Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Central versus local education finance: a political economy approach

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper models voters’ preferences over central versus local education policies when there are private alternatives. Education is financed by income taxes and individuals are mobile between communities. Public education levels are chosen by majority vote. Contrary to conventional wisdom, centralisation may benefit the rich and poor, while the middle class prefer decentralised education. The model is also extended to include peer effects. Peer effects increase the support for central school finance, even in the community with good public schools.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alesina, A., & Spolaore, E. (1997). On the number and size of nations. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 1027–1056.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bearse, P., Glomm, G., & Ravikumar, B. (2001). Education finance in a dynamic Tiebout economy. Mimeo.

  • Bolton, P., & Roland, G. (1997). The breakup of nations: a political economy analysis. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 1057–1090.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borck, R. (1998). Centralization of public good supply with majority voting. FinanzArchiv, 55, 21–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen-Zada, D., & Justman, M. (2003). The political economy of school choice: linking theory and evidence. Journal of Urban Economics, 54(2), 277–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Bartolome, C. A. M. (1990). Equilibrium and inefficiency in a community model with peer group effects. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 110–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epple, D., & Romano, R. E. (1996). Ends against the middle: determining public service provision when there are private alternatives. Journal of Public Economics, 62, 297–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epple, D., & Romano, R. E. (1998). Competition between private and public schools, vouchers, and peer-group effects. American Economic Review, 88, 33–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R., & Rogerson, R. (1999). Education finance reform and investment in human capital: lessons from California. Journal of Public Economics, 74, 327–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R., & Rogerson, R. (2003). Equity and resources: an analysis of education finance systems. Journal of Political Economy, 111(4), 858–897.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franc, C., & Abadie, L. (2004). Opting out of public insurance: is it socially desirable?. Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance: Theory, 29, 115–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans, J. S., & Smart, M. (1996). Majority voting with single-crossing preferences. Journal of Public Economics, 59, 219–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, N. A., & Kessler, A. S. (2001). (Non)-existence of equilibria in multicommunity models. Journal of Urban Economics, 50, 418–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jouvet, P.-A., Michel, P., & Pestieau, P. (2004). Public and private environmental spending: a political economy approach. CORE discussion paper 2004/68.

  • Jürges, H., Schneider, K., & Büchel, F. (2005). The effect of central exit examinations on student achievement: quasi-experimental evidence from TIMSS Germany. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3, 1134–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba, T. (2003a). School finance, spatial income segregation and the nature of communities. Journal of Urban Economics, 54, 61–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba, T. J. (1999). School finance induced migration and stratification patterns: the impact of private school vouchers. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 1, 5–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba, T. J. (2003b). Centralization, fiscal federalism, and private school attendance. International Economic Review, 44(1), 179–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2004). Education at a glance: OECD indicators. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solon, G. (1992). Intergenerational income mobility in the United States. American Economic Review, 82(3), 393–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1974). The demand for education in public and private school systems. Journal of Public Economics, 3, 349–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimmerman, D. J. (1992). Regression toward mediocrity in economic stature. American Economic Review, 82(3), 409–429.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rainald Borck.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Borck, R. Central versus local education finance: a political economy approach. Int Tax Public Finance 15, 338–352 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-007-9029-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-007-9029-9

Keywords

JEL

Navigation