Skip to main content
Log in

The rank, stock, order and epidemic effects of technology adoption: an empirical study of bounce protection programs

  • Published:
The Journal of Technology Transfer Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Karshenas and Stoneman (RAND J Econ 24(4):503–528, 1993) gathered four theories of technology adoption: the rank, stock, order and epidemic effects. Tests of these four effects reveal support for rank and epidemic but not the stock or order effects. Since then numerous other studies have tried to find evidence in support of the stock and order effects. But evidence has been elusive, until now. Further, a survey by Frame and White (J Econ Lit 42:116–144, 2004) concludes that much more work is needed into financial innovation. This paper accomplishes three goals: (1) evidence is found to support certain technology adoption theories (the order effects and possibly the stock effects), (2) since the technology under consideration is a financial innovation called bounce protection, the paper answers Frame and White’s call for papers, and (3) refinements are made to the Karshenas and Stoneman methodology and found to be superior to the original empirical model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Intuition behind the arbitrage condition is that banks time their adoption for maximum benefits. They balance a falling price of the technology against the cost of waiting to adopt. KS also consider a profit condition whereby banks adopt once the net present value of adoption is positive. KS test these two conditions and find the arbitrage condition to be a better predictor of adoption. Thus the arbitrage condition is used here.

  2. If data collection corresponds with the initial availability of the technology then we can think of these banks as being near point C when the technology is first available and should be observed adopting immediately. This will not change the hazard function math which follows.

References

  • Abdulai, A., & Huffman, W. E. (2005). The diffusion of new agricultural technologies: The case of crossbred-cow technology in Tanzania. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 87(3), 645–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bar-Ilan, A. (1990). Overdrafts and the demand for money. American Economic Review, 80(5), 1201–1216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartoloni, E., & Baussola, M. (2001). The determinants of technology adoption in Italian manufacturing industries. Review of Industrial Organization, 19(3), 305–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M. G., & Mosconi, R. (1995). Complementary and cumulative learning effects in the early diffusion of multiple technologies. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 43(1), 13–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David, P., & Olsen, T. (1992). Technology adoption, learning spillovers, and the optimal duration of patent-based monopolies. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10(4), 517–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies, S. (1979). The diffusion of process innovations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frame, S. W., & White, L. J. (2004). Empirical studies of financial innovation: Lots of talk, little action? Journal of Economic Literature, 42, 116–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1985). Preemption and rent equalization in the adoption of new technology. Review of Economic Studies, 52(170), 383–401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fusaro, M. A. (2003). Consumers’ bank choice and overdraft volume: A Structural Empirical Study of Bounce Protection Programs. Mimeo.

  • Fusaro, M. A. (2006). Consumers’ checking account behavior: Are ‘Bounced Check Loans’ Really Loans? Theory, Evidence and Policy. Mimeo.

  • Genesove, D. (1999). The Adoption of Offset Presses in the Daily Newspaper Industry in the United States. NBER Working Paper W7076.

  • Geroski, P. A. (2000). Models of technology diffusion. Research Policy, 29(4–5), 603–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gotz, G. (1999). Monopolistic competition and the diffusion of new technology. RAND Journal of Economics, 30(4), 679–693.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gouray, A., & Pentecost, E. (2002). The determinants of technology diffusion: Evidence from the UK financial sector. Manchester School, 70(2), 185–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hannan, T., & McDowell, J. (1987). Rival precedence and the dynamics of technology adoption: The case of the banking firm. Economica, 54(214), 155–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoppe, H. (2000). Second-mover advantages in the strategic adoption of new technology under uncertainty. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18(2), 315–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoppe, H. (2002). The timing of new technology adoption: Theoretical models and empirical evidence. Manchester School, 70(1), 56–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ireland, N., & Stoneman, P. (1985). Order effects, Perfect Foresight and Interterporal Price Discrimination. Recherches Economiques de Louvain, 51(1), 7–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ireland, N., & Stoneman, P. (1986). Technological diffusion, expectation and welfare. Oxford Economic Papers, 38(2), 283–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karshenas, M., & Stoneman, P. (1993). Rank, stock, order and epidemic effects in the diffusion of new process technologies: An empirical model. RAND Journal of Economics, 24(4), 503–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (1994). Peddling prosperity. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1968). Industrial research and technological innovation: An economic analysis. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1989). The diffusion of industrial robots in Japan and the United States. Research Policy, 18(4), 183–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Molyneux, P., & Shamroukh, N. (1996). Diffusion of financial innovations: The case of junk bonds and note issuance facilities. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 28(3), 502–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, J. G., & Llinares, E. (2003). Market segmentation and the diffusion of quality-enhancing innovations: The case of downhill skiing. Review of Economic and Statistics, 85(3), 493–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum, J. (1981). Market structure and the diffusion of new technology. Bell Journal of Economics, 12(2), 618–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riordan, M. (1992). Regulation and preemptive technology adoption. RAND Journal of Economics, 23(4), 334–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank Rob Porter, Shane Greenstein, Ron Braeutigam, Bill Rogerson, Nick Kreisle, Larry White, and an anonomous referee, for helpful comments and ideas.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marc Anthony Fusaro.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Fusaro, M.A. The rank, stock, order and epidemic effects of technology adoption: an empirical study of bounce protection programs. J Technol Transf 34, 24–42 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-007-9062-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-007-9062-y

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation