Skip to main content
Log in

Detecting motives for cooperation in public goods experiments

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study clarifies the types of motives that are important as a source of cooperation in a linear public goods experiment. Our experimental design separates contributions into those due to confusion, one-shot motives (which includes altruism, warm-glow, inequality aversion, and conditional cooperation), and multi-round motives (which includes a strategic motive under incomplete information, a failure of backward induction, and reciprocity). The experiment reveals that multi-round motives plays an important role in driving cooperative behavior. Confusion and one-shot motives play a minor role.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Jacobson and Petrie (2014) find that a change in information provision increases contribution to the public good due to direct reciprocity by 14 %.

  2. Some papers try to separate strategic motives from pro-social motives in indefinitely-repeated games (e.g., Reuben and Suetens 2012; Cabral et al. 2014; Dreber et al. 2014).

  3. Ferraro et al. (2003) also use computer players to separate out the motives for cooperation, and find that other-regarding behavior elevates contributions in public goods experiments. Cox (2004) discriminates between transfers due to trust or reciprocity and transfers due to other-regarding preferences that are not conditional on the behavior of others in a trust game, by comparing between different treatments.

  4. This nomenclature is imperfect because conditional cooperation is not a one-shot type motive. However, we use it because meaningful name will be helpful for readers to read.

  5. Cason et al. (2002), Van Dijk et al. (2002), Cason et al. (2004), and Yamakawa (2012) also adopt a two-player public goods game and a detailed payoff table. Of these studies, Cason et al. (2002), Van Dijk et al. (2002), and Cason et al. (2004) examined non-linear public goods games with interior Nash or dominant strategy equilibria. Yamakawa (2012) examined a linear public goods game. The data in Van Dijk et al. (2002) and Yamakawa (2012) has a similar pattern to that in our experiment. They observe stable or slightly increasing contributions over time, and sudden cooperative decay in the last round. Cason et al. (2002) and Cason et al. (2004) do not observe such a pattern. Charness et al. (2004) conduct gift exchange experiments and show that the behavior is significantly sensitive to whether the subject is provided a detailed payoff table.

  6. Subjects in the C condition are not informed that the choices of the computer are human actions’ data of the previous experimental session.

  7. One might think that contributions due to warm-glow may also occur in the C condition by its definition. However, if we interpret that warm-glow is realized through interaction with the other people, it does not work in the C condition.

  8. 1 US dollar was about 95 yen at the time when the experiment took place in Osaka, and about 118 yen when we moved to Kochi.

  9. \(p=0.113\) in round 2, \(p=0.190\) in round 3, \(p=0.082\) in round 4, \(p=0.154\) in round 6, \(p=0.082\) in round 8, \(p=0.202\) in round 10, and \(p=0.063\) in round 19.

  10. \(p=0.080\) in rounds 1, 2, 3, 10, 17, 18, and 19; \(p=0.165\) in rounds 4, 6, 7, 8, 9, 11, and 12; \(p=1.000\) in rounds 5, 13, 14, 15, and 16.

  11. The absence of decay in the HC and C conditions is partly because the contributions in the HC and C conditions are very low throughout the experiment, and hence there is little room for decay.

References

  • Anderson, S. P., Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (1998). A theoretical analysis of altruism and decision error in public goods games. Journal of Public Economics, 70, 297–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1988a). Privately provided public goods in a large economy: The limits of altruism. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 57–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1988b). Why free ride? Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 37, 291–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with impure altruism: Applications to charity and Ricardian equivalence. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1447–1458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm glow giving. Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1995). Cooperation in public goods experiments: Kindness or confusion? American Economic Review, 85, 891–904.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binmore, K., McCarthy, J., Ponti, G., Samuelson, L., & Shaked, A. (2002). A backward induction experiment. Journal of Economic Theory, 104, 48–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandts, J., Saijo, T., & Schram, A. (2004). How universal is behavior? A four country comparison of spite and cooperation in voluntary contribution mechanisms. Public Choice, 119, 381–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandts, J., & Schram, A. (2001). Cooperation and noise in public goods experiments: Applying the contribution function approach. Journal of Public Economics, 79, 399–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, L., Ozbay, E. Y., & Schotter, A. (2014). Intrinsic and instrumental reciprocity: An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 87, 100–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cason, T. N., Saijo, T., & Yamato, T. (2002). Voluntary participation and spite in public good provision experiments: An international comparison. Experimental Economics, 5, 133–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cason, T. N., Saijo, T., Yamato, T., & Yokotani, K. (2004). Non-excludable public good experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 49, 81–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., Fréchette, G. R., & Kagel, J. H. (2004). How robust is laboratory gift exchange. Experimental Economics, 7, 189–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, R., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1996). Cooperation without reputation: Experimental evidence from prisoner’s dilemma games. Games and Economic Behavior, 12, 187–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J. C. (2004). How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 46, 260–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson, R. T. A. (1996). Partners and strangers revisited. Economics Letters, 53, 25–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson, R. T. A. (2007). Theories of commitment, altruism and reciprocity: Evidence from linear public goods games. Economic Inquiry, 45, 199–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreber, A., Fudenberg, D., & Rand, D. G. (2014). Who cooperates in repeated games: The role of altruism, inequity aversion, and demographics. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 98, 41–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54, 293–315.

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraro, P. J., Rondeau, D., & Poe, G. L. (2003). Detecting other-regarding behavior with virtual players. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 51, 99–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71, 397–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goeree, J. K., Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Private costs and public benefits: Unraveling the effects of altruism and noisy behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 83, 255–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houser, D., & Kurzban, R. (2002). Revisiting kindness and confusion in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 92, 1062–1069.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson, S., & Petrie, R. (2014). Favor trading in public good provision. Experimental Economics, 17, 439–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E. J., Camerer, C., Sen, S., & Rymon, T. (2002). Detecting failures of backward induction: Monitoring information search in sequential bargaining. Journal of Economic Theory, 104, 16–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keser, C., & Van Winden, F. (2000). Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 102, 23–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D. M., Milgrom, P., Roberts, J., & Wilson, R. (1982). Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoners’ dilemma. Journal of Economic Theory, 27, 245–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ledyard, J. O. (1995). Public goods: A survey of experimental research. In J. H. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), The handbook of experimental economics (pp. 111–194). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1996). Altruism, reputation, and noise in linear public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 61, 409–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1997). Anomalous behavior in public goods experiments: How much and why? American Economic Review, 87, 829–846.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. American Economic Review, 83, 1281–1302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reuben, E., & Suetens, S. (2012). Revisiting strategic versus non-strategic cooperation. Experimental Economics, 15, 24–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sonnemans, J., Schram, A., & Offerman, T. (1999). Strategic behavior in public good games: When partners drift apart. Economics Letters, 62, 35–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Dijk, F., Sonnemans, J., & Van Winden, F. (2002). Social ties in a public good experiment. Journal of Public Economics, 85, 275–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weimann, J. (1994). Individual behavior in a free riding experiment. Journal of Public Economics, 54, 185–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamakawa, T. (2012). Strategic, social and confused motivations in public goods experiments. (in Japanese). Keizai Kenkyu, 63, 236–248.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Takao Kusakawa, Kan Takeuchi, Guillaume Fréchette, and the participants at the 13th Experimental Social Sciences Conference at Kobe University, the seminar at Shanghai Jiao Tong University, the 2011 meeting of the Asia-Pacific Economic Science Association at University of Nottingham Malaysia Campus, Experimental Social Sciences Workshop at Osaka University, the 11th Society for the Advancement of Economic Theory Conference, and the 14th International Conference on Social Dilemmas for their helpful comments and discussions. The present version of this paper has benefited from the comments of the editor and two referees. This research was supported by KAKENHI (Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research from the Ministry of Education, Culture, Sports, Science and Technology of Japan) on Priority Areas “Experimental Social Science.” The authors are responsible for any remaining errors that may occur.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yoshitaka Okano.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 232 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yamakawa, T., Okano, Y. & Saijo, T. Detecting motives for cooperation in public goods experiments. Exp Econ 19, 500–512 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-015-9451-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-015-9451-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation