Skip to main content
Log in

Industrialists hand in hand with environmentalists: how eco-labeling schemes can help firms to raise rivals’ costs

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Industrialists may promote eco-labeling schemes in order to gain the support of environmentalists and ultimately gain market protection. Beyond the environmental effects of such coalitions, these schemes can provide industrialists a legitimate way to disadvantage rivals, frequently foreign rivals, by raising their costs. We consider a Stackelberg model that determines the conditions under which a domestic firm has incentive to impose an eco-label in order to raise the costs of its foreign rivals. The effects of eco-labeling on domestic social welfare are ambiguous. Policy recommendations are drawn. Notably, factors that may help policy makers to identify situations more vulnerable to undesirable outcomes from a welfare viewpoint are developed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Amacher, G., Koskela, E., & Ollikainen, M. (2004). Environmental quality competition and eco-labeling. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 47, 284–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (1992). Strategy and environment. Columbia Journal of World Business, 27, 202–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (1982). Measurement costs and the organization of markets. Journal of Law and Economics, 25(1), 27–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben Youssef, H., Grolleau, G., & Jebsi, K. (2005). L’utilisation stratégique des instances de normalisation environnementale. Revue Internationale de Droit Economique, 4, 367–388.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besen, S. M., & Farrell, J. (1994). Choosing how to compete; Strategies and tactics in standardization. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(2), 117–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudreaux, D. J. (1990). Turning back the antitrust clock nonprice predation in theory and practice. The Cato Review of Business & Government, 13(3), 45–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bougherara, D., Grolleau, G., & Thiébaut, L. (2007). Benefiting from a clean environment versus undertaking efforts to protect the environment. Review of Agricultural Economics, 29(2), 216–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caswell, J. A. (2000). Labeling policy for GMOs: To each his own? AgBioForum. Published by Illinois Missouri Biotechnology Alliance 3 (1/Winter) (http://www.agbioforum.org/), Accessed 15 June 2006.

  • Coate, M. B., & Kleit, A. N. (1994). Exclusion, collusion, or confusion?: the underpinnings of raising rivals’ costs. Research in Law and Economics, 16, 73–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crespi, J., & Marette, S. (2001). How should food safety certification be financed. American Journal of Agricutural Economics, 83(4), 852–861.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Depken, G. A., & Ford, J. M. (1999). NAFTA as a means of raising rivals’ costs. Review of Industrial Organization, 15(2), 103–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Director, A., & Levi, E. H. (1956). Law and the future: Trade regulation. Northwestern University Law Review, 51, 281–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, R. J. (1981). Patents, sleeping patents, and entry deterrence. In Steven C. Salop (Eds.), Strategy, predation, and antitrust analysis (pp. 205–269). Washington D.C.: Federal Trade Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granitz, E., & Klein, B. (1996). Monopolization by raising rivals’ costs: The standard oil case. Journal of Law and Economic, 39, 1–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greaker, M. (2006). Eco-labels, trade and protectionism. Environmental and Resource Economics, 33, 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grodsky, J. A. (1993). Certified Green: The law and the future of environmental labeling. Yale Journal on Regulation, 10(1), 147–227.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grolleau, G., Lakhal, T., & Mzoughi, N. (2004). Does ethical activism lead to firm relocation? Kyklos International Review for Social Sciences, 3, 391–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grote, U. (1999). Sustainable development in the flower sector with eco-labels? Paper presented in the Deutscher Tropentag, Berlin.

  • Hilke, J. C., & Nelson, P. B. (1984). Noisy advertising and the predation rule in antitrust analysis. American Economic Review, 74(2), 367–371.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L., & Ursprung, H. W. (1992). The influence of environmental concerns on the political determination of trade policy. In Kym Anderson, Richard Blackhurst (Eds), The Greening of World Trade Issues (pp. 195–220). New York: Harvester Wheatcheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L., & Ursprung, H. W. (1994). Greens, Super greens, and International Trade Policy: Environmental concerns and protectionism. In Carlo Carraro (Eds.), Trade, innovation, environment (pp. 75–108). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karl, H., Orwat, C. (1999). Economic Aspects of Environmental Labelling. In Hank Folmer, Tom Tietenberg (Eds), Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 1999/2000 (pp. 107–170). UK: Edward Elgar Cheltenham.

    Google Scholar 

  • Körber, A. (1998). Why everybody loves flipper: The Political-Economy of the U.S. Dolphin-Safe laws. European Journal of Political Economy, 14(3), 475–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liemt, G. V. (2000). The World cut flower industry: Trends and prospects. International Labour Organization.

  • Lopatka, J. E., & Godek, P. E. (1992). Another look at ALCOA: Raising rivals’ costs does not improve the view. Journal of Law and Economics, 35, 311–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyon, T. P. (2003). Green firms bearing gifts. Regulation, 4, 36–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marquez, H. (2005). Americas: Tuna Ban—environmentalism or trade protectionism? Global Information Network, 14, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCluskey, J. (2000). A game theoretic approach to organic foods: An analysis of asymmetric information and policy. Agricultural and Resource Economics, 29, 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • McWilliams, A., Van Fleet, D. D., et al. (2002). Raising rivals’ costs through political strategy: An extension of resource-based theory. Journal of Management Studies, 39(5), 707–723.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, J., & Scarlett, L. (1996). Green groceries: Consumers, product labels and the environment. Policy Study, 217, 51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nadaï, A. (1998). Des conditions d’émergence d’un écolabel de produit. Qualification environnementale des produits et échange marchand. économie rurale. Agricultures, espaces, sociétés, 244, 32–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1957). Increased rents from increased costs: A paradox of value theory. Journal of Political Economy, 65, 287–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD, (2002). The development dimension of trade and environment: Case studies on environmental requirements and market access. Joint Working Party on Trade and Environment, OECD, Paris.

  • Pablo, S., & Fischer, R. (2000). Standards and protection. Journal of International Economics, 52(2), 377–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S., (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 1, 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piotrowski, R., & Kratz, S. (1999). Eco-Labeling in the globalized economy. International Politics and Society, 4, 430–443.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pirog, R., & Shuh, P. (2000). The load less traveled: Examining the potential of using food miles and CO2 emissions in eco-labels. In: Proceedings of a Conference Eco-labels and the Greening of the Food Market, Boston, Massachusetts, November 7–9.

  • Reinhardt, F. L. (2000). Down to earth: Applying business principles to environmental management(p. 291). Boston (MA): Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salop, S. C., & Scheffman, D. T. (1983). Raising rivals’ costs. The American Economic Review, 73, 267–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salop, S. C., & Scheffman, D. T. (1987). Cost-raising strategies. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 1, 19–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sasidharan, V., Sirakaya, E., & Kerstetter, D. (2002). Developing countries and tourism eco-labels. Tourism management, 23, 161–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sartzetakis, E. S. (1997). Raising rivals’ costs strategies via emission permits markets. Review of Industrial Organization, 12, 751–765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheffman, D. T. (1992). The application of raising rivals’ costs theory to antitrust. The Antitrust Bulletin Spring: 187–206.

  • Scheffman, D., & Higgins, R. S. (2003). 20 years of raising rivals’ costs: History, assessment, and future. George Mason Law Review, 12(2), 371–387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G., (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2, 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sturm, D., & Ulph, A., (2002). Environment and trade: The implications of imperfect information and political economy. World Trade Review, 1(3), 235–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teisl, M. F., & Roe, B. (1998). The economics of labeling: An overview of issues for health and environmental disclosure. Agriculture and Resource Economics Review, 27, 140–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tian, H. (2003). Eco-labelling scheme, environmental protection, and protectionism. Canadian Journal of Economics, 36(3), 608–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G., (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5, 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verbruggen, H., Kuik, O., & Bennis, M. (1995). Environmental regulations as trade barriers for developing countries: Eco-labeling and the Dutch cut flower industry. International Institute for Environment and Development, London.

  • Vitalis, V., (2002), Private voluntary eco-labels: Trade distorting, discriminatory and environmentally disappointing. Background Paper for the Round Table on Sustainable Development, Paris, December, 6th.

  • West, K. (1995). Eco-labels: The industrialization of environmental standards. The Ecologist, 25(1), 16–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wijk, J. V. (1994). Floriculture in Colombia. Biotechnology and Development Monitor, 20, 4–5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildavsky, B. (1996). Sticker shock. National Journal, 28(10), 532–534.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1968). Wage rates as a barrier to entry: The Pennington case. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82, 85–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WTO. (1998). Environmental labels and market access: Case study on the Colombian flower-growing industry (pp. 98–1038). Committee on Trade and Environment, Geneva, G/TBT/W/60.

  • Yandle, B. (1983). Bootleggers and baptists: The education of a regulatory economist. Regulation, 7(3), 12–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yandle, B. (1999a). Bootleggers and baptists in retrospect. Regulation, 22(3), 5–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yandle, B. (1999b). Public Choice at the Intersection of Environmental Law and Economics. European Journal of Law and Economics, 8, 5–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gilles Grolleau.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Grolleau, G., Ibanez, L. & Mzoughi, N. Industrialists hand in hand with environmentalists: how eco-labeling schemes can help firms to raise rivals’ costs. Eur J Law Econ 24, 215–236 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-007-9034-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-007-9034-6

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation