Advertisement

Journal of Bioeconomics

, Volume 16, Issue 1, pp 83–90 | Cite as

The diversity of institutional rules as engine of change

  • Claude Ménard
Article

Abstract

The target paper by Elinor Ostrom in this Special Issue carries a clear message about her research agenda: be attentive to institutional diversity, be aware of the danger of ‘monoculture’ and ‘monocropping’ of rules. Although Ostrom was fully aware of the necessity to focus on relevant and simplified variables in order to build general explanations, she deliberately adopted a bottom-up research strategy that opposes the top-down approach dominating social sciences. Her framework, developed through extensive field studies, shows the central role of “clusters” of rules in defining institutions and understanding how they change. My discussion is organized around this privilege conferred to rules. Section 2 posits her contribution, particularly her IAD model, in relation to New Institutional Economics. Section 3 focuses on what I consider her main contribution: her analysis of rules as the strategic point through which changes happen. Section 4 discusses some methodological issues, and Sect. 5 concludes.

Keywords

Institutions Rules New institutional economics  Methodology 

References

  1. Alchian, A. A. (1987). Property rights. In J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, & P. Newman (Eds.), The new Palgrave: A dictionary of economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1031–1034). London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
  2. Bardhan, P. K., & Dayton-Johnson, J. (2002). Unequal irrigators: Heterogeneity and commons management in large-scale multivariate research. In E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolšak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, & E. Weber (Eds.), The drama of the commons, National Research Council (pp. 87–112). Washington, DC: National Academies Press.Google Scholar
  3. Barzel, Y. (1989). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  4. Davis, L. E., & North, D. C. (1971). Institutional change and American economic growth. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Furubotn, E. G., & Richter, R. (1997). Institutions and economic theory. The contribution of the new institutional economics. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  6. Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, voice, and loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  7. MacLeod, W. B. (2013). On economics: A review of why nations fail by D. Acemoglu and J. Robinson and pillars of prosperity by T. Besley and T. Persson. Journal of Economic Literature, 50(1), 116–143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Ménard, C. (2009). Redesigning public utilities: The key role of micro-institutions. In J. Kornai, L. Mathyas, & G. Roland (Eds.), Corruption, development and institutional design (Chap. 10, pp. 189–202). London: Palgrave-MacMillan.Google Scholar
  9. Ménard, C., & Shirley, M. S. (2013). The contribution of Douglass North to new institutional economics. In S. Galliani & I. Sened (Eds.), Institutions, property rights and economic growth: The legacy of Douglass North (Chap. 1). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  10. North, D. C. (1990a). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. North, D. C. (1990b). A transaction cost theory of politics. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2(4), 355–367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Ostrom, E. (2013). Do institutions for collective action evolve? Journal of Bioeconomics. doi: 10.1007/s10818-013-9154-8.

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2013

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of Paris (Panthéon-Sorbonne)ParisFrance

Personalised recommendations