Skip to main content
Log in

Incentives to tax foreign investors

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper shows that a small country can have an incentive to tax inbound FDI even in a setting with perfect competition and free entry that is compatible with the Diamond–Mirrlees (Am Econ Rev 61(1):8–27, 1971) framework. While firms make no aggregate profits worldwide due to free entry in this setting, they make taxable profits in foreign production locations because their costs are partly incurred in their home countries. These profits are not perfectly mobile because firm productivity varies across locations. Consequently, the host country does not bear the entire burden of a tax on foreign firms, giving rise to an incentive to tax foreign investors. The standard zero optimal tax result can be recovered in this model under an apportionment system that ensures zero economic profits in each location.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also Dixit (1985), Razin and Sadka (1991) and Gordon and Hines (2002) for alternative formulations of this result.

  2. The compatibility of a heterogeneous firms setting featuring perfect competition and free entry with Diamond–Mirrlees has been noted by Dharmapala et al. (2011), who study optimal taxation with administrative costs in a closed economy.

  3. Several papers that study monopolistically competitive settings also have the property that households receive pure profits, either because of the absence of a free entry condition (e.g., Haufler and Stähler 2013) or due to a free entry condition that allows for such profits (e.g., Davies and Eckel 2010).

  4. Section 4.4 extends this analysis to the multi-country case.

  5. Note that there are no profits that enter into the household’s budget; the free entry condition that guarantees this will be discussed in Sect. 2.4.

  6. This differs from Helpman et al. (2004), where a firm draws a single productivity parameter for both countries. Hence, in their framework, differences in profitability across locations are due to aggregate factors such as wages or market sizes, whereas in the current paper, firms will also have idiosyncratic differences in profitability across locations.

  7. What is essential for the main result in the paper is that firms receive some signal of their productivity in both countries before choosing where to produce. The main result would still hold if there is some additional uncertainty that is only resolved following location choice.

  8. In this setting, each firm will only produce in one location. The most natural way of accommodating firms that produce in multiple locations within this framework would be to follow some of the heterogeneous firms literature in international trade in interpreting the basic unit of production as a “project” rather than a “firm” so that multiple projects can be thought of as nested within a firm.

  9. See Dharmapala et al. (2011) for more on the connection between this type of setup and Diamond–Mirrlees.

  10. A more formal justification for this small country equilibrium can be obtained by assuming that \(L_{1}=\epsilon L_{2}\) and \(K_{1}=\epsilon K_{2}\) and considering what happens as \(\epsilon \rightarrow 0\). This argument is presented in Appendix A.2.

  11. More broadly, these small country results would also hold qualitatively for a country that is not technically a small country but is sufficiently small so as to have a relatively limited effect on foreign prices and the foreign mass of entrants.

  12. The positive optimal tax result, however, would still hold even with multiple immobile factors.

  13. See Davies and Gresik (2003) for a more extensive discussion of the conditions under which factor prices will be fixed with respect to tax rate changes, and the implications of this for tax policy.

  14. Formally, this is because the unit normal vectors point in opposite directions (i.e., \(u_{1}=-\,u_{2}\)).

  15. Note also that this proof holds even if the measure of country 1 firms locating at home was zero, so that \(\intop _{\Theta _{11}}l_{11}\left( w_{1},r,z_{1} \right) g(z)\hbox {d}z=0\). This is because domestic entry is always connected to domestic labor since a portion of the fixed entry costs is paid in terms of labor.

  16. A more detailed analysis of the implicit apportionment system would require an examination of the royalty regime that is in place, since royalties often serve as a means of apportioning profits across countries. Such an analysis would be beyond the scope of the current paper.

  17. If country 1 firms all located in their home country, the profits net of all fixed costs would be equal to zero. This means that if fixed costs were deductible, no tax revenue could be raised on domestic firms. Since some firms locate abroad and so are not subject to domestic taxation, the net profits at home after fixed costs will actually be negative. Since the purpose of this extension is to consider what happens when domestic firms are subject to actual taxation, I assume that the fixed costs are not deductible.

  18. The case with domestic firms also in operation (Case II in Sect. 3.2) is identical to Sect. 3.2 since the factor price insensitivity still holds and so the host country would again have an incentive to maximize revenue.

  19. As with the two-country case, we can more formally justify the small country concept here by assuming \(L_{i}=\epsilon \sum _{j\ne i}L_{j}\) and \(K_{i}=\epsilon \sum _{j\ne i}K_{j}\) and considering the equilibrium as \(\epsilon \rightarrow 0\). The formal argument would then be of essentially the same nature as the one presented for two countries in Appendix A.2, i.e., that as \(\epsilon \rightarrow 0\), the wage in each foreign country, the mass of entrants in each foreign country and the factor price for capital would be determined by foreign equilibrium conditions that hold independently of any country i variables. As in the two-country case, the results derived here would again be qualitatively true of a country that is not technically a small country but is sufficiently small so as to have a limited effect on foreign variables.

  20. Note that owing to Walras’ Law, we could have equivalently used the goods market clearing condition, (2.3), which also becomes independent of country 1 variables as \(\epsilon \rightarrow 0\), in place of either the capital market clearing condition or country 2’s labor market clearing condition.

References

  • Bauer, C., Davies, R. B., & Haufler, A. (2014). Economic integration and the optimal corporate tax structure with heterogeneous firms. Journal of Public Economics, 110, 42–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burbidge, J., Cuff, K., & Leach, J. (2006). Tax competition with heterogeneous firms. Journal of Public Economics, 90(3), 533–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chor, D. (2009). Subsidies for FDI: Implications from a model with heterogeneous firms. Journal of International Economics, 78(1), 113–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies, R. B., & Eckel, C. (2010). Tax competition for heterogeneous firms with endogenous entry. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2(1), 77–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davies, R. B., & Gresik, T. A. (2003). Tax competition and foreign capital. International Tax and Public Finance, 10(2), 127–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demidova, S., & Rodriguez-Clare, A. (2009). Trade policy under firm-level heterogeneity in a small economy. Journal of International Economics, 78(1), 100–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demidova, S., & Rodriguez-Clare, A. (2013). The simple analytics of the melitz model in a small economy. Journal of International Economics, 90(2), 266–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dharmapala, D., Slemrod, J., & Wilson, J. D. (2011). Tax policy and the missing middle: Optimal tax remittance with firm-level administrative costs. Journal of Public Economics, 95(9), 1036–1047.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production I: Production efficiency. American Economic Review, 61(1), 8–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1985). Tax policy in open economies. Handbook of Public Economics, 1, 313–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. H. (1986). Taxation of investment and savings in a world economy. American Economic Review, 76(5), 1086–1102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. H., & Hines, J. R. (2002). International taxation. Handbook of Public Economics, 4l, 1935–1995.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haufler, A., & Stähler, F. (2013). Tax competition in a simple model with heterogeneous firms: How larger markets reduce profit taxes. International Economic Review, 54(2), 665–692.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., Melitz, M. J., & Yeaple, S. R. (2004). Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review, 94(1), 300–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopenhayn, H. A. (1992). Entry, exit, and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica, 60(5), 1127–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huizinga, H., & Nielsen, S. B. (1997). Capital income and profit taxation with foreign ownership of firms. Journal of International Economics, 42(1), 149–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M., & Lahiri, S. (1998). The comparison between destination and origin principles under imperfect competition. Journal of International Economics, 45(2), 323–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1978). On the size distribution of business firms. The Bell Journal of Economics, 9(2), 508–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Razin, A., & Sadka, E. (1991). Efficient investment incentives in the presence of capital flight. Journal of International Economics, 31(1), 171–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharma, R. R. (2017). Taxing and subsidizing foreign investors. FinanzArchiv: Public Finance Analysis, 73(4), 402–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am very grateful to Alan Deardorff, Jim Hines, Joel Slemrod, Kyle Handley, Dominick Bartelme, Javier Cravino, Andrei Levchenko, Sebastian Sotelo and Ugo Troiano for useful comments and discussion of this work. I also thank the editor (Ron Davies) and an anonymous referee for suggestions that have substantially improved the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rishi R. Sharma.

A Proofs

A Proofs

1.1 A.1 Profit Function Property

In this appendix, I show that we can write the pre-tax profit function (excluding fixed costs) in the following separable form: \(\pi _{ij}(w_{i},r,\tilde{z}_{i})=\tilde{z}_{i}^{1/(1-\lambda )} \pi _{ij}\left( w_{i},r\right) \). First, note that from the homogeneity of the production function, we can use Euler’s rule to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ F_{l}(.)l+F_{k}(.)k\right] =\lambda F(.), \end{aligned}$$

where\(\lambda <1\) is the returns to scale parameter. The first-order conditions are: \(\tilde{z}_{i}F_{l}\left( l^{*},k^{*}\right) =w_{i}\) and \(\tilde{z}_{i}F_{k}\left( l^{*},k^{*}\right) =r\), where \(l^{*}\) and \(k^{*}\) are the optimal choices of l and k, respectively. Using the first-order condition, the firm’s profits (excluding fixed costs) before taxes are:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{ij}(w_{i},r,\tilde{z}_{i})= & {} \tilde{z}_{i}F(.) -\tilde{z}_{i}F_{l}(.)l^{*}-\tilde{z}_{i}F_{k}(.)k^{*}\\= & {} \tilde{z}_{i}F(.)-\lambda \tilde{z}_{i}F(.)\\= & {} \tilde{z}_{i}\left( 1-\lambda \right) F(.) \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the firm’s profits (excluding fixed costs) are proportional to its sales. Next, we can differentiate maximized profits, \(\tilde{z}_{i}F(.)-wl-rk\), with respect to \(\tilde{z}_{i}\) using the envelope theorem to get:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\hbox {d}\pi _{ij}(.)}{\hbox {d}\tilde{z_{i}}}\frac{\tilde{z}_{i}}{\pi _{ij}(.)}= & {} F\left( .\right) \frac{\tilde{z}_{i}}{\pi _{ij}(.)}\\ \frac{\hbox {d}\pi _{ij}(.)}{\hbox {d}\tilde{z_{i}}}\frac{\tilde{z}_{i}}{\pi _{ij}(.)}= & {} F\left( .\right) \frac{\tilde{z}_{i}}{\tilde{z}_{i} \left( 1-\lambda \right) F(.)}\\ \frac{\hbox {d}\pi _{ij}(.)}{\hbox {d}\tilde{z_{i}}}\frac{\tilde{z}_{i}}{\pi _{ij}(.)}= & {} \frac{1}{1-\lambda } \end{aligned}$$

The above expression is a separable differential equation and can be solved as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{\pi _{ij}(.)}\hbox {d}\pi _{ij}(.)= & {} \frac{1}{1-\lambda } \frac{1}{\tilde{z}_{i}}\hbox {d}\tilde{z}_{i}\\ \intop \frac{1}{\pi _{ij}(.)}\hbox {d}\pi _{ij}(.)= & {} \frac{1}{1-\lambda } \intop \frac{1}{\tilde{z_{i}}}\hbox {d}\tilde{z_{i}}\\ \log \pi _{ij}(.)= & {} \frac{1}{1-\lambda }\log \tilde{z}_{i}+c\\ \log \pi _{ij}(.)= & {} \log \tilde{z}{}_{i}^{1/(1-\lambda )}e^{c}\\ \pi _{ij}(w_{i},r,\tilde{z}_{i})= & {} \tilde{z}{}_{i}^{1/(1-\lambda )}e^{c}, \end{aligned}$$

where c is a constant of integration. In order to solve for the constant \(e^{c}\), we can set \(\tilde{z}_{i}\) equal to 1 (an arbitrary choice) to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{ij}(w_{i},r,1)=e^{c} \end{aligned}$$

If we define \(\pi _{ij}\left( w_{i},r\right) \equiv \pi _{ij} (w_{i},r,1)\), then the profits of an individual firm can be expressed as being proportional to a general term that is common to all firms: \(\pi _{ij}(w_{i},r,\tilde{z}_{i})=\tilde{z}_{i}^{1/ (1-\lambda )}\pi _{ij}\left( w_{i},r\right) \).

1.2 A.2 Small country assumption

This appendix elaborates on the small country assumption introduced in Sect. 3.1. Given \(L_{1}=\epsilon L_{2}\) and \(K_{1}=\epsilon K_{2}\), the small country assumption captures the equilibrium as \(\epsilon \rightarrow 0\). First, note that as \(\epsilon \) approaches zero, the mass of entrants in country 1, \(m_{1}\), must also approach zero. This is because a part of the fixed costs that enable entry is paid in terms of labor—specifically, the part captured by the fixed cost \(f_{1}\)—and so as \(L_{1}\) approaches zero, the portion of country 1 labor used to pay these entry costs must also go to zero. Second, the equilibrium measure of country 2 firms that site in country 1 must also approach zero so that \(\Theta _{22}\rightarrow U\), where U is defined as the set of all country 2 firms. This is because otherwise, labor demand, which is the right-hand side of (2.4), would not go to zero for country 1 even as the labor supply, \(L_{1}\) does.

With these two points in mind, the labor market clearing condition for country 2, (2.4), the capital market clearing condition, (2.5), and the domestic entry condition for country 2, (2.2), become independent of the terms that depend on \(\Theta _{12}\) and \(m_{1}\) and, respectively, take the following forms:

$$\begin{aligned}&L_{2}=m_{2}\intop _{U}l_{22}\left( w_{2},r,z_{2}\right) g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z+m_{2}f_{2}\\&K_{2}=m_{2}\intop _{U}k_{22}\left( w_{2},r,z_{2}\right) g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z+m_{2}\phi _{2}\\&\intop _{U}z_{2}\pi _{22}\left( w_{2},r\right) g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z =f_{2}w_{2}+\phi _{2}r \end{aligned}$$

Intuitively, as country 1’s size become negligible, country 1 variables cease to effect country 2’s labor market and domestic entry conditions as well as the global market clearing condition for capital. These three conditions now determine \(w_{2}\), r and \(m_{2}\), which are therefore independent of country 1’s policies.Footnote 20 Hence, we can think of the small country assumption made in this paper as capturing the limiting equilibrium as country 1’s share of labor and capital become small.

1.3 A.3 Proof of \(\hbox {d}R_{12}/\hbox {d}\tau _{1}<0\)

This appendix proves that \(\hbox {d}R_{12}/\hbox {d}\tau _{1}<0\), which, as discussed in the main text, will imply that the optimal tax is positive. To see this, we can start with the definition of inframarginal profits:

$$\begin{aligned} R_{12}=m_{2}\intop _{\Theta _{12}}\left[ \left( 1-\tau _{1}\right) z_{1}\pi _{12}\left( w_{1},r\right) -z_{2}\pi _{22}\left( w_{2},r\right) \right] g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating this term, we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\hbox {d}R_{12}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{1}}=m_{2}\intop _{\Theta _{12}}\left\{ z_{1} \frac{\left[ d\left( 1-\tau _{1}\right) \pi _{12}\left( w_{1},r\right) \right] }{\hbox {d}\tau _{1}}\right\} g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z \end{aligned}$$

When differentiating this term, we are again using the fact that firms on the boundary set make no inframarginal profits and so the derivative of the integral is simply the integral of the derivative. A firm that is on the boundary set, i.e., \(z\in \partial \Theta _{12}\), will be indifferent between locating in country 1 and country 2:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1-\tau _{1}\right) z_{1}\pi _{12}\left( w_{1},r\right)= & {} z_{2}\pi _{22}\left( w_{2},r\right) \nonumber \\ \left( 1-\tau _{1}\right) \pi _{12}\left( w_{1},r\right)= & {} a_{12}\pi _{22}\left( w_{2},r\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

where \(a_{12}\) is the cutoff value of \(z_{2}/z_{1}\) that defines the indifferent firms. For later use, note that (A.1) implies a function \(a_{12}=\gamma \left( w_{1},\tau _{1}\right) \), with \(\partial \gamma /\partial w_{1}<0\) and \(\partial \gamma /\partial \tau _{1}<0\).

Differentiating (A.1), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\hbox {d}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{1}}\left[ \left( 1-\tau _{1}\right) \pi _{12} \left( w_{1},r\right) \right] =\frac{\hbox {d}a_{12}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{1}} \pi _{22}\left( w_{2},r\right) \end{aligned}$$

Thus:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\hbox {d}R_{12}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{1}}= & {} m_{2}\intop _{\Theta _{12}} \left\{ z_{1}\frac{\left[ d\left( 1-\tau _{1}\right) \pi _{12} \left( w_{1},r\right) \right] }{\hbox {d}\tau _{1}}\right\} g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z\\= & {} m_{2}\frac{\left[ d\left( 1-\tau _{1}\right) \pi _{12} \left( w_{1},r\right) \right] }{\hbox {d}\tau _{1}} \intop _{\Theta _{12}}z_{1}g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z\\= & {} m_{2}\left[ \frac{\hbox {d}a_{12}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{1}}\pi _{22} \left( w_{2},r\right) \right] \intop _{\Theta _{12}}z_{1}g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z\\= & {} \frac{\hbox {d}a_{12}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{1}}\times m_{2}\intop _{\Theta _{12}} \left[ z_{1}\pi _{22}\left( w_{2},r\right) \right] g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z \end{aligned}$$

Hence, the sign of \(\hbox {d}R_{12}/\hbox {d}\tau _{1}\) will be the same as the sign of \(\hbox {d}a_{12}/\hbox {d}\tau _{1}\). Since higher taxes will cause firms to leave country 1, it follows that the new marginal firm will be one that is relatively more productive in country 1, i.e., \(\hbox {d}a_{12}/\hbox {d}\tau _{1}<0\). To show this formally, we need to use the labor market clearing condition.

With no domestic firms, the labor market clearing condition can be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} L_{1}= & {} m_{2}\intop _{\Theta _{12}}l_{12} \left( w_{1},r,z_{1}\right) g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z\\= & {} m_{2}\intop _{0}^{z_{1}^{\max }}\intop _{0}^{a_{12}z_{1}}l_{12} \left( w_{1},r,z_{1}\right) g_{2}(z)\hbox {d}z_{2}\hbox {d}z_{1}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(z_{1}^{\max }\) is the upper-bound on productivity for \(z_{1}\). The right-hand side above is decreasing in \(w_{1}\) and increasing in \(a_{12}\). Thus, this expression defines a positive relationship between \(w_{1}\) and \(a_{12}\). Intuitively, at a fixed wage, the presence of more firms means that labor supply exceeds labor demand, necessitating an increase in the wage to restore equilibrium. We can express this relationship as a function: \(a_{12}=\delta (w_{1})\) with \(\partial \delta /\partial w_{1}>0\). Note that \(\delta \left( .\right) \) , unlike \(\gamma \left( .\right) \), does not depend on \(\tau \) because \(\tau \) does not directly enter into the labor market clearing condition. Of course, \(a_{12}\) and \(w_{1}\) do both depend on \(\tau \) in equilibrium because \(\tau \) enters into \(\gamma \left( .\right) \) and it is \(\gamma \left( .\right) \) and \(\delta \left( .\right) \) that together determine the equilibrium values for \(a_{12}\) and \(w_{1}\).

This\(\delta \left( w_{1}\right) \)function together with \(\gamma (w_{1},\tau _{1})\) defined earlier implies that an increase in \(\tau _{1}\) will shift down \(\gamma (.)\) and cause a movement along \(\delta (.)\) corresponding to a lower wage. Consequently, \(\hbox {d}w_{1}/\hbox {d}\tau _{1}<0\) and \(\hbox {d}a_{12}/\hbox {d}\tau _{1}<0\).

1.4 A.4 Positive optimal tax in the multiple country case

This appendix shows that the optimal tax rate is positive in the multiple country case, assuming that there are no domestic firms in operation. The steps followed are substantially identical to those in Appendix A.3. When there are domestic firms, the argument is identical to the one made in the text in Sect. 3.2.2.

$$\begin{aligned} \tau _{i} = \frac{\hbox {d}R_{iF}/\hbox {d}\tau _{i}}{\frac{\hbox {d}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{i}} (1-\tau _{i})\Pi _{iF}} \end{aligned}$$

Note that the derivative of inframarginal profits with respect to the tax rate is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\hbox {d}R_{iF}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{i}}=\sum _{j\ne i}m_{j} \intop _{\Theta _{ij}}\left[ z_{i}\frac{d\left( 1-\tau _{i}\right) \pi _{ij}\left( w_{i},r\right) }{\hbox {d}\tau _{i}}\right] g_{j}(z)\hbox {d}z \end{aligned}$$

The sign of the \(d\left( 1-\tau _{i}\right) \pi _{ij}\left( w_{i}, r\right) /\hbox {d}\tau _{i}\) term thus determines the sign of \(\hbox {d}R_{iF}/\hbox {d}\tau _{i}\). A firm that is on the boundary, i.e., \(z\in \partial \Theta _{ij}\), will be indifferent between locating in i and locating in some country h:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1-\tau _{i}\right) z_{i}\pi _{ij}\left( w_{i},r\right)= & {} \left( 1-\tau _{hj}\right) z_{h}\pi _{hj}\left( w_{h},r\right) \nonumber \\ \left( 1-\tau _{i}\right) \pi _{ij}\left( w_{i},r\right)= & {} \left( 1-\tau _{hj}\right) a_{ihj}\pi _{hj} \left( w_{h},r\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

where \(a_{ihj}\) the cutoff value of \(z_{h}/z_{i}\) for a firm from j that is indifferent between locating in h and i. We will have a maximum of \(C-1\times C-1\) such conditions. Subtracting the right-hand side of (A.2) from both sides, we have an equation \(\psi _{ihj}\left( a_{ihj},w_{i},\tau _{i}\right) =0\) such that \(\psi _{1}<0\), \(\psi _{2}<0\) and \(\psi _{3}<0\).

The labor market clearing condition, in notation using \(a_{ihj}\) instead of \(\Theta _{ij}\), and denoting country i as country 1—without loss of generality—is the following:

$$\begin{aligned} L_{i}=\sum _{j\ne i}m_{j}\intop _{0}^{z_{1}^{\max }} \intop _{0}^{a_{12j}z_{1}}\ldots \intop _{0}^{a_{1Cj}z_{1}}l_{ij} \left( w_{i},r,z_{i}\right) g_{j}(z)\hbox {d}z, \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

where \(z_{1}^{\max }\) is the upper-bound on productivity for \(z_{1}\). The labor market clearing condition defines an equation \(\Psi (a,w_{i})=0\)—where a is a vector of \(a_{ihj}\)—such that \(\Psi (.)\) is decreasing in each \(a_{ihj}\) and increasing in \(w_{i}\). An small increase in \(\tau _{i}\) will increase the value of \(a_{ihj}\) for a given \(w_{i}\). This corresponds to a movement along the (A.3) curve toward a higher \(a_{ihj}\) and lower \(w_{i}\). This is intuitive: an increase in \(\tau _{i}\) leads to fewer firms (i.e., a higher \(a_{ihj}\)) and a lower wage.

Differentiating both sides of (A.2), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\hbox {d}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{i}}\left( 1-\tau _{i}\right) \pi _{ij} \left( w_{i},r\right) =\frac{\hbox {d}a_{ihj}}{\hbox {d}\tau _{i}} \left( 1-\tau _{h}\right) \pi _{hj}\left( w_{h},r\right) <0 \end{aligned}$$

Thus, \(\hbox {d}R_{iF}/\hbox {d}\tau _{i}<0\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sharma, R.R. Incentives to tax foreign investors. Int Tax Public Finance 26, 257–281 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9506-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9506-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation