Skip to main content
Log in

Bargaining Over Environmental Budgets: A Political Economy Model with Application to French Water Policy

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In decentralized water management with earmarked budgets financed by user taxes and distributed back in the form of subsidies, net gains are often heterogeneous across user categories. This paper explores the role of negotiation over budget allocation and coalition formation in water boards, to provide an explanation for such user-specific gaps between tax payments and subsidies. We propose a bargaining model to represent the sequential nature of the negotiation process in water districts, in which stakeholder representatives may bargain upon a fraction of the budget only. The structural model of budget shares estimated from the data on French Water Agencies performs well as compared with reduced-form estimation. Empirical results confirm the two-stage bargaining process and provide evidence for systematic net gains from the system for agricultural water users.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Several empirical analyses of the BF bargaining model have been conducted, including Knight (2004, 2005) on decisions of the US House Committee on Transportation and Infrastructure, Ferejohn (1974) and Lewitt and Poterba (1999) on federal spending and representation by congressional delegations, Eraslan (2008) on bargaining in the BF vein in corporate finance, and Diermeier and Merlo (2004) on the analysis of the formation of coalition governments in Europe.

  2. For any real number x, \(\left\lfloor x\right\rfloor \) denotes the smallest integer greater than x.

  3. A coalition S is a winning one if and only if \(\sum _{i\in S}q_{i}\ge Q\). If, moreover, by dropping any player j we reverse the inequality, i.e., \( \sum _{i\in S\backslash \left\{ j\right\} }q_{i}<Q\) for any \(j\in S\), then such a coalition S is called minimal winning.

  4. The component \(x_{ij}\) is the share of the budget offered to player i by proposer j.

  5. This result implies that if n is odd, then the equilibrium is unique. However, if n is even, there is no single middle value, and the median is then can be defined as the mean of the two middle values.

  6. In our setting, a difference is that the disagreement payoffs correspond to the relative amount of taxes paid.

  7. This evidence is provided by interviews conducted by the authors with the deputy-CEO of the Adour-Garonne water agency on April 24, 2012, officials of the same Agency’s economic division, and members of the Adour-Garonne RBC on April 1, 2011.

  8. According to the representative of industrial water users, Mr. Yves Casenove, “it is only with a global evaluation of subsidies and taxes that an objective comparison across user categories can be achieved. Such procedure has no other goal but to make sure the distribution of the budget is organized within reasonable bounds, in order to make progress in the concertation” (Adour-Garonne River Basin Committee meeting, July 4, 2011, Toulouse).

  9. Subsidy figures from Water Agencies are detailed by final user but, from a non-budgetary point of view, there may be indirect beneficiaries to projects. For example, abatement projects for livestock farmers may be beneficial in terms of raw water quality to residential users; extension of a water distribution network may benefit industrial plants within city bounds, etc. We acknowledge this can be a source of bias which cannot be corrected given available data, but from a strictly budgetary point of view, final beneficiaries from subsidy decisions are correctly identified.

References

  • Banks JS, Duggan J (2000) A bargaining model of collective choice. Am Polit Sci Rev 94(1):73–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron DP, Ferejohn JA (1989) Bargaining in legislatures. Am Polit Sci Rev 83:1181–1206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carraro C, Sgobbi A (2011) A stochastic multiple players, multi-issues bargaining model for the Piave River Bassin. Strateg Behav Environ 1(2):119–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carraro C, Marchiori C, Sgobbi A (2005) Application to negotiation theory to water issues. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3641

  • Carraro C, Siniscalco D (1993) International protection of the environment. J public Econ 52:309–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CGDD (2012) Valuation of environmental goods and services: use and best practices (in French). In: Katossky A, Marcus V (eds) Commissariat for sustainable development working paper 78, Ministry of the Environment, Paris (November)

  • Diermeier D, Merlo A (2004) An empirical investigation of coalitional bargaining procedures. J Public Econ 88:783–797

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eraslan H (2008) Corporate Bankruptcy reorganizations: estimates from a bargaining model. Int Econ Rev 49(2):659–681

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn J (1974) Pork Barrel politics: rivers and harbors legislation 1947–1968. Stanford University Press, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • Gatti R, Goeschl T, Groom B, Swanson T (2011) The biodiversity bargaining problem. Environ Resour Econ 48:609–628

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall AR, Pelletier D (2015) Non-nested testing in models estimated via generalized method of moments. Econometric Theory 27(2):443–456

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hattori K (2010) Strategic voting for noncooperative environmental policies in open economies. Environ Resou Econ 46:459–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kauppi H, Widgrén M (2004) What determines EU decision making? Needs, power or both? Econ Policy 19(39):221–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight B (2004) Parochial interests and the centralized provision of local public goods: evidence from congressional voting on transportation projects. J Public Econ 88:845–866

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight B (2005) Estimating the value of proposal power. Am Econ Rev 95(5):1639–1652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lessmann K, Kornek U, Bosetti V, Dellink R, Emmerling J, Eyckmans J, Nagashima M, Weikard H, Yang Z (2015) The stability and effectiveness of climate coalitions. A comparative analysis of multiple integrated assessment models. Environ Resour Econ. doi:10.1007/s10640-015-9886-0

  • Lewitt SD, Poterba JM (1999) Congressional distributive politics and state economic performance. Public Choice 99:185–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moro D, Sckokai P (1999) Modelling the CAP arable crop regime in Italy: degree of decoupling and impact of agenda 2000. Rev Agric Environ Stud 53:49–73

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2011) Water governance in OECD countries: a multi-level approach. OECD Studies on Water, OECD Publishing, Paris

  • Proost S, Zaporozhets V (2013) The political economy of fixed regional public expenditure shares with an illustration for Belgian railway investments. Region Sci Urban Econ 43(5):808–815

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivers D, Vuong Q (2002) Model selection tests for nonlinear dynamic models. Econom J 5:1–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seroa da Motta R, Thomas A, Hazin L Saade, Feres JG, Nauges C, Hazin Saade (2004) Economic instruments for water management. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

  • Simon LK, Thoyer S, Morardet S, Goodhue RE, Rio P, Rausser GC (2006) Structure and bargaining power in multilateral negotiations: applications to water management policies in France, LAMETA Working Paper n2006–09

  • Smith RJ (1992) Non-nested tests for competing model sestimated by generalized method of moments. Econometrica 60(4):973–980

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thoyer S, Morardet S, Rio P, Simon L, Goodhue R, Rausser G (2001) A bargaining model to simulate negotiations between water users. J Artif Soc Soc Simul. http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/4/2/6.html

  • Van Egteren H, Tang J (1997) Maximum Victim benefit: a fair division process in transboundary pollution problems. Environ Resour Econ 10:363–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang H, Mamingi N, Laplante B, Dasgupta S (2003) Incomplete enforcement of pollution regulation: bargaining power of chinese factories. Environ Resou Econ 24:245–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watson N, Howe J (2006) Implementing the EU water framework directive: experiences of participatory planning in the Ribble Basin, North West England. Water Int 31(4):472–487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weikard H, Dellink R, Van Ierland E (2010) Renegotiations in the greenhouse. Environ Resour Econ 45:573–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alban Thomas.

Additional information

The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Adour-Garonne Water Agency. They wish to thank Bruno Cinotti, Frédéric Caméo-Ponz, Jean-Michel Grandmont, Kerry Krutilla, Cuong Le Van and Stéphane Robichon for helpful comments and discussions. We thank Michel Le Breton for very helpful discussions on a first version of this paper.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proof of Proposition 1

Taking derivatives of V with respect to \(\alpha \) one gets:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{i}^{\prime }\left( \alpha \right)= & {} -\widehat{p}_{i}u_{i}^{\prime }\left( \gamma _{i}+(1-\alpha )\sum _{j\in N\backslash (S_{i}\cup \left\{ i\right\} )}\gamma _{j}\right) \sum _{j\in N\backslash (S_{i}\cup \left\{ i\right\} )}\gamma _{j} \nonumber \\&+\left( 1-\widehat{p}_{i}-P_{i}\right) u_{i}^{\prime }(\alpha \gamma _{i})\gamma _{i}. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

and

$$\begin{aligned} V_{i}^{\prime \prime }\left( \alpha \right)= & {} \widehat{p}_{i}u_{i}^{\prime \prime }\left( \gamma _{i}+(1-\alpha )\sum _{j\in N\backslash (S_{i}\cup \left\{ i\right\} )}\gamma _{j}\right) \left( \sum _{j\in N\backslash (S_{i}\cup \left\{ i\right\} )}\gamma _{j}\right) ^{2} \nonumber \\&+\left( 1-\widehat{p}_{i}-P_{i}\right) u_{i}^{\prime \prime }(\alpha \gamma _{i})\left( \gamma _{i}\right) ^{2}. \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Since \(u_{i}^{\prime \prime }(\cdot )<0\) it follows from (24) that \( V_{i}^{\prime \prime }\left( \alpha \right) \le 0\).

From (23) it follows that:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{i}^{\prime }\left( 1\right) =u_{i}^{\prime }(\gamma _{i})\left[ \left( 1- \widehat{p}_{i}-P_{i}\right) \gamma _{i} - \widehat{p}_{i}\sum _{j\in N\backslash (S^{i}\cup \left\{ i\right\} ) }\gamma _{j}\right] . \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, for \(\gamma _{i}\ge \overline{\gamma }_{i}=\left( \widehat{p}_{i}\sum _{j\in N\backslash (S_{i}\cup \left\{ i\right\} )}\gamma _{j}\right) /\left( 1- \widehat{p}_{i}-P_{i}\right) \), the function \(V_{i}^{\prime }\left( 1\right) \ge 0\), and for \(\gamma _{i}\le \overline{\gamma }_{i}\) the opposite inequality holds true.

The derivative of V at \(\alpha =0\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{i}^{\prime }\left( 0\right) =-\widehat{p}_{i}u_{i}^{\prime }\left( \sum _{j\in N\backslash S_{i}}\gamma _{j}\right) \sum _{j\in N\backslash (S_{i}\cup \left\{ i\right\} )} \gamma _{j} + (1-\widehat{p}_{i}-P_{i})u_{i}^{ \prime }(0)\gamma _{i}. \end{aligned}$$

One can check that: \(V_{i}^{\prime }\left( 0\right) \le 0\) if and only if \( \gamma _{i}\le \underline{\gamma }_{i}\), where \(\underline{\gamma }_{i}\) satisfies (14).

Since \(u_{i}^{\prime \prime }\le 0\) we can deduce that \(u_{i}^{\prime }(0)\ge u_{i}^{\prime }\left( \sum _{j\in N\backslash S^{i}}\gamma _{j}\right) \). Substituting this into (14) we prove that \( \underline{\gamma }_{i}\le \overline{\gamma }_{i}\).

Summing up, for \(0\le \gamma _{i}\le \underline{\gamma }_{i}\) the function \(V_{i}\left( \alpha \right) \) is decreasing on the whole interval \(\left[ 0,1 \right] \), for \(\gamma _{i}\ge \overline{\gamma }_{i}\) it is increasing on the whole interval, and for \(\underline{\gamma }<\gamma _{i}<\overline{ \gamma }_{i}\) it has unique maximum on the interval \(\left[ 0,1\right] \).

Appendix 2: Derivation of Optimal \(\alpha ^* \)

From Proposition 1, the thresholds for group 2 are:

$$\begin{aligned} \overline{\gamma }_{2}= & {} \frac{\widehat{p}_{2}\gamma _{3}}{\widehat{p}_{3}} \text { and} \\ \underline{\gamma }_{2}= & {} \frac{\widehat{p}_{2}\gamma _{3}u_{2}^{\prime }\left( \gamma _{2}+\gamma _{3}\right) }{\widehat{p}_{3}u_{2}^{\prime }\left( 0\right) }. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, the behavior of player 2 can be described as follows:

  • for \(\displaystyle {\frac{\gamma _{3}}{\gamma _{2}} < \frac{\widehat{p}_{3}}{ \widehat{p}_{2}}}\), function \(V_{2}\left( \alpha \right) \) increases on the whole interval \(\left[ 0,1\right] \) and therefore \(\alpha _{2}^{*}=1\);

  • for \(\displaystyle {\frac{\widehat{p}_{3}}{\widehat{p}_{2}} < \frac{\gamma _{3}}{\gamma _{2}}<\frac{\widehat{p}_{3}}{\widehat{p}_{2}}\frac{ u_{2}^{\prime }(0)}{u_{2}^{\prime }\left( \gamma _{2}+\gamma _{3}\right) }}\) , function \(V_{2}\left( \alpha \right) \) has an inferior maximum \(\alpha _{2}^{*}\) on \(\left[ 0,1\right] \) which is defined from the equality \( V_{2}^{\prime }\left( \alpha \right) =0\), that is,

    $$\begin{aligned} -\widehat{p}_{2}u_{2}^{\prime }\left( \alpha \gamma _{2}+(1-\alpha ) \left( 1-\gamma _{1}\right) \right) \gamma _{3}+\widehat{p}_{3}u_{2}^{\prime }(\alpha \gamma _{2})\gamma _{2}=0\text {;} \end{aligned}$$
    (25)
  • for \(\displaystyle {\frac{\gamma _{3}}{\gamma _{2}} > \frac{\widehat{p}_{3}}{ \widehat{p}_{2}}\frac{u_{2}^{\prime }(0)}{u_{2}^{\prime }\left( \gamma _{2}+\gamma _{3}\right) }}\), function \(V_{2}\left( \alpha \right) \) is decreasing on the whole interval \(\left[ 0,1\right] \) and therefore \(\alpha _{2}^{*}=0\).

In a similar way, the thresholds on the tax share for player 3 can be expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \overline{\gamma }_{3}= & {} \frac{\widehat{p}_{3}\gamma _{2}}{1-\widehat{p}_{3}} \text { and} \\ \underline{\gamma }_{3}= & {} \frac{\widehat{p}_{3}\gamma _{2}u_{3}^{\prime }\left( \gamma _{2}+\gamma _{3}\right) }{\left( 1-\widehat{p}_{3}\right) u_{3}^{\prime }\left( 0\right) }. \end{aligned}$$

The behavior of player 3 can be summarized as:

  • for \(\displaystyle {\frac{\gamma _{3}}{\gamma _{2}} < \frac{\widehat{p}_{3}}{ 1-\widehat{p}_{3}}\frac{u_{3}^{\prime }\left( \gamma _{2}+\gamma _{3}\right) }{u_{3}^{\prime }(0)}}\) function \(V_{3}\left( \alpha \right) \) is decreasing on the whole interval \(\left[ 0,1\right] \) and therefore \(\alpha _{3}^{*}=0\);

  • for \(\displaystyle {\frac{\widehat{p}_{3}}{1-\widehat{p}_{3}}\frac{ u_{3}^{\prime }\left( \gamma _{2}+\gamma _{3}\right) }{u_{3}^{\prime }(0)}< \frac{\gamma _{3}}{\gamma _{2}}<\frac{\widehat{p}_{3}}{1-\widehat{p}_{3}}}\), function \(V_{3}\left( \alpha \right) \) has an inferior maximum \(\alpha _{3}^{*}\) on \(\left[ 0,1\right] \) and it is defined from \(V_{3}^{\prime }\left( \alpha \right) =0\):

    $$\begin{aligned} -\widehat{p}_{3}u_{3}^{\prime }\left( \alpha \gamma _{3} + (1-\alpha ) \left( 1-\gamma _{1}\right) \right) \gamma _{2}+(1-\widehat{p}_{3})u_{3}^{\prime }(\alpha \gamma _{3})\gamma _{3}=0\text {;} \end{aligned}$$
    (26)
  • for \(\displaystyle {\frac{\gamma _{3}}{\gamma _{2}} > \frac{\widehat{p}_{3}}{ 1-\widehat{p}_{3}}}\), function \(V_{3}\left( \alpha \right) \) is increasing on the whole interval \(\left[ 0,1\right] \) and therefore \(\alpha _{3}^{*}=1\).

We can identify the median voter: it is either player 2 if \(\displaystyle { \frac{\gamma _{3}}{\gamma _{2}} > \frac{\widehat{p}_{3}}{\widehat{p}_{2}}}\) or player 3 if the opposite inequality holds.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Thomas, A., Zaporozhets, V. Bargaining Over Environmental Budgets: A Political Economy Model with Application to French Water Policy. Environ Resource Econ 68, 227–248 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0013-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0013-7

Keywords

Navigation