1 Introduction

The single market of the European Union (EU) should enable businesses to source anywhere, produce anywhere and sell anywhere without being hampered by double taxation and tax discrimination issues arising under the corporation taxes (CTs) of the Member States (European Commission 2015). At the same time, harmful tax competition between the Member States, which would jeopardize revenue collections, should be avoided. With this in mind, the European Commission has made various proposals for aligning the CTs in the EU to remove tax obstacles for companies operating on an EU-wide basis. Following the publication of a number of expert reports—Neumark Committee (1962), Van den Tempel (1970) and Ruding Committee (1992)—and the issue of a Code of Conduct (European Commission 1998), the European Commission (2001) proposed a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB) for European companies. The common base would be allocated to participating Member States which could then apply their own CT rate, an approach known as formulary apportionment (FA).

Neither the various reports nor the CCCTB proposal actually left the drawing board.Footnote 1 Yet, some approximation or coordination of the CTs within the EU remains attractive, because it would reduce compliance costs for corporations established in more than one Member State, eliminate various forms of tax arbitrage, enable cross-border loss offsets and business restructuring, and, more generally, reduce tax-induced distortions of the intra-EU allocation of capital. The European Commission, along with the Member States, believes that these objectives should be achieved by strengthening source-based taxation of corporate income.

This paper surveys and evaluates the corporation tax systems of the Member States of the European Union on the basis of a comprehensive taxonomy of actual and potential regimes, which have as their base either profits; profits, interest and royalties; or economic rents. In doing so, it should be borne in mind that the need for CT coordination in the EU should be examined in light of the basic principles—neutrality and subsidiarity—that govern the tax relationships between the Member States (Cnossen and Bovenberg 1997). The leitmotiv of the Treaty of Rome (1957) is that the single market should ensure an efficient allocation of resources. Hence, unless expressly stipulated otherwise, CT regimes should affect saving and investment decisions as little as possible. The treaty’s implicit neutrality criterion implies that the effective tax rate [CT and personal income tax (PT)] on various forms of capital income, such as retained profits, dividends and interest, should be approximately the same across Member States.

By contrast, the Treaty of Maastricht (1992) enshrined subsidiarity as the guiding principle in the discussion on the assignment of policy functions in the EU. Subsidiarity proceeds from a presumption in favor of decentralization.Footnote 2 Basically, policy functions, including taxation, should be exercised by the Member States, although the states are obliged to consider the effects of their actions (spillovers) on other Member States. While tax neutrality appears to require a substantial degree of tax harmonization, subsidiarity implies that each Member State should be permitted as much tax sovereignty as is commensurate with the goals of free trade and free competition in the single internal market. In other words, tax systems should require little concerted coordination, except perhaps on basic design principles.Footnote 3

To set the stage for the review and the subsequent discussion of reform options, Sect. 2 develops a taxonomy of CT regimes and briefly reviews revenue developments. Against this background, Sect. 3 proceeds to examine the actual CT regimes of the Member States and attempts to distill some basic findings. Next, Sect. 4 reviews various directions for CT reform and coordination. Section 5 outlines the preferred choice and concludes.

2 Background

Corporate source income can be defined in three ways: (1) equity income (profits), (2) capital income (profits, interest and royalties) and (3) economic rents (above-normal returns). The various taxes that these bases permit are summed up below. Feasible options for reform often depend on the revenue consequences. Hence, corporate tax yields are also reviewed.

2.1 Taxonomy of corporation tax regimes

CTs in the EU are based on the OECD Model Convention with respect to Taxes on Income and on Capital (OECD 2010), which draws on the blueprint agreed to by the League of Nations in the 1920s. As befits their pedigree, the original CTs were largely designed for economies in which cross-border capital transactions were the exception rather than the rule, in which debt could be distinguished clearly from equity, and in which shareholders were natural persons generally residing in the country in which the corporation had been established. In such economies, CTs were meant to be a schedular tax on the equity income of shareholders, that is, profits. Interest was deductible in ascertaining profits and was meant to be taxed in the hands of debt holders.

But globalization and capital market liberalization and innovation have turned this traditional CT model on its head. Debt has become largely indistinguishable from equity through the use of financial derivatives and hybrid instruments. Unlike equity income, interest is not taxed at the corporate level and may not be taxed at all if it accrues to foreign debt holders or exempt entities. This has led to concerns with revenue erosion and the “debt bias,” which can increase the bankruptcy risk of corporations.Footnote 4 The discrepancy in the tax treatment of returns that are largely identical suggests that equity income and interest should be taxed alike at the level of the corporation (De Mooij 2012).

Equity income differs from interest, however, to the extent that it consists of a normal rate of return (in other words, the opportunity cost of an investment, comparable to interest) and an above-normal rate of return or economic rent. The normal or hurdle rate of return is required to make the corporation’s marginal investment just worthwhile. The CT reduces this return and, hence, affects the level of investment and, possibly, economic growth. If this is to be avoided, the normal rate of return should not be taxed and neither should interest (to the extent that it equates the normal return). By contrast, the above-normal return can be taxed without influencing the level of investment, because it can be attributed to advantages, such as favorable head starts, patents, inventions, or some form of natural monopoly—in other words, entrepreneurial advantages not enjoyed by competitors. Generally, the taxation of these advantages does not affect behavior, but the location of the underlying intangibles in, say, low-tax countries has implications for revenue collection.

Apart from the tax treatment of the returns on equity, debt and intangibles at the corporate level, there is the interaction of the CT with the PT imposed on residual income, whether dividends, interest or capital gains. Retained profits are taxed by the CT, dividend and interest under the PT. Capital gains arise if profits are retained in the corporation, which pari passu increases the value of the corporation’s shares. Taxing dividends and capital gains (except if in the nature of windfall gains) at shareholder level involves double taxation, which may not be desirable, particularly if they reflect the normal rate of return.

On this basis, three kinds of CT regimes can be distinguished whose features and modalities are summed up in Table 1; they have been amply discussed in the tax literature.Footnote 5

Table 1 Options for taxing corporate source income
  • Conventional CT regimes (classical systems) that take equity income or profits as their base and that permit a deduction for interest paid on debt. Double taxation of profit distributions can be mitigated through dividend relief systems and by applying reduced PT rates on capital gains. Double taxation would be fully avoided if corporate profits would be allocated to shareholders proportionate to their shareholdings under a full integration system, called piercing the corporate veil.Footnote 6

  • CT regimes that tax profits, interest and royalties (jointly called capital income) at the level of the corporation under a dual income tax (DIT) that purports to tax all capital income, corporate and personal, once at a uniform rate. Alternatively, interest and royalties, like dividends, are not allowed as a deduction from profits and are not taxed at recipient level under a comprehensive business income tax (CBIT). Disallowing interest and royalty deductibility under the CBIT is equivalent to imposing final withholding taxes on interest and royalties at the corporate level under the DIT at rates equal to the CT rate.

  • CT regimes, called cash flow taxes, whose base is confined to above-normal returns by permitting the immediate expensing of business assets while clawing back interest and royalties, or by allowing a deduction from profits of the normal return on equity (as well as interest), referred to as allowance for corporate equity (ACE)—an allowance that can be extended to non-corporate capital income through a rate of return allowance (RRA).Footnote 7 But for the extension, these forms of taxing economic rents are identical, if it is assumed that the value of corporate assets represents the discounted value of all their future earnings at the normal rate of return. Note that economic rents equal the business cash flow component of the value added tax (VAT), which can be derived by deducting wages from the difference between sales and purchases (including investment goods), which represents value added.

The table does not show the tax treatment of cross-border flows of corporate source income. Profits (also called active income) are usually taxed in the source country (that is, the country in which corporations carry on their business), while residual income (referred to as passive income) tends to be taxed in the residence country (that is, the country in which the corporation’s shareholders, be it individuals or other (holding) companies, reside). The issues are touched upon in Sect. 3.6.

2.2 Trends in corporation tax rates and revenues

Prima facie, the source-based nature of CTs should induce tax rate competition between Member States, which has been called “a race to the bottom.”Footnote 8 As shown in Fig. 1, following the liberalization of capital markets in the early 1990s, the simple average CT rate declined by 12%-points or about one-third, from on average 35% in 1996 to 23% in 2014. By contrast, CT ratios (revenues as a percentage of GDP) hardly declined. Since 1996, the arithmetical average ratio for 28 Member States dropped from 2.8 to 2.5% in 2014.Footnote 9 Revenue even peaked around 2007, although rates had already been lowered to around their current level. Apparently, the statutory rate reductions were offset by base broadening measures (for instance, reduced depreciation allowances), increased incorporation of firms (shifting income from PTs to CTs) and an increase in the profitability of the corporate sector (Griffith and Miller 2014).Footnote 10 Individual country CT ratios differ widely, ranging from 1.4% in Hungary, Lithuania and Slovenia to 6.4% in Cyprus, a tax haven country (European Commission 2016b).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source: European Commission (2016b). Calculations are based on simple arithmetic averages

European Union: trends in corporation tax rates and ratios 1995–2014.

Obviously, effective CT rates (and consequently revenues) are the product of nominal rates and tax bases. Although economic theory prescribes that corporate profits should be calculated on an accretion basis,Footnote 11 in practice taxable profits are determined on the basis of International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS), which is the European-wide rule since 2005 for corporations listed on EU stock exchanges. The accounting principles prescribe that revenues and costs should be matched on an annual basis under the accrual system of accounting. The costs of raw materials, intermediate products and wages, as well as expenses, including interest, are deductible if incurred in earning taxable profits and in maintaining the assets used in the corporation’s activities. Potential losses are taken into account in computing taxable profits, but accrued capital gains are not taxed until they are realized.

Further, in all Member States the tax base is reduced by a variety of tax incentives (provisions that provide special treatment to qualified investment projects not available to investment projects in general) primarily to promote entrepreneurship and stimulate innovation. The incentives take the form of tax holidays and reduced rates, accelerated investment recovery allowances and tax credits, and R&D incentives. The latest tax invention is a patent box in which the whole or part of profits attributable to new inventions is taxed at a lower effective CT rate or not at all, and which reduces the tax on wages paid to researchers.Footnote 12

3 Current tax treatment of corporate source income

This section reviews and comments on existing CT regimes in the EU. The taxation of capital gains and closely held corporations is also evaluated as is the treatment of cross-border income flows.

3.1 Overview of corporation tax systems

On the basis of the taxonomy developed above, Table 2 shows how the various CT systems of the EU Member States treat equity income and debt income.Footnote 13 Equity income consists of retained profits (taxed at the CT rate), dividend income (taxed at the CT \(+\) PT rate), and capital gains (taxed at the CT \(+\) PT rate when realized). PT dividend withholding taxes (WHTs), provisional or final, are also listed, as are the WHTs on interest paid to domestic recipients taxed under the PT. Interest may be disallowed indirectly by prescribing that for tax purposes debt cannot exceed a prescribed ratio of total capital shown in the balance sheet or by limiting the deduction to a percentage of earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization (EBITDA). If interest is not subject to a (final) withholding tax, it may not be taxed at all if paid into an exempt pension or investment fund.Footnote 14

Table 2 European Union: corporation taxes (CTs) and personal income taxes (PTs) on corporate source income in 2017

The average CT rate in the EU of 22.6% conceals widely different individual-state rates, ranging, in 2017, from a low of 10% in Bulgaria to a high of 35% in Malta. Interestingly, CT rates in the 12 new states (not counting EstoniaFootnote 15) that acceded to the EU after 1992 are on average more than 3%-points lower than in the 15 old Member States. This suggests that new Member States use their CT rates more aggressively in stimulating investment in the corporate sector than old Member States. On the other hand, agglomeration may also matter: some old Member States are larger than most new states and, therefore, less susceptible to tax avoidance schemes (Baldwin and Krugman 2004; Garretsen and Peeters 2007).

Most systems listed in Table 1 are found in the EU.Footnote 16 The majority of the Member States impose a rudimentary form of CBIT by levying a final withholding tax on interest (and dividends), which is equivalent to not allowing a deduction against profits for interest and not taxing it at recipient level. The CBITs are rudimentary, because the effective tax rates on dividend income (CT plus final withholding tax) differ from the effective rates on interest (final withholding tax). Also, the withholding taxes may not apply to returns paid on shares and bonds held abroad, which are usually the subject of double tax treaties and EU directives.

Clearly, most Member States appear to have a preference for source taxation of capital income. Exceptionally, Slovakia, Sweden and the UK do not impose a withholding tax on dividends, while Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Cyprus, Malta and the Netherlands do not tax capital gains. Interest is not subject to withholding in Bulgaria, the Netherlands, Sweden and the UK. Seven Member States do not restrict the deductibility of interest through a debt/equity ratio or EBITDA percentage (but may apply other restrictions on interest deductibility). In sum, not all Member States tax corporate source income comprehensively at the level of the corporation.

3.2 Taxing profits (equity income)

The so-called classical system (coined by Van den Tempel 1970) is found in four Member States. Proponents of this system regard the corporation as an entity entirely separate from its shareholders and taxed as such. Generally, no deduction for dividends is allowed when computing taxable profits. Moreover, dividends are taxed again in the hands of shareholders. The double tax is particularly high in France and Ireland where the combined CT \(+\) PT burden on dividends distributed from current profits takes up more than half of dividend income. By comparison, in six other Member States, the combined CT \(+\) PT burden is 25% or less.

The phenomenon of taxing equity income at corporate as well as shareholder level is called the “double taxation of dividends.”Footnote 17 The CT and the PT on equity income both enter the wedge between the before-tax return of the corporation and the required after-tax return (the reward for saving) that must be paid to shareholders to induce them to put up their capital. Presumably, this double tax affects entrepreneurial behavior, because the wedge (and, by extension, the required return) will vary, depending on the choice of financing (retained profits, new equity, or debt) and the corporation’s dividend policy (distribution or retention).Footnote 18 Double taxation tends to generate a bias against profit distribution and in favor of debt financing, distorting dividend payout policies and financing decisions.

One Member State, Malta, employs an imputation system. The relief is expressed as a fraction (or percentage) of the net dividend.Footnote 19 Malta has a full imputation system, which means that profits distributed to domestic shareholders are taxed at their marginal PT rate.Footnote 20 The imputation tax credit is also available to nonresident shareholders. Imputation systems used to dominate the CT picture in the EU, especially in the 1970s and 1980s. Over time, however, they were regarded as overly complicated, while their cross-border implications were held to be discriminatory.Footnote 21 In 2016, the UK abolished its imputation system, which permitted a deemed tax credit of merely 1/9th of the net dividend, and replaced it with a PT dividend exemption of £5000.

3.3 Taxing profits and interest (capital income)

Under the classical system, interest (and royalties) is not treated on par with the return on equity, even if debt and equity are fully substitutable. Equal treatment is achieved under regimes that tax the returns on both equity and debt at the corporate or personal level, either provisionally in the form of a dual income tax (DIT) or definitively under a comprehensive business income tax (CBIT).

Under DIT, capital income, corporate and non-corporate, is separated from labor income and taxed at a moderate, uniform rate, ideally equal to the CT rate. In the Nordic countries, the DIT was introduced on the philosophy that in a small open economy with perfect capital mobility, any source-based tax on the normal return to capital will be shifted onto domestic, immobile factors or products through an increase in the pre-tax rate of return required by investors.Footnote 22 In this situation, it is simply not optimal for a small economy to levy any source-based tax on the normal return. Although corporate capital is not fully mobile, the degree of mobility is so high that it is advisable to keep any source-based tax low, absent international tax coordination. If, for revenue and distributional reasons, the top PT rate cannot be reduced to the level of the lower CT rate, the obvious solution therefore is to tax capital income on a schedular basis. Further, capital market innovation in conjunction with tax arbitrage implies that it is not feasible to tax capital income effectively at different tax rates. Hence, the decision to tax capital income at a moderate uniform tax rate, basically equal to the CT rate.

The Nordic Member States, Finland and Sweden, now have 25 years of experience with dual income taxation.Footnote 23 The DITs in these countries, however, are not as pure as the Norwegian DIT.Footnote 24 Corporate profits and other capital income are taxed at the same rate in Norway, but other capital income is taxed at somewhat higher PT rates in Finland and Sweden. Further, capital gains are taxed twice in Finland and Sweden to the extent that no account is taken of the CT that is levied on retained profits. Spain is the latest member of the DIT club.Footnote 25

Fifteen Member States may be said to have some form of CBIT. As shown in Table 2, they impose a final withholding tax (WHT) at the corporate level on interest paid to residents or exempt interest altogether from the PT (Bulgaria, Croatia). Dividends, too, are subject to final withholding (or exempt as in Slovakia) and not taxed under the PT.Footnote 26 These CBITs are not pure, however, because the effective tax rates differ for various types of capital income. Retained profits are taxed at a lower rate than distributed profits, while interest tends to be taxed at rates similar to the CT rate. With some exceptions, this is also true of capital gains, although deferral implies that effective rates are lower.

3.4 Taxing economic rents

The allowance for corporate equity (ACE) is the only cash flow tax in practice today.Footnote 27 The ACE system purports to tax only pure profits by providing a deduction from profits, conventionally computed, equal to the shareholders’ funds (generally, the corporation’s total equity capital, including taxable profits net of CT) multiplied by an appropriate nominal interest rate set by the government but reflecting a normal market rate of return on, say, medium-term government bonds.Footnote 28 Since the ACE closely resembles normal profits, its deduction from total taxable profits means that the CT is confined to pure profits from infra-marginal investments.Footnote 29

Belgium exempts the normal return from CT in the form of an ACE, called “notional interest on corporate capital.” The interest is set at the rate payable on 10-year government bonds issued in the previous year. Presumably, this rate reflects the normal rate of return on capital. The rate—1.131% in 2017 but 1.631% for SMEs—is applied to the corporation’s “risk capital,” that is, its equity shown on the balance sheet. Belgium introduced the ACE system to stimulate the self-financing capability of corporations, but did not extend it to unincorporated businesses and private investors.Footnote 30 The ACE in Cyprus is equal to the yield on 10-year government bonds plus 3%. Italy confines the ACE to new equity. For some time, Croatia also had an ACE system but abolished it for reasons that are not entirely clear (Keen and King 2002).

By exempting the normal return on capital, the ACE regime does not affect real investment. Also, financing decisions—choosing between equity and debt or retained earnings and new equity—are not distorted, while the distortion of the organizational form in which the business is conducted—corporate versus non-corporate form—is mitigated. However, not taxing the normal return implies that the CT rate has to be higher if CT revenues are to be maintained. This should exacerbate tax avoidance through profit shifting.

In comparing the ACE system with the CBIT, Bond (2001) opines that in a world with increasing mobility of physical capital, the user cost of capital may no longer be the only route through which the CT influences the level of domestic investment. If, as is likely, multinational companies dominate in the earning of economic rents, their discrete location decisions would also be influenced by the statutory rate or, more precisely, the Effective Average Tax Rate (EATR) which can be shown to be a weighted average of the statutory tax rate and the Marginal Effective Tax Rate (METR). Under an equal-yield assumption, the statutory rate would have to be higher under the ACE tax, which would distribute corporate tax payments toward relatively profitable companies. By contrast, a lower-rate CBIT would leave profitable multinational companies with lower tax bills. In this situation, a government in an open economy may achieve a higher level of domestic investment by lowering the statutory rate and accepting a broader tax base, even though this results in a higher cost of capital.

Estonia goes even further than Belgium by exempting the whole of corporate profits from CT. Instead, a 20% tax is levied upon the distribution of corporate profits to individuals or other corporate entities. The profits distribution tax in Estonia, which is recorded as CT revenue, yielded 1.7% of GDP in 2014 (European Commission 2016b). Interest is also taxed at 20% at the PT level. Finally, the Netherlands exempts dividend income in full (although it still levies a withholding tax at corporate level, which is creditable against other income). Instead, in the 2001 reform, it introduced a 1.2% net wealth tax, which it calls income tax (not shown in the table) as a substitute for the PT on dividend income and interest.Footnote 31

3.5 Taxing capital gains and closely held corporations

As shown in Table 2, 22 Member States tax capital gains on shares, but no Member State makes a systematic attempt to alleviate the double tax on retained profits by allowing shareholders to increase the acquisition price of shares by the corporation’s retained profits net of CT (as Norway does). Further, the capital gains tax rates are statutory or nominal rates. Deferral and various tax base preferences result in effective capital gains tax rates that are lower than the nominal rates and also lower than the CT \(+\) PT burden on profit distributions. Accordingly, shareholders should have a preference for capital gains over dividends, which may be expected to affect payout policies.

The treatment of capital gains is of special interest in the case of closely held corporations in which shareholders work in the company as managers and, hence, can decide whether profits (constituting capital as well as labor income) are retained (taxed by the CT plus a deferred tax when capital gains are realized), paid out as dividends (CT \(+\) PT), or as wages (PT). Applying the CT only would induce managers/shareholders to adopt the corporate form for their labor income generating activities, which would then be taxed at a generally lower rate than the income of ordinary wage earners. To prevent this from happening, profits of closely held corporations can be taxed in full under the PT (full integration), or split into labor income (subject to the PT) and capital income (subject to the CT) under the DIT.

No Member State practices full integration for closely held corporations.Footnote 32 Instead, most Member States adopt an ad hoc approach by arguing that profit distributions are taxed twice under the CT and the PT, which roughly equals the PT on labor income. The concern therefore is mainly with capital gains attributable to profit (\(=\)labor income) retention. To prevent labor income from being effectively taxed less when sheltered in corporations, at least 13 Member States distinguish capital gains realized on the sale of (non-traded) shares (which represent a controlling interest, called substantial holding, in closely held corporations) from capital gains realized on the sale of ordinary (widely held) shares (generally, quoted on national stock exchanges). The former gains are taxed differentially higher than ordinary gains. Details can be found in Table 3.

Table 3 European Union: personal income tax treatment of substantial holdings and unquoted shares in 2016

Nordic DITs provide the most consistent treatment of capital and labor income that accrues jointly in closely held corporations, as well as proprietorships and partnerships. Taxable profits, conventionally computed, are split into a capital income component and a labor income component (if the sum of the two components exceeds the first bracket of the labor income tax, the rate of which equals the CT rate), and taxed on a current basis. Specifically, the capital income component of profits is calculated by applying a presumptive rate of return to the value of all business assets, called the gross method (Norway), or to the value of all assets minus liabilities (equity capital), referred to as the net method (Finland).Footnote 33 The amount thus calculated is deducted from total profits, and remaining profits are considered as labor income. As explained by Sørensen (2010), the choice between the two methods is largely a choice between investment neutrality and minimizing opportunities for tax arbitrage. Tax arbitrage is less of an issue under the gross method, because the presumptive rate of return is applied to a base that is not influenced by the financing structure of the business. The net (equity) method, on the other hand, is more conducive to investment neutrality because it does not encourage debt-financed investment if the government sets the presumptive rate of return above the going interest rate.

3.6 Intra-EU capital income flows

The previous paragraphs analyzed the domestic tax treatment of corporate source income. However, owners of shares, bonds and intangibles, be it corporate entities or individuals, may reside in states other than the state in which the paying corporation carries on its business and the residence states may assert a right to tax the dividends, interest, royalties and capital gains accruing to its residents. The division of the taxing rights of source and residence states is the subject of bilateral tax treaties and EU directives agreed to by the Member States. In practice, dividends are taxed not only by the source state (under the CT and by withholding taxes, if any) but also by the residence state (under the PT and CT on portfolio dividend income). Most residence states tax shareholders on realized capital gains. The returns on debt and intangibles, that is, interest and royalties, are taxed by the residence state and, if a withholding tax applies, by the source state.

Table 4 shows the general bilateral treaty withholding tax (WHT) rates in the EU on dividends, interest and royalties between non-related parties. For each Member State, the treaty WHT rates are listed that have been agreed with the Member State that provided the largest amount of inward foreign domestic investment over the period 2008–2014 (OECD 2014) as a proxy for portfolio investment in the same direction.Footnote 34 Regarding dividends, most WHT rates are fixed at 15%. Sixteen Member States impose a WHT on interest at various rates, while royalty income tends to be exempted or subject to 5% WHT.

Table 4 European Union: treaty withholding tax (WHT) rates in 2017 on dividend, interest and royalty payments to non-related parties in member states providing the largest amount of foreign direct investment during 2008–2014

By contrast, EU directives proscribe the use of withholding taxes on dividends, interest, royalties and capital gains between related parties in favor of residence states. Thus, the Parent-Subsidiary Directive (European Council 1990; revised in 2003 and 2006) eliminates nonresident withholding taxes on dividend payments among related companies with a minimum shareholding of 10%.Footnote 35 Similarly, the Interest-Royalty Directive (European Council 2003a) eliminates nonresident withholding taxes on intra-firm interest and royalty payments if the beneficial owner is effectively subject to tax on interest and royalties received in the corporation’s Member State of establishment. Further, the Merger Directive (European Council 2009) eliminates the taxation of capital gains realized by corporations and shareholders upon an intra-EU merger or acquisition. Finally, the Savings Directive (2003b) provides for the exchange of information on cross-border interest accruing to individuals, which can then be taxed in the residence state.

Accordingly, EU Member States apply the source as well as the residence principle in taxing corporate source income. As is well known, the residence principle permits capital export neutrality (CEN), which implies that the tax system does not affect the choice between investing at home or abroad (Musgrave 1969). On the other hand, the source principle promotes capital import neutrality (CIN). This implies that both resident and nonresident investors face the same tax burden on an investment in a particular source country. The source principle is easier to apply in practice than the residence principle because the taxable income originates in the Member State collecting the tax.

In a situation of perfect capital mobility, the residence principle equalizes pre-tax rates of return; in other words, at the margin, capital costs are the same in different countries. The source principle, in contrast, tends to equalize the post-tax rates of return of savers residing in different states. Whether one principle is economically superior to the other principle depends on whether users of capital (business firms) or suppliers of capital (savers) are more sensitive to differences in returns. Business firms are likely to be more sensitive to differences in capital costs than savers are to differences in net returns. Hence, the residence principle (that is, capital export neutrality) seems a more important efficiency objective to pursue than the source principle (that is, capital import neutrality).Footnote 36

The subsidiarity principle, however, indicates a preference for source country taxation over residence-country taxation of corporate source income in the EU. By implication, capital import neutrality is favored over capital export neutrality. In a single market, however, in which capital and persons can move freely, the distinction between these two kinds of neutrality tends to become blurred. Administrative considerations, moreover, support the argument for source country taxation.Footnote 37 Further, the experience in federal countries, such as the USA and Canada, indicates that different CTs can exist in a single market without internal borders.Footnote 38

3.7 Some important findings

The analysis in this section yields some important findings, which can be summed up as follows.

  • Basically, the taxable return on corporate investments is defined in terms of equity income (profits), but increasingly Member States levy final withholding taxes on interest (and dividends) paid to domestic share and debt holders—income items that are subsequently exempted.

  • In the domestic context, therefore, 15 Member States are moving toward some form of CBIT. Within this context, however, various forms of capital income are taxed at different effective rates, which may distort savings and investment decisions. Capital income is taxed more uniformly in three Member States with a DIT. Another three Member States do not tax the normal return to capital under their ACE, which, they believe, should promote investment.

  • Generally, dividends are taxed at a higher rate than interest if the earlier CT is taken into account, as it should be. This favors debt over equity.Footnote 39 The higher tax on dividends can be defended if they reflect above-normal profits. The tax on dividends, which stimulates profit retention, reduces the amount of capital becoming available on European capital markets and thus hampers the development of EU share markets.Footnote 40

  • Capital gains are widely taxed at schedular PT rates and only upon realization, implying lower effective rates. Higher rates would be appropriate if the gains reflect economic rents or windfalls. No state takes account of the earlier CT by correcting the basis of share purchases for retained corporate profits net of CT.

  • Withholding taxes are imposed on dividends paid to non-related parties abroad, but to a lesser extent on interest and royalties. Payments to related foreign corporate entities tend to be exempted from tax. Withholding tax exemptions or lower rates are granted only if the beneficial recipient is effectively taxed. Prescribed debt/equity ratios effectively limit interest payments to foreign as well as domestic debt holders.

  • In all Member States, pension and investment funds are not taxed and can hence be used as conduits for not paying tax on interest or dividends if tax is not withheld at corporate level or the withholding taxes on these payments are refundable.Footnote 41 In addition, the tax exempt status of institutional investors affects their portfolio choice and thereby the ownership structure of firms.

Although various efforts have been made in recent years to reduce the discrimination of profit distributions by lowering the PT on dividends, and the preferential treatment of debt and royalties by imposing (final) withholding taxes at corporate level, most neutrality shortcomings have not yet been eliminated fully or have been removed through ad hoc measures (for example, debt/equity ratios) that leave the basic conventional CTs largely intact. Further, much of the tax literature is in favor of not taxing the hurdle rate of return on capital in the form of an ACE. What should Member States do?

4 Directions for corporation tax reform and coordination

This section examines the various options for CT reform and coordination in the EU more closely. CT regimes that tax the normal rate of return (DIT, CBIT, formulary apportionment) are discussed first, followed by regimes that exempt the normal rate of return (ACE, destination-based cash flow tax).

4.1 Dual income tax (DIT)

A pragmatic scenario for further CT (and other capital income tax) reform and coordination in the EU could start with a DIT, as found in Finland, Norway, Sweden and Spain, under which capital income, not just corporate income, would be taxed once at a single rate (different for each Member State) equal to the CT rate. This would mitigate the distorting effects of current differential CT \(+\) PT systems on corporate financial and investment policies. Agreement could be pursued in the EU on a minimum DIT rate. Under these DITs, dividends paid out of fully taxed profits should be exempted at shareholders’ level (which would reduce the debt bias), while dividends paid out of exempt profits should be subject to a compensatory tax at the CT rate.

A differentially higher tax on dividends could be contemplated, however, to the extent that the dividends reflect above-normal returns. This extra tax could be confined to residents by imposing it at shareholder level as is done in Norway. The Norwegian shareholder’s income tax, as it is called (Sørensen 2005), taxes dividend income in full under the PT but permits a deduction of a rate of return allowance equal to the interest on medium-term government bonds. Accordingly, this rate of return allowance is taxed only once, namely at corporate level, while economic rents are taxed twice.Footnote 42 As a result, as noted by Kleinbard (2010), Norway does not make a distinction between labor and capital income, but between the normal return on capital and all other income.Footnote 43

As pointed out by Sørensen (2005), an advantage of this approach is that it eliminates the incentive for income shifting between jointly accruing labor and capital income in closely held corporations in a manner that limits investment distortions. Furthermore, it obviates the need to make a distinction between “active owners” of closely held corporations (owning the business as well as managing it—simultaneously earning labor and capital income) and “passive owners” (financing, but not owning the business and not involved in running it).Footnote 44 The distinction between labor and capital income remains relevant for unincorporated businesses, but only if the total income exceeds the first bracket of the labor income tax schedule, the rate of which equals or closely reflects the CT rate.

As regards interest and royalties, for the time being, the level of the creditable or final withholding taxes at the corporate level could vary between Member States in light of domestic and international policy considerations (for instance, its effect on foreign domestic investment). Provisionally, the (final) withholding tax rates could be lower than the CT rate, for instance, and not apply to foreign recipients of interest for fear of discouraging inward capital flows. Presumably, full (and final) withholding taxes on interest and royalties paid to foreign bondholders and intellectual property owners would require EU-wide coordination. Coordination with the EU’s major trading partners would also be needed.

Finally, the concern that some Member States may have regarding the lower taxation of capital income compared to labor income could be addressed by adopting a net wealth tax on residents. This would raise the effective tax burden on domestic (mostly well-to-do) residents without affecting nonresidents and hence inward capital flows. In this respect, too, Norway leads the way.

4.2 Comprehensive business income tax (CBIT)

The extension of final interest and royalty withholding taxes throughout the EU to payments to nonresidents as well as residents would effectively tax the returns on all forms of capital, eliminate incentives for thin capitalization and the discrimination in favor of tax exempt investment and pension funds. Over time, the withholding taxes could be raised to the level of the DIT rate, which would convert the DITs into CBITs. Agreement should then be reached that interest and royaltiesFootnote 45 are not taxed again in residence countries, which would require the abrogation of the Parent-Subsidiary Directive and the Interest-Royalty Directive. To ensure that dividends, interest and royalties are not paid out of exempt earnings (possibly escaping the tax altogether), a compensatory tax should be levied on exempt profits made available for distribution in either of these forms of return. Preferably, capital gains on shares should only be taxed to the extent that they exceed the acquisition cost stepped up by the corporation’s retained profits net of the CT.

Subsequently, the narrowing of CT (and withholding tax) rates throughout the EU would eliminate incentives for transfer pricing manipulation within the EU (but not with third countries). Presumably, rate narrowing would be easier to achieve following the introduction of DITs and more comprehensive withholding taxes on interest. This reform would make the debt–equity distinction irrelevant, and greatly reduce the distinction between retained and distributed profits (depending on the treatment of capital gains).

The effective taxation of interest and royalties on par with equity income would reduce the relative tax burden on new equity-financed investment and increase the burden on debt-financed investment. Established firms and institutional investors would face relatively higher tax burdens, as would tax haven countries, but new, growing firms would be taxed less heavily. If the reform were revenue neutral, nominal CT rates could be reduced, while average tax rates could perhaps be allowed to fall due to overall efficiency gains. In an important contribution to the tax literature, De Mooij and Devereux (2011) conclude that their applied general equilibrium model for the EU suggests that “if governments adjust statutory corporate tax rates to balance their budget, profit shifting and discrete location render CBIT more attractive for most individual European countries.”Footnote 46

4.3 Formulary apportionment (FA)?

Under the previous proposals, the CTs would still proceed from the separate accounting approach in determining the taxable profits of affiliated corporations in different Member States. Accordingly, profit shifting through transfer pricing manipulation would still be possible, albeit moderated by the narrowing of rate differentials. Further, provisions for the removal of tax obstacles to cross-border economic activity and business restructuring would still be needed. A comprehensive solution to these problems, if desired, can only be achieved through common base taxation.

In this connection, the European Commission (2016a) has launched a recalibrated proposal for a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCBT) for large multinational groups with global revenues in excess of €750 million a year. The CCCBT would be allocated to Member States on the basis of three equally weighted factors: the value of assets in a Member State, the number of employees and labor costs, and the company’s destination-based sales in the Member State.Footnote 47

According to the European Commission, the advantages of a CCCBT with formula apportionment (and its logical conclusion, unitary taxation) are fewer distortions, less tax arbitrage (transfer pricing) and lower compliance costs. This is disputed by Altshuler and Grubert (2010), however, whose model indicates that separate accounting causes fewer distortions than FA under capital-based formulas, which induces capital to move to low tax jurisdictions. Further, sales-based formulas induce companies to change the mix of high margin and low margin sales in a market, and also the extent to which independent resellers in low-tax countries are used. In sum, the simulations which the authors perform indicate that FA has no clear advantage over separate accounting.

The path to common base taxation would not be easy either. As pointed out by McLure and Weiner (2000) and Mintz and Weiner (2003), its introduction would give rise to serious policy sequencing and transition problems for EU Member States. Accounting conventions and institutional structures would have to be harmonized. All of these problems would be exacerbated by complex technical questions, such as defining a unitary business, choosing the appropriate apportionment formula (directly affecting the interstate allocation of revenue) and measuring the factors in the formula (precise definitions are crucial).Footnote 48 Harmonization of the tax base seems less urgent than coordination of the tax rates. Perhaps formulary apportionment should therefore be left for two or more Member States to deal with as is the case in the USA and Canada.

4.4 Allowance for corporate equity (ACE)

Under DIT, CBIT and FA, the return on marginal investments, just making a viable economic return, would be taxed, which might harm investment. This normal rate of return is effectively exempted under the ACE, which is favored by De Mooij and Devereux (2011) as well as, more cautiously, by the IMF (2016).

Undoubtedly, the ACE system has attractive neutrality properties.Footnote 49 By exempting the hurdle rate of return, marginal investments are not hampered. Similarly, the debt–equity choice is not affected by the tax system, while economic distortions through differences in depreciation between assets and industrial sectors are eliminated. Complex valuation issues are avoided, and inflation would not affect the tax base. Broad adoption of the ACE would make profit shifting through transfer pricing manipulation considerably less attractive, just like the shifting of assets and firms (mergers and inversions) or the manipulation of the debt/equity ratio.

Against these advantages, sight should not be lost of some disadvantages. Given the same rate, the ACE will generate less revenue than a conventional CT. To make up for the revenue shortfall, either the CT rate would have to be increased (magnifying the remaining distortions and tax avoidance incentives) or compensation would have to be sought elsewhere in the tax-and-expenditure system with effects that cannot be ignored. The revenue loss can be reduced by confining the ACE to new equity-financed investments (as is done in Italy), but this would aggravate the administrative complexity of the tax. Initially, immediate expensing of investments would also increase losses and with it the call for offset against past losses.

More generally, the neutrality conditions that are required for the ACE to work are met only if capital markets are perfect. To ensure investment neutrality, moreover, the government would have to share symmetrically in all gains and losses under unlimited loss carry forward and backward provisions. Further, if dividends continue to be taxed under PTs, the ACE system would favor retentions even more strongly over distributions than do other CT systems. In effect, the ACE system would then resemble a form of dividend relief, akin to the dividend deduction system. Also, the ACE regime does not provide relief to unincorporated businesses. To be fully neutral, the ACE system would require the transformation of the PT into a personal consumption tax, which comprehensively exempts the normal return to capital.Footnote 50 On the basis of these arguments, Mintz (2015) rejects an ACE for Canada. He also points out that an ACE would increase tax losses, make the corporate form even more attractive for sheltering labor income and run afoul of the US tax credit system (a point also made by Griffith et al. 2010).

4.5 Destination-based cash flow tax (DBCFT)

While the ACE does not affect investment in a closed economy setting, in an international context countries should still compete over tax rates, because the base would remain mobile even if confined to economic rents. To mitigate this effect, Auerbach et al. (2017) propose to shift the ACE base from its origin, the producer, to its destination, the consumer, who is less mobile. This can be done by making the ACE border adjustable by including imports in the domestic tax base and excluding exports from that base. In other words, the ACE base would equal the business cash flow component of the base of a VAT, which is a destination-based consumption tax. The authors call their proposal a destination-based cash flow tax, or DBFCT, for short. The new tax, at a rate of 20%, has been tabled by the US House of Representatives Republican Task Force on Tax Reform (see Ryan 2016).Footnote 51

The DBCFT would have many of the same disadvantages and advantages as the ACE, but in addition, the trading partners of a DBCFT country might consider the proposed treatment of imports and exports a form of protectionism not permitted under the provisions of the World Trade Organization (WTO) Treaty. The proponents of the new tax, however, argue that the implicit taxation of imports and the rebate of the tax on exports mean that the USA will import less and export more. This should result in an appreciation of the dollar, such that the relative prices of internationally traded and domestically produced goods and services remain the same, which should restore the ex ante situation. Buiter (2017), however, has argued that the presumed exchange rate adjustment is not robust; even a deprecation of the dollar should not be excluded. Finally, Auerbach et al. (2017) have pointed out that the effect of a DBCFT can also be achieved by introducing a VAT in the form of a Hall and Rabushka (1995) flat tax under which wages are deducted from value added leaving business cash flow, that is, the above-normal return to capital. The tax on wages could then be plowed back in the form of a reduction in employers’ social security contributions which would result in an immediate reduction of labor costs.

5 Concluding comments

This review of CT systems in the EU appears to indicate that subsidiarity and neutrality in the EU are best served by the moderate, even-handed, source taxation of capital income.Footnote 52 This reflects the preference of the Member States, which shore up their source-based CTs with transfer pricing rules, prescribed debt/equity ratios, prohibitions on the deferral of tax on the income of controlled foreign corporations (CFCs) and, increasingly, final withholding taxes on dividends, interest and royalties. Basically, the right to tax of residence states is confined to residual income.

However, differences in the tax treatment of various forms of capital income distort corporate financial and investment policies, involve complex administrative arrangements and induce tax competition. A pragmatic solution to these issues appears to lie in a combination of CT reform within Member States with CT coordination between Member States. A start could be made with the wider adoption of DITs under which capital income would be taxed at a moderate uniform rate (that is, the CT rate, which, subject to a minimum, could still vary between Member States), except interest and royalties on inbound investment and the use of foreign intangibles. Subsequently, agreement could be reached on expanding and converting current EU Member State treaty withholding tax rates into final taxes on interest and royalty payments with regard to foreign (as well as domestic) debt and intangibles. To prevent double taxation, residence states would then have to give up their right to tax residual income in the form of dividends, interest and royalties. Further, the EU directives on the exemption of capital income payments between related entities would have to be withdrawn. The DITs would turn into CBITs once the withholding taxes reach the level of the CT rate.

Although full taxation of interest and royalties at corporate level would seem a goal worth pursuing, gradual and concerted action is called for. Caution is advisable because the current tax-induced changes in corporate financing and intangible ownership patterns may, to a large extent, serve to reduce the distortions of real investment and saving decisions.Footnote 53 A start could be made with the common 10% withholding tax on interest and royalties, also on intra-group transactions, proposed by Finke et al. (2014).Footnote 54 Presumably, full source-based taxation of capital income in EU Member States would require coordination with the EU’s major trading partners, particularly the USA.

The article has not come out in favor of FA, because of its distortions and complexities. Neither does it favor some form of cash flow taxation since most Member States appear to believe that the normal return on capital should be taxed. This view finds support in recent work on the incidence of the CT which is shown to fall predominantly on capital and therefore to be progressive (Clausing 2013). More generally, the scope for capital taxation from an equity perspective should not be lost sight of.Footnote 55