1 is proxied by wage costs per value added at the two-digit industry level, and b 2 = 1 − b 1.

If compensation for intangible capital is based on productivity, then the influence of the worker proportions should have the same effect on production and average wages. To analyze the wage effects, we estimate a model for the average wage W:

$$\begin{aligned} W &= f_{0} + f_{OC} \frac{OC}{L} + f_{RND} \frac{RND}{L} + f_{ICT} \frac{ICT}{L} + \varepsilon \\ &= f_{0} + f^{\prime } X + \varepsilon \\ \end{aligned} $$
(10)

In Eq. (7), we observe that ∂Y/∂(OC/L) ≈ c OC  = b 1(a OC  − 1), and in Eq. (8), we observe that ∂TFP/∂(OC/L) = c OC ; thus, we can analyze the productivity effect from the TFP equation. However, because we need to compare (a OC  − 1) to the coefficient of OC/L in the wage model (10), we must first divide the productivity model coefficient by the labor share coefficient b 1. The wage-productivity gap is then defined as follows:

$$gap_{OC} = (c_{OC} /b_{1} ) - f_{OC} $$
(11)

where f OC is the coefficient from the wage model (10). For R&D and ICT employees, the gaps are calculated in a similar manner. The total wage-productivity gap for a firm is defined as follows:

$$gap = (OC/L)gap_{OC} + (RND/L)gap_{RND} + (ICT/L)gap_{ICT} $$
(12)

The aggregate figures are calculated as firm size weighted averages.

Appendix 2: human capital

Human capital, lnHC it , is based on the firm average of the person effects obtained from the estimation of wage models for individuals with separate person and firm effects (see Abowd and Kramarz 2005). The wage regression includes only time-varying person characteristics as deviations from their means. The dependent variable is the log of the wage ln(w jit ) of person j working in firm i at time t, measured as a deviation from the individual mean, μ wj . This variable is expressed as a function of individual heterogeneity, firm heterogeneity, and measured time-varying characteristics in the following equation:

$${ \ln }\left( {w_{jit} } \right) - \mu_{wj} \, = \, \theta_{j} + \psi_{I(j,t)} \, + \beta^{\prime } \left( {x_{jt} - \mu_{xj} } \right) + e_{jit} $$
(13)

where θ j is the individual fixed effect (interpreted as time-invariant compensation for human capital) and ψ I(j,t) is the firm fixed effect (captures the unmeasured employer heterogeneity), where I(j, t) indicates the employer of j at date t. β′(x jt  − μ xj ) indicates the compensation for time-varying HC, which is stated as a deviation from the individual mean, and e jit is the error term. The time-variant variables x jt are experience (age minus years of education minus age when entering school) and seniority (duration in one’s job measured in years). Individual heterogeneity, which is captured by the person-specific fixed effect, includes the returns to education, and the remaining part of the person-specific fixed effect is the proportion of wages that cannot be explained by observed characteristics (to the econometrician). The firm-level HC variable is measured as the average of the θ j terms of the employees for each firm in each year. In their study, Abowd et al. (2002) develop a numerical solution to address a large set of firm dummies when evaluating both individual and firm fixed effects simultaneously. We use their method as applied to Stata by Ouazad (2008). The HC measure also includes abilities that are not reflected in education and work experience; thus, this measure provides a more valid indication of the abilities of less educated production workers (40 % of all employees in our data).

Appendix 3: occupational classifications of non-production workers

See Table 6.

Table 6 Occupational classifications

Appendix 4: descriptive statistics

See Tables 7 and 8.

Table 7 Variables in the productivity estimation
Table 8 Variables used for explaining productivity changes

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ilmakunnas, P., Piekkola, H. Intangible investment in people and productivity. J Prod Anal 41, 443–456 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-013-0348-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-013-0348-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation