Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Corruption, interest rates and business cycles: comparison of emerging economies

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine the hypothesis that corruption in a country negatively influences the macroeconomy through an increase in the country-specific interest rate (interest rate shock). An empirical study estimated the contribution of the interest rate shocks to the variance in output growth at 5.1% in Mexico within the framework of stochastic growth models for small open economies. We replicate this study with the same dataset and investigate which parameters affect the contribution of the interest rate shocks to business cycles. Then, we estimate the same model for different emerging economies to investigate the relationship between the corruption level and macroeconomic contribution of the interest rate shocks. For this purpose, we use Transparency International’s Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI) to measure the corruption level. Finally, we investigate the correlation between the CPI and the estimated series of the interest rate shock. Our findings are as follows. First, the average size of the interest rate shocks is positively associated with the contribution of these shocks to the variability of output growth. Second, the average size of the interest rate shocks is also positively associated with the corruption level. Third, the estimated interest rate shock and the corruption level are positively correlated with each other. As we treat the corruption level as an exogenous variable in the model, these findings lead us to accept the hypothesis. The “Appendix” further clarifies a well-known hypothesis that the cycle is the trend in an emerging economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Viewed in December 2016. http://www.transparency.org/cpi2015.

  2. The prediction that corruption decreases investment is consistent with some empirical studies. Mauro (1995) argues that Bangladesh can increase its investment rate by approximately five percentage points by improving its bureaucratic efficiency to the level of Uruguay. Wei (2000) shows that the effect of an increase in corruption from the level of Singapore to that of Mexico on an inflow of foreign direct investment is equivalent to a tax increase of eighteen to fifty percentage points.

  3. A stationary autoregressive process of the first order can be written as a moving-average process of the infinite order. Therefore, the autoregressive process assumed in Eq. (10) is more flexible in describing the dynamics of the interest rate shock than it might appear.

  4. Equations (2), (3) and (7)–(11) imply that ε t accounts for the proportion of the changes in the interest rate that are not explained by changes in corruption, productivity shocks or external debt.

  5. The dataset is available at https://sites.google.com/site/andresfernandezmartin8/research. Viewed on 31 October 2016.

  6. Chang and Fernández (2013) also make available the J.P. Morgan’s EMBI+ spreads used by Uribe and Yue (2006) at the same website mentioned in the preceding footnote.

  7. The sources of quarterly data on GDP and its components and the annual data on population are the OECD and the World Bank, respectively. The annual data are interpolated by spline interpolation. The sample periods for ARG, BRA, CHL, COL, KOR, TUR and ZAF are 2004Q2–2016Q2, 1996Q2–2016Q3, 1995Q2–2016Q3, 2000Q2–2016Q3, 1994Q1–2016Q3, 1998Q2–2016Q3 and 1995Q1–2016Q3, respectively.

  8. The quarterly series of \(\epsilon^{R}\) is converted to annual data by taking the average of four quarters in each year.

References

  • Aguiar M, Gopinath G (2007) Emerging market business cycles: the cycle is the trend. J Polit Econ 115:69–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldacci E, Gupta S, Mati A (2011) Political and fiscal risk determinants of sovereign spreads in emerging markets. Rev Dev Econ 15:251–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert G, Harvey CR, Lundblad CT, Siegel S (2014) Political risk spread. J Int Bus Stud 45:471–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang R, Fernández A (2013) On the sources of aggregate fluctuations in emerging economies. Int Econ Rev 54:1265–1293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciocchini F, Durbin E, Ng DTC (2003) Does corruption increase emerging market bond spreads? J Econ Bus 55:503–528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dell M (2015) Trafficking networks and the Mexican drug war. Am Econ Rev 105:1738–1779

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felbab-Brown V (2009) The violent drug market in Mexico and lessons from Columbia. The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Fowowe B, Shuaibu MI (2014) Is foreign direct investment good for the poor? New evidence from African countries. Econ Change Restruct 47:321–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas X, Rochet JC (1997) Microeconomics of banking. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • García-Cicco J, Pancrazi R, Uribe M (2010) Real business cycles in emerging countries? Am Econ Rev 100:2510–2531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood J, Hercowitz Z, Huffman GW (1988) Investment, capacity utilization, and the real business cycle. Am Econ Rev 78:402–417

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann D, Wei SJ (1999) Does ‘grease money’ speed up the wheels of commerce? In: NBER working paper series no. 7093. Cambridge, Massachusetts

  • Kisswani KM, Nusair SA (2014) Nonlinear convergence in Asian interest and inflation rates: evidence from Asian countries. Econ Change Restruct 47:155–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauro P (1995) Corruption and growth. Q J Econ 110:681–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumeyer PA, Perri F (2005) Business cycles in emerging economies: the role of interest rates. J Monet Econ 52:345–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt-Grohé S, Uribe M (2003) Closing small open economy models. J Int Econ 61:163–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toro MC (1998) The political repercussions of drug trafficking in Mexico. In: Joyce E, Malamud C (eds) Latin America and the multinational drug trade. Macmillan Press, New York, pp 133–145

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Uribe M, Yue VZ (2006) Country spreads and emerging countries: who drives whom? J Int Econ 69:6–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei SJ (2000) How taxing is corruption on international investors? Rev Econ Stat 82:1–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams P (2009) Illicit markets, weak states and violence: Iraq and Mexico. Crime Law Soc Change 52:323–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author would like thank an anonymous referee for constructive comments. The author would also like to thank the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (JSPS) for financial support. This research is supported by the JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number 16K03683. The author would like to thank Enago (www.enago.com) for the English language review.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tomoya Suzuki.

Appendix

Appendix

A well-known hypothesis in the literature states that the cycle is the trend in an emerging economy. Aguiar and Gopinath (2007) estimate a stochastic growth model driven by productivity shocks for Canada and Mexico, finding that the contribution of permanent productivity shocks to the variance in output growth is greater in Mexico than in Canada. As a permanent productivity shocks generates a stochastic trend, this finding implies that a stochastic trend is a primary force driving business cycles in an emerging economy like Mexico. However, García-Cicco et al. (2010) augment the model by considering not only productivity shocks but also non-productivity shocks and estimate the augmented model for Argentina over a long sample period of 1900–2005. They find that permanent productivity shocks account only for a small proportion of the variance in output growth, which leads them to reject the hypothesis that the cycle is the trend. Chang and Fernández (2013) reject the same hypothesis by estimating models like the one laid out by García-Cicco et al. (2010) with the dataset used by Aguiar and Gopinath (2007).

The fourth section estimates the benchmark model of Chang and Fernández (2013) for eight emerging economies. Table 9 shows the forecast-error variance decompositions for a 40-quarter horizon. Temporary productivity shocks account for the largest proportion of the variance in output growth in six of the eight countries, which is consistent with the rejection of the hypothesis. In contrast, permanent productivity shocks account for 84.6 and 66.7% of the variance in output growth for COL and ZAF, respectively. The large contribution of permanent productivity shocks to the variance in output growth supports the hypothesis. Not surprisingly, the choice of the sample affects whether we can accept or reject the hypothesis that the cycle is the trend in an emerging economy.

Table 9 Contributions of three shocks to the variance in output growth

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Suzuki, T. Corruption, interest rates and business cycles: comparison of emerging economies. Econ Change Restruct 51, 303–316 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-017-9206-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-017-9206-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation