Advertisement

Making index insurance attractive to farmers

  • Anthony Patt
  • Nicole Peterson
  • Michael Carter
  • Maria Velez
  • Ulrich Hess
  • Pablo Suarez
Original Article

Abstract

There are several factors that influence whether people will want to participate in index insurance programs. A number of these influence their attractiveness on economic grounds, including both the size and timing of the premium and potential payouts, and the degree of risk aversion of the potential customers. Other factors make programs attractive for reasons that are not economic, but no less valid. These have to do with the trust that people have in the insurance product and the organizations involved in selling and managing it. Indeed, data from India, Africa, and South America show that these factors may be more important than the economic ones in influencing demand. Index insurance pilot projects, in order to estimate demand for alternative products, have typically involved a great deal of interaction with potential customers. It is important to recognize that such interaction is crucial not just as a research tool, but also as a means to build understanding and trust in the products. When scaling up from isolated pilots to operational programs, it is vital to recognize this trust building function by replicating participation efforts in every community. In this paper, we examine the role of field games in establishing and building trust in three important aspects of these projects for participants: trust in the insurance product, trust in the participating organizations, and trust in their own ability to make good decisions. While games have previously been used as a way to gauge interest in the product and to identify design features, we argue that these games are also valuable tools for constructing these kinds of trust.

Keywords

Index insurance Smallholder farmers Role-playing games Climate variability Climate adaptation 

Notes

Acknowledgments

This paper resulted from the workshop Technical issues in index insurance, held in October 2008 at the International Research Institute for Climate and Society at Columbia University. Funding for several of the authors’ participation in the workshop came from the World Food Programme and International Fund for Agricultural Development, with support from the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation. We would like to thank Daniel Osgood and Molly Hellmuth for their organization of the workshop, and their comments on earlier drafts of this paper. Any remaining errors of fact or omission are those of the authors.

References

  1. Agrawal A, Gibson CC (1999) Enchantment and disenchantment: the role of community in natural resource conservation. World Dev 27(4):629CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Agrawal A, Gupta K (2005) Decentralization and participation: the governance of common pool resources in Nepal's Terai. World Dev 33:1104–1114CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Alderman H, Haque T (2007) Insurance against covariate shocks: the role of index-based insurance protection in low-income countries. The World Bank, WashingtonGoogle Scholar
  4. Argote L, Ingram P, Levine J, Moreland R (2000) Knowledge transfer in organizations: learning from the experience of others. Org Behav Human Decis Process 82(1):1–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Barnett BJ, Mahul O (2007) Weather index insurance for agriculture and rural areas in lower-income countries. Am J Agric Econ 89(5):1241–1247CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Bohnet I, Huck S (2004) Repetition and reputation: implications for trust and trustworthiness when institutions change. Am Econ Rev 94(2):362–366CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Bohnet I, Zeckhauser R (2004) Trust, risk and betrayal. J Econ Behav Organ 55(4):467–484CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Boko M et al (2007) Africa. In: Parry ML, Canziani OF, Palutikof J, van der Linden P, Hanson C (eds) Climate change 2007: Impacts, adaptation and vulnerability. Contribution of working group II to the fourth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge University, Cambridge, pp 433–467Google Scholar
  9. Bruine de Bruin W, Fischhoff B, Millstein S, Halpbern-Felscher B (2000) Verbal and numerical expressions of probability: “It’s a Fifty-Fifty Chance”. Org Behav Human Decis Process 81(1):115–131CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Camerer C (2001) Prospect theory in the wild: evidence from the field. In: Kahneman D, Tversky A (eds) Choices, values, and frames. Cambridge University, Cambridge, pp 288–300Google Scholar
  11. Carter MR et al. (2008) Insuring the never before insured: explaining index insurance through financial education games. BASIS Brief 2008-07.Google Scholar
  12. Cash D, Borck J, Patt AG (2006) Countering the 'loading dock' approach to linking science and decision making: a comparative analysis of ENSO forecasting systems. Sci Technol Human Values 31:465–494CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Churchill C (ed) (2006) Protecting the poor: a microinsurance compendium. International Labour Organization, Geneva, p 678Google Scholar
  14. Cleaver F (1999) Paradoxes of participation: questioning of particpatory approaches to development. J Int Dev 11:597–612CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Cohen M, Sebstad J (2006) The demand for microinsurance. In: Churchill C (ed) Protecting the poor: a microinsurance compendium. International Labour Organization, Geneva, pp 25–44Google Scholar
  16. Cook KS (ed) (2003) Trust in society. Russell Sage, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  17. Covello V (1990) Risk comparisons in risk communication: issues and problems in comparing health and environmental risks. In: Kasperson R, Stallen D (eds) Communicating risks to the public: international perspectives. Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht, pp 79–124Google Scholar
  18. Cropper M, Aydede S, Portney P (1994) Preferences for life savings programs: how the public discounts time and age. J Risk Uncertain 8:243–265CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Damasio A (1995) Decartes' error: emotion, reason, and the human brain. Bantam, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  20. Darr E, Kurtzberg T (2000) An investigation of partner similarity dimensions on knowledge transfer. Org Behav Human Decis Process 82(1):28–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Dercon S, Kirchberger M, Gunning J, Platteau J (2008) Literature review on microinsurance. International Labour Organization, GenevaGoogle Scholar
  22. Ditto P, Pizarro D, Epstein E, Jacobson J, MacDonald T (2006) Visceral influences on risk-taking behavior. J Behav Decis Mak 19:99–113CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Elster J (1998) Emotions and economic theory. J Econ Lit 36(1):47–74Google Scholar
  24. FAO (2000) Public Assistance and Agricultural Development in Africa, Twenty-first FAO regional conference for Africa, Yaounde, CameroonGoogle Scholar
  25. Fehr E, Gächter S (2002) Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415:137–140CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Frederick S, Loewenstein G, O'Donoghue T (2002) Time discounting and time preference: a critical review. J Econ Lit 40:351–401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Gigerenzer G (2000) Adaptive thinking: rationality in the real world. Oxford University, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  28. Gigerenzer G, Selten R (eds) (2001) Bounded rationality: the adaptive toolbox. MIT, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  29. Glantz M (2000) Once burned, twice shy? Lessons learned from the 1997-98 El Niño. UNEP/NCAR/UNU/WMO/ISDR, Tokyo, JapanGoogle Scholar
  30. Greig F, Bohnet I (2005) Is there reciprocity in a reciprocal-exchange economy? Evidence from a slum in Nairobi, Kenya. RWP05-044, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge, MassachusettsGoogle Scholar
  31. Grothmann T, Reusswig F (2006) People at risk of flooding: why some residents take precautionary action action while others do not. Nat Hazards 38(1-2):101–120CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Herrmann B, Thoni C, Gächter S (2008) Antisocial punishment across societies. Science 319(5868):1362–1367CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Hochrainer S, Mechler R, Pflug G (2009) Climate change and financial adaptation in Africa: investigating the impact of climate change on the robustness of micro-insurance in Malawi. Mitig Adapt Strategies Glob Chang 14(3):231–250CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. IRI (2005) Sustainable development in Africa: is the climate right? International Research Institute for Climate Prediction, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  35. Johnson EJ, Hershey J, Meszaros J, Kunreuther H (1993) Framing, probability distortions, and insurance decisions. J Risk Uncertain 7(1):35–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:263–291CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Kasperson JX, Kasperson R, Turner BLI (eds) (1995) Regions at risk: comparisons of threatened environments. United Nations University, TokyoGoogle Scholar
  38. Klopper E, Vogel C, Landman W (2006) Seasonal climate forecasts—potential agricultural-risk-management tools? Clim Change 76:73–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Kunreuther H (1996) Mitigating disaster losses through insurance. J Risk Uncertain 12(3):171–187CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Laibson D (1997) Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Q J Econ 112(2):443–478CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Laibson, D., Repetto, A. and Tobacman, J., 2004. Estimating discount functions from lifecycle consumption choices, Harvard University Department of Economics, Cambridge, MA, pp. 44 pages.Google Scholar
  42. Leftley R, Mapfumo S (2006) Effective microinsurance programs to reduce vulnerability, Opportunity International NetworkGoogle Scholar
  43. Lemos MC, Finan T, Fox R, Nelson D, Tucker J (2000) The use of seasonal climate forecasting in policy-making: lessons from northeast Brazil. University of Arizona, TusconGoogle Scholar
  44. Linnerooth-Bayer J, Mechler R, Pflug G (2005) Refocusing disaster aid. Science 309:1044–1046CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Loewenstein G, Elster J (1992) Choice over time. Russell Sage, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  46. Manuamorn O (2007) Scaling up micro-insurance: the case of weather insurance for smallholders in India. The World Bank, WashingtonGoogle Scholar
  47. McCord MJ (2001) Health care microinsurance: case studies from Uganda, Tanzania, India, and Cambodia. Small Enterp Dev 12(1):25–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Meze-Hausken E, Patt A, Fritz S (2009) Reducing climate risk for micro-insurance providers in Africa: a case study of Ethiopia. Glob Environ Change 19:66–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Munroe A, Sugden R (2003) On the theory of reference-dependent preferences. J Econ Behav Organ 50:407–428CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Nisbett R, Krantz D, Jepson D, Kunda Z (1983) The use of statistical heuristics in everyday inductive reading. Psychological Review 90:339–363CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Nisbett R, Ross L (1980) Human inferences: strategies and shortcomings of social judgment. Prentice Hall, New JerseyGoogle Scholar
  52. Osgood D, Warren D (2007) Drought insurance in Malawi. In: Hellmuth M, Moorhead A, Thomson MC, Williams J (eds) Climate risk management in Africa: learning from practice. International Research Institute for Climate and Society (IRI), Columbia University, New York, pp 75–88Google Scholar
  53. Patt AG (2007) Assessing model-based and conflict-based uncertainty. Global Environmental Change 17:37–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Patt AG, Bowles HR, Cash D (2006) Mechanisms for enhancing the credibility of an advisor: prepayment and aligned incentives. J Behav Decis Mak 19(4):347–359CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Patt AG, Ogallo L, Hellmuth M (2007) Learning from 10 years of Climate Outlook Forums in Africa. Science 318:49–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Patt AG, Suarez P, Gwata C (2005) Effects of seasonal climate forecasts and participatory workshops among subsistence farmers in Zimbabwe. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 102:12623–12628CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Payne JW, Bettman JR, Johnson EJ (1993) The adaptive decision maker. Cambridge University, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  58. Peters E, Västfjall D, Gärling T (2006) Affect and decision making: a "hot" topic. J Behav Decis Mak 19:79–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Phillips J, Orlove BS (2004) Improving climate forecast communication for farm management in Uganda. National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, WashingtonGoogle Scholar
  60. Prentice-Dunn S, Rogers RW (1986) Protection motivation theory and preventative health: beyond the health belief model. Health Educ Res 1:153–161CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Pretty J (1995) Participatory learning for sustainable agriculture. World Dev 23(8):1247–1263CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Roncoli C, Ingram K, Kirshen P (2001) The costs and risks of coping with drought: livelihood impacts and farmers' responses in Burkina Faso. Clim Res 19:119–132CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Samuelson W, Zeckhauser R (1988) Status quo bias in decision making. J Risk Uncertain 1:7–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Scoones I et al (1996) Hazards and opportunities: farming livelihoods in dryland Africa, lessons from Zimbabwe. Zed Books, LondonGoogle Scholar
  65. Simon H (1956) Rational choice and the structure of the environment. Psychol Rev 63:129–138CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Simon H (1991) Bounded rationality and organizational learning. Organizational Science 2(1):125–134CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Skees J, Hartell J, Murphy A (2007) Using index-based risk transfer products to facilitate micro-lending in Peru and Vietnam. Am J Agric Econ 89(5):1255–1261CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Sniezek J, Schrah GE, Dalal R (2004) Improving judgment with prepaid expert advice. J Behav Decis Mak 17:173–190CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Sniezek J, Van Swol L (2001) Trust, confidence, and expertise in a judge-advisor system. Org Behav Human Decis Processes 84(2):288–307CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Suarez P, Linnerooth-Bayer J, Mechler R (2007) Feasibility of risk financing schemes for climate adpatation: the case of Malawi. The World Bank, WashingtonGoogle Scholar
  71. Tversky A, Kahneman D (1973) Availability: a heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cogn Psychol 5:207–232CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Tversky A, Kahneman D (1974) Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science 211:1124–1131CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Tversky A, Kahneman D (1992) Advances in prospect theory, cumulative representation of uncertainty. J Risk Uncertain 5:297–323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Washington R et al (2006) African climate change: taking the shorter route. Bull Am Meteorol Soc 87(10):1355–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Weber E (1994) From subjective probabilities to decision weights: the effect of asymmetric loss functions on the evaluation of uncertain outcomes and events. Psychol Bull 115(2):228–242CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Weber E (2006) Experienced-based and description-based perceptions of long-term risk: why global warming does not scare us (yet). Clim Change 77:103–120CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. White P, et al. (2005) Disaster risk reduction: a development concern. A scoping study on links between disaster risk reduction, poverty and development, Department for International Development, London.Google Scholar
  78. World Bank (2005) Managing agricultural production risk: innovations in developing countries. World Bank Agriculture and Rural Development Department, WashingtonGoogle Scholar
  79. Wänke M, Schwarz N, Bless H (1995) The availability heuristic revisited: experienced ease of retrieval in mundane frequency estimates. Acta Psychologica 89(1):83–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media B.V. 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  • Anthony Patt
    • 1
  • Nicole Peterson
    • 2
  • Michael Carter
    • 3
  • Maria Velez
    • 4
  • Ulrich Hess
    • 5
  • Pablo Suarez
    • 6
  1. 1.International Institute for Applied Systems AnalysisLaxenburgAustria
  2. 2.Columbia UniversityNew YorkUSA
  3. 3.University of WisconsinMadisonUSA
  4. 4.Columbia UniversityNew YorkUSA
  5. 5.World Food ProgrammeRomeItaly
  6. 6.Red Cross Climate CentreThe HagueThe Netherlands

Personalised recommendations