Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal Waste Disposal Fees When Product Durability is Endogenous: Accounting for Planned Obsolescence

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Considering the Coase conjecture (J Law Econ 15:143–149, 1972), we explore the optimal disposal fee of solid waste through the choice of product durability by a producer. We find that introducing a disposal fee curbs planned obsolescence and increases product durability. This increased durability decreases the social cost of waste and increases the service flow from the durable product. Therefore, the optimal disposal fee is higher than the Pigouvian level in the closed-loop.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Waste policies have been set for a wide variety of durable products. For example, European battery producers are required to collect 45% of used batteries. In Japan, the Automobile Recycling Law, established in 2002, demands that consumers pay the disposal fees at the time of purchase of cars. In Canada, when buying new tires, consumers are responsible for paying a fee per tire under a waste disposal scheme called the “tire stewardship program,” which is transferred to the provincial tire recycling agency and is used to help cover the cost of collecting, transporting, and recycling scrap tires.

  2. Most previous studies have paid attention to the recyclability as DfE. For example, see Calcott and Walls (2000, 2005) and Fullerton and Wu (1998).

  3. In this study, we assume that excess waste generation is due to low product durability, which then raises demand and increases the amount of waste. However, the energy consumption of highly durable products may be less efficient than that of new durable products. Since this study focuses on product durability as a feature of DfE, to simplify our analysis, we ignore the energy efficiency of durable products.

  4. See also Bond and Samuelson (1984), Bulow (1982), Hendel and Lizzeri (1999), Kinokuni (1999), Kinokuni et al. (2010) and Waldman (1996). Waldman (2003) provides a comprehensive survey of the theory of durable products.

  5. As Guiltinan (2009) mentions, the environmental forms of planned obsolescence include limiting functional life design (or “death dating”), designing for limited repair, and choosing design aesthetics that lead to reduced satisfaction.

  6. For simplicity, we assume that the environmental damage cost is a linear function of the amount of waste.

  7. A central issue of our study is the time-inconsistency problem for the producer. If we assume that the municipality also adopts a different disposal fee in each period in addition to the producer, the time-inconsistency problems of both players complicate our model. To avoid these complications and obtain clear results, we assume a time-independent disposal fee.

  8. The parameter condition for this restriction is given by (22).

  9. Runkel (2003) demonstrates that a waste tax has a waste-reducing effect and a waste-delaying effect in his open-loop model. Our closed-loop model shows that the disposal fee has corresponding effects and alleviates the time-inconsistency problem the monopolistic producer faces.

  10. Appendix B extends our analysis to the case of \(\tau + k \ge {\tilde{K}}\).

  11. For a review of theoretical studies of environmental policy under imperfect competition, see Requate (2006).

  12. If the monopolist supplies durable goods to consumers by a rental contract, it can commit the future stock of the durable goods in the market. Therefore, the equilibrium of the rental case of the durable goods monopoly corresponds to the open-loop equilibrium of the sales case. See Bulow (1982; 1986).

  13. Shinkuma (2007) shows that an exogenous disposal fee, which equals the marginal disposal cost, attains the social optimum in the perfectly competitive durable goods market by using an infinite-horizon model where product durability is affected by consumers’ repairing rather than producers’ decisions.

References

  • Bond E, Samuelson L (1984) Durable good monopolies with rational expectations and replacement sales. RAND J Econ 15:336–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bulow J (1982) Durable-goods monopolists. J Polit Econ 90:314–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bulow J (1986) An economic theory of planned obsolescence. Q J Econ 101:729–749

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calcott P, Walls M (2000) Can downstream waste disposal policies encourage upstream “design for environment”? Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 90:233–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calcott P, Walls M (2005) Waste, recycling and ‘Design for environment’: roles for markets and policy instruments. Resour Energy Econ 27:287–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase R (1972) Durability and monopoly. J Law Econ 15:143–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubois M, Eyckmans J (2015) Efficient waste management policies and strategic behavior with open borders. Environm Resour Econ 62:907–923

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fethke G, Jagannathan R (2002) Monopoly with endogenous durability. J Econ Dyn Control 26:1009–1027

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleckinger P, Glachant M (2010) The organization of extended producer responsibility in waste policy with product differentiation. J Environ Econ Manag 59:57–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton D, Wu W (1998) Policies for green design. J Environ Econ Manag 36:131–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiltinan J (2009) Creative destruction and destructive creations: environmental ethics and planned obsolescence. J Bus Ethics 89:19–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendel I, Lizzeri A (1999) Interfering with secondary markets. RAND J Econ 30:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ino H (2011) Optimal environmental policy for waste disposal and recycling when firms are not compliant. J Environ Econ Manag 62:290–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kinokuni H (1999) Repair market structure, product durability, and monopoly. Aust Econ Pap 38:343–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kinokuni H, Ohkawa T, Okamura M (2010) Planned antiobsolescence occurs when consumers engage in maintenance. Int J Ind Organ 28:441–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Requate T (2006) Environmental policy under imperfect competition. In: Tietenberg T, Folmer H (eds) The international Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 2006/2007, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar, pp 120–207

  • Runkel M (2003) Product durability and extended producer responsibility in solid waste management. Environ Resour Econ 24:161–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shinkuma T (2007) Reconsideration of an advance disposal fee policy for end-of-life durable goods. J Environ Econ Manag 53:110–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swan P (1970) Durability of consumption goods. Am Econ Rev 60:884–894

    Google Scholar 

  • Swan P (1971) The durability of goods and regulation of monopoly. Bell J Econ Manag Sci 2:347–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldman M (1996) Durable goods pricing when quality matters. J Bus 69:489–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldman M (2003) Durable goods theory for real world markets. J Econ Perspect 17:131–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the editor, the two anonymous referees, Masanobu Ishikawa, Tomomichi Mizuno, Akihisa Shibata, Takayoshi Shinkuma, Kenji Takeuchi, Tomoki Fujii, and Makoto Yano. This research was supported by MEXT/JSPS KAKENHI Grant Numbers 26380338 and 26380344.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shuichi Ohori.

Appendices

Appendix A: The derivations of (10), (12), (13), and (16)

Here, we solve the multi-stage game. In stage 6, the household discards \(G_2\). At this time, the SWM sector collects and disposes them. In stage 5, the household maximizes \(u_2\) subject to (8) by x and \(q_2\). The Lagrangian for this problem is

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathscr {L}}_2 = x_2 + (Dq_1+q_2) \left( a - \frac{Dq_1+q_2}{2} \right) + \lambda \left\{ RS - x_2- p_2q_2-(Dq_1 +q_2)f \right\} , \end{aligned}$$

where \(\lambda \) is the multiplier. The first-order conditions for this problem are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\mathscr {L}}_2}{\partial x_2}= & {} 1 - \lambda = 0, \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\mathscr {L}}_2}{\partial q_2}= & {} a-Dq_1-q_2-\lambda p_2 -\lambda f = 0 \;\;\;\; \text {and} \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\mathscr {L}}_2}{\partial \lambda }= & {} RS -x_2-p_2q_2 - (Dq_1 +q_2)f =0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

From (A.1) and (A.2), we have the second-period inverse demand function (10). In stage 4, the producer chooses \(q_2\), which maximizes \(\pi _2=p_2q_2 -C_2\), given the first-period decisions \(q_1\) and D. The first-order condition for the producer’s profit maximization in period 2 is given by (11). Then, we have (12).

Next, we consider the first-period decisions. In stage 3, the household discards \(G_1\). At this time, the SWM sector collects and disposes them. In stage 2, the household maximizes (6) subject to (9) by choosing \(x_1\) and \(q_1\). The second-period price and quantity are given for the representative household. The Lagrangian for this problem is

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathscr {L}}_1= & {} x_1 + q_1 \left( a - \frac{q_1}{2} \right) \\&+\, \delta \left\{ x_2 + (Dq_1+q_2) \left( a - \frac{Dq_1+q_2}{2} \right) \right\} \\&+ \,\mu \left\{ I - x_1 - p_1q_1- (1-D)q_1f -\frac{1}{R}x_2-\frac{1}{R}p_2q_2 -\frac{1}{R}(Dq_1 +q_2 )f \right\} , \end{aligned}$$

where \(\mu \) is the multiplier. The first-order conditions for this problem are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\mathscr {L}}_1}{\partial x_1}= & {} 1 - \mu = 0, \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\mathscr {L}}_1}{\partial q_1}= & {} a - q_1+ \delta D(a-Dq_1-q_2) -\mu p_1-\mu (1-D)f \nonumber \\&-\, \mu \delta Df = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\mathscr {L}}_1}{\partial \mu }= & {} I - x_1 - p_1q_1 -(1-D)q_1 f- \frac{1}{R}x_2 \nonumber \\&-\, \frac{1}{R}p_2q_2 -\frac{1}{R} (Dq_1+q_2) f =0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

From (A.1), (A.2), (A.4), and (A.5) and considering \(R^{-1}=\delta \), we have the first-period inverse demand function (13).

In stage 1, the profit given (10), (13), and \(q_2(q_1,D)\) defined in (12) is

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi (q_1,D)= & {} \{ p_1(q_1, D, q_2(q_1,D)) - (1+\delta D)c \} q_1 \nonumber \\&+\,\delta \{ p_2(q_1, D, q_2(q_1,D)) -c \} q_2(q_1,D). \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

The producer chooses not only \(q_1\) but also D, which maximizes (A.7), given (10), (12), and (13). The first-order conditions for the producer’s overall profit maximization are given by (14) and (15). From (12), (14), and (15), we have the equilibrium (16).

Appendix B: Optimal disposal fee in the closed-loop equilibrium without planned obsolescence

First, we examine the market equilibrium where the monopolist does not practice planned obsolescence. If \({\tilde{f}} \equiv \frac{\delta }{4+\delta } (a-c) \le f\), durability reaches the upper bound. By substituting \(D=1\) into (12) and (14), we have

$$\begin{aligned} D^{CL2}=1, \;\; q_1^{CL2} = \frac{2}{4+\delta }(a-c) \;\; \text {and} \;\; q_2^{CL2} = \frac{2+\delta }{2(4+\delta )}(a-c)-\frac{1}{2}f, \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

where the superscript CL2 denotes the closed-loop equilibrium without planned obsolescence. We restrict our analysis to the interior solution of \(q_2\). Otherwise, the case is \(q_2=0\), that is, the producer can commit to the future production schedule. In other words, the case contradicts the assumption of the closed-loop strategy. The condition for \(q_2>0\) is given as \(f < {\bar{f}} \equiv \frac{2+\delta }{4+\delta }(a-c)\).

Next, we derive the optimal disposal fee in the closed-loop equilibrium when \({\tilde{f}} \le f < {\bar{f}}\). Without planned obsolescence, social welfare is

$$\begin{aligned} W^{CL2}= & {} \left\{ a - \frac{q_1^{CL2}}{2} - c \right\} q_1^{CL2} + \delta \left( a- \frac{q_1^{CL2}+q_2^{CL2} }{2}-c \right) (q_1^{CL2}+q_2^{CL2}) \nonumber \\&-\, \delta (\tau +k)(q_1^{CL2}+q_2^{CL2}). \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)

The first-order condition of welfare maximization yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dW^{CL2}}{df}= & {} \delta \{ a-(q_1^{CL2}+q_2^{CL2}) -c -(\tau +k) \} \frac{dq_2^{CL2}}{df} \nonumber \\= & {} \delta \left[ a- \left\{ \frac{(6+\delta )(a-c)}{2(4+\delta )}-\frac{1}{2}f \right\} -c-(\tau + k) \right] \frac{dq_2^{CL2}}{df} =0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)

From (A.10), the optimal disposal fee without planned obsolescence is

$$\begin{aligned} f^{CL2} = 2(\tau + k) -\frac{2+\delta }{4+\delta } (a-c). \end{aligned}$$
(A.11)

The condition that makes \(f^{CL2}\) an interior solution is given by \({\tilde{f}} \le f^{CL2} < {\bar{f}}\); this is rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1+\delta }{4+\delta } \equiv {\widehat{K}} \le \tau + k < \frac{2+\delta }{4+\delta }(a-c) \equiv {\bar{K}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.12)

Under condition (A.12), the optimal disposal fee is lower than the Pigouvian level since

$$\begin{aligned} f^{CL2} - (\tau +k) = (\tau +k) -\frac{2+\delta }{4+\delta }(a-c) <0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.13)

Finally, we consider the globally optimal disposal fee that includes cases both with and without planned obsolescence. From (22) and (A.12), we have the following relationship:

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{K}}< {\widehat{K}} < {\bar{K}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.14)

Moreover, we know that \(f^{CL}\) is optimal if \(\tau + k < {\widetilde{K}}\) and \(f^{CL2}\) is optimal if \({\widehat{K}} \le \tau +k < {\bar{K}}\). Thus, our remaining problem is to investigate the optimal disposal fee when

$$\begin{aligned} {\widetilde{K}} \le \tau +k < {\widehat{K}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.15)

(A.15) is rewritten as \(f^{CL2}<{\tilde{f}} \le f^{CL}\). This condition implies that neither \(f^{CL}\) nor \(f^{CL2}\) is a solution. From (20) and (A.15), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{dW^{CL}}{df} \right| _{f={\tilde{f}}} = \frac{1}{2\delta (4+\delta )} \{ (4+\delta )(4-\delta +\delta ^2)(\tau +k)-\delta ^3(a-c) \} <0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.16)

From (A.10) and (A.15), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{dW^{CL2}}{df} \right| _{f={\tilde{f}}} = -\frac{\delta }{2(4+\delta )} \{ (1+\delta )(a-c)-(4+\delta )(\tau +k) \} >0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.17)

In addition, from (16), (19), and (A.9), the social welfare function is continuous at \(f={\tilde{f}}\),

$$\begin{aligned}&\left. W^{CL} \right| _{f={\tilde{f}}} = \left. W^{CL2} \right| _{f={\tilde{f}}} \nonumber \\&\quad = \frac{a-c}{2(4+\delta )^2} \{ (12+19\delta +6\delta ^2)(a-c)-6\delta (4+\delta )(\tau +k) \}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.18)

Because the social welfare functions are single-peaked, (A.16), (A.17), and (A.18) imply that the social welfare function is continuous, monotonically increasing when \(f<{\tilde{f}}\) and monotonically decreasing when \({\tilde{f}} <f\). Therefore, we conclude that \({\tilde{f}}\) is optimal if (A.15) holds.

Summarizing above results, in our closed-loop model the globally optimal disposal fee \(f^*\) is the following:

$$\begin{aligned} f^* = \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} f^{CL} &{} if \;\; \tau +k< {\widetilde{K}} \\ {\tilde{f}} &{} if \;\; {\tilde{K}} \le \tau + k< {\widehat{K}} \\ f^{CL2} &{} if \;\; {\widehat{K}} \le \tau + k < {\bar{K}}. \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(A.19)

Appendix C: The derivations of (24) and (25)

We consider the open-loop maximization problem of the monopolistic producer. The first-order derivatives of (3) yield

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_1}= & {} p_1 -(1+\delta D)c +\frac{\partial p_1}{\partial q_1}q_1 + \delta \frac{\partial p_2}{\partial q_1} q_2 \nonumber \\= & {} a -2q_1 +\delta D(a-2Dq_1 -q_2)-(1-D)f-\delta Df \nonumber \\&-\,(1+\delta D)c- \delta Dq_2 \end{aligned}$$
(A.20)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_2}= & {} \frac{\partial p_1}{\partial q_2} q_1 + \delta \left( p_2 -c+ \frac{\partial p_2}{\partial q_2} q_2 \right) \nonumber \\= & {} -\,\delta Dq_1 + \delta (a-Dq_1 -2q_2 -f)- \delta c \end{aligned}$$
(A.21)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D}= & {} \left( \frac{\partial p_1}{\partial D} - \delta c \right) q_1 + \delta \frac{\partial p_2}{\partial D} q_2 \nonumber \\= & {} \delta (a-2Dq_1-q_2)q_1 + (1-\delta )f q_1 -\delta cq_1 -\delta q_1 q_2. \end{aligned}$$
(A.22)

In order that the producer provides a positive amount of durable products in the first period, \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_1}=0\) must be valid. If \(f=0\), however, from (A.21) and (A.22), we have \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_2}=\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D}\). Thus, we classify this into two cases: \(f>0\) and \(f=0\).

Case I: :

\(f > 0\). This case is classified into three sub-cases, namely \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} = 0\), \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} < 0\), and \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} > 0\), which respectively correspond to \(D^{OL} \in (0,1)\), \(D^{OL}=0\), and \(D^{OL}=1\).

Case I-1: :

\(f > 0\) and \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} = 0\). From (A.21), (A.22), and \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} = 0\), we have \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_2} <0\). This condition leads to a corner solution \(q_2 =0\). Thus, the conditions \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_1}=0\), \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} = 0\), and \(q_2 =0\) lead to \(q_1 = \frac{1}{2} (a-c-f)\) and \(D=1+ \frac{f}{\delta (a-c-f)} >1\). However, \(D>1\) contradicts the case requirement, \(D^{OL} \in (0,1)\); this implies that case I-1 never holds in equilibrium.

Case I-2: :

\(f > 0\) and \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} < 0\). From (A.21) and (A.22), if \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} < 0\), then \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_2} < 0\). The conditions \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} < 0\) and \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_2} < 0\) lead to the corner solutions \(D^{OL} =0\) and \(q_2^{OL}=0\). Because \(Q_2=Dq_1 + q_2\), we have \(Q_2=0\). This implies that the market vanishes in the second period despite the existence of market demand (10). Therefore, this case does not hold in equilibrium.

Case I-3: :

\(f > 0\) and \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D} > 0\). This case implies that \(D^{OL}=1\). From (A.20) and \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_1}=0\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} a-2q_1 = \frac{2\delta }{1+\delta }q_2 + c + \frac{\delta }{1+\delta } f. \end{aligned}$$
(A.23)

By substituting (A.23) into (A.21), we have \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_2} = - \frac{2 \delta }{1+\delta } q_2 - \frac{\delta }{1+\delta } f <0\). This leads to the corner solution \(q_2^{OL}=0\). By substituting \(q_2^{OL}=0\) into (A.23), we have (24). From the above three sub-cases, we find that (24) is the only equilibrium if \(f>0\).

Case II: :

\(f = 0\). As mentioned above, \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_2} = \frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D}\) is valid. From \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_1}=0\), \(\frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial q_2} = \frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial D}=0\), (A.20), and (A.21), we have (25).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kinokuni, H., Ohori, S. & Tomoda, Y. Optimal Waste Disposal Fees When Product Durability is Endogenous: Accounting for Planned Obsolescence. Environ Resource Econ 73, 33–50 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0248-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0248-6

Keywords

Navigation