Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Aiding Decision Making to Reduce the Impacts of Climate Change

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Consumer Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Utilizing theory and empirical insights from psychology and behavioural economics, this paper examines individuals’ cognitive and motivational barriers to adopting climate change adaptation and mitigation measures that increase consumer welfare. We explore various strategies that take into account the simplified decision-making processes used by individuals and resulting biases. We make these points by working through two examples: (1) investments in energy efficiency products and new technology and (2) adaptation measures to reduce property damage from future floods and hurricanes. In both cases there is a reluctance to undertake these measures due to high and certain upfront costs, delayed and probabilistic benefits, and behavioural biases related to this asymmetry. The use of choice architecture through framing and the use of default options coupled with short-term incentives and long-term contracts can encourage greater investment in these measures.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Some individuals prefer incandescent to CFL bulbs because they light up immediately and provide better lighting.

  2. In this regard, Borenstein (2012) emphasizes the need to develop cost estimates of the associated environmental and non-environmental externalities of existing technologies for generating electricity so that one can compare the use of coal and gas against renewable energy technologies—wind, solar, and biomass.

  3. Since W is irrelevant when a person is risk neutral, the expected discounted benefits from investing in flood-proofing when β = .10 is \( .01{\displaystyle \sum_{t=1}^T\left(40\kern-0em 000\right)/{(1.10)}^t} \) which exceeds $1200 when T > 3.

  4. Loss aversion should motivate more action than would be undertaken using formal models of choice such as discounted expected utility theory. Climate change is typically framed as the loss of climate conditions that are conducive to human habitation on planet earth or more concretely as the loss of features (e.g., glaciers or coral reefs) or species (e.g., polar bears) that are highly valued by many people. This insight is being used by organizations like the Natural Resources Defense Council and the World Wildlife Fund that attempt to trigger loss aversion in their solicitations for charitable donations with images of doomed species (e.g., https://www.nrdcgreengifts.org/den-defender?s_src=CKGG-NRDC-GG-A02-S.DD-GG-SE-SE-US-PLR-BO-ALL-Z00, http://www.arctichome.com/showLBE.do?id=arcticHome&type=pillar&size=3&exp=html&). However, the effect of loss aversion to motivate actions is often counteracted by other factors. For example, most people do not find the threat of such losses credible, given that it is based on scientific predictions that are abstract and temporally distant rather than being personal and imminent (Weber 2006).

  5. From a social welfare perspective it may be appropriate to make green energy the default option only if the estimated cost of carbon is sufficiently high. Borenstein (2012) calculated that residential solar would be cost competitive only on a social cost basis in the USA, if the cost of carbon dioxide emissions were greater than $316 per ton.

  6. Allcott points out that there is an unambiguous gain in consumer welfare from the OPOWER program if the treatments affect energy use by improving information or facilitating social learning about privately optimal levels of energy use. If on the other hand, the treatments affect only the moral utility of energy use (i.e., happy feeling when reducing energy use and contributing to a public good such as reduced GHG emissions, or guilt when increasing energy use), then it is not clear whether they are consumer-welfare enhancing.

  7. See Kunreuther et al. (2013b) for more details on the role that insurance can play to encourage investment in adaptation measures by utilizing formal models of choice while taking into account the features of intuitive thinking.

References

  • Allcott, H. (2011). Social norms and energy conservation. Journal of Public Economics, 95(9), 1082–1095.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borenstein, S. (2012). The private and public economics of renewable electricity generation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(1), 67–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bostrom, A., Morgan, M. G., Fischhoff, B., & Read, D. (1994). What do people know about global climate change? 1. Mental models. Risk Analysis, 14, 959–970.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B. C., & Metrick, A. (2003). Optimal defaults. Behavioral Economics, Public Policy, and Paternalism, 93, 180–185.

  • Creyts, J., Granade, H. C., & Ostrowski, K. J. (2010). U.S. energy savings: Opportunities and challenges. McKinsey Quarterly, January Issue.

  • Cullen, H. (2010). The weather of the future: heat waves, extreme storms, and other scenes from a climate-changed planet. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denholm, P., Margolis, R. M., Ong, S., & Roberts, B. (2009). Break-even cost for residential photovoltaics in the United States” Key drivers an sensitivities. National Renewable Energy Lab, Technical Report NREL/TP-6A2–46909.

  • Dietz, T., Stern, P. C., & Weber, E. U. (2013). Reducing carbon-based energy consumption through changes in household behavior. Daedalus, 142, 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinner, I., Johnson, E. J., Goldstein, D. G., & Liu, K. (2011). Partitioning default effects: Why people choose not to choose. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, 17(4), 332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drury, E., Jenkins, T., Jordan, D., & Margolis, R. (2013). Photovoltaic investment risk and uncertainty for residential customers. IEEE Journal of Photovoltaics.

  • Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351–401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gately, D. (1980). Individual discount rates and the purchase and utilization of energy-using durables: Comment. The Bell Journal of Economics, 11, 373–374.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, D. G., Johnson, E. J., Herrmann, A., & Heitman, M. (2008). Nudge your customer toward better choices. Harvard Business Review, 86(12), 99–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodnough, A. (2006). As hurricane season looms, state aim to scare. The New York Times, May 31.

  • Gromet, D. M., Kunreuther, H., & Larrick, R. P. (2013). Political identity affects energy efficiency attitudes and choices. PNAS, 110(23), 9314–9319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardisty, D. J., Johnson, E. J., & Weber, E. U. (2010). A dirty word or a dirty world? Attribute framing, political affiliation, and query theory. Psychological Science, 21(1), 86–92. doi:10.1177/0956797609355572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J. (1979). Individual discount rates and the purchase and utilization of energy-using durables. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 33–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertwig, R., Barron, G., Weber, E. U., & Erev, I. (2004). Decisions from experience and the effect of rare events in risky choice. Psychological Science, 15(8), 534–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirst, E., & Brown, M. (1990). Closing the efficiency gap: Barriers to the efficient use of energy. Resources, Conservation and Recycling, 3(4), 267–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B., & Stavins, R. N. (1994). The energy-efficiency gap. What does it mean? Energy Policy, 22(10), 804–810.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jakob, M. (2006). Marginal costs and co-benefits of energy efficiency investments: The case of the Swiss residential sector. Energy Policy, 34(2), 172–187.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E. J., & Goldstein, D. (2003). Do defaults save lives? Science, 302, 1338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E. J., Häubl, G., & Keinan, A. (2007). Aspects of endowment: A query theory of value construction. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 33(3), 461–474.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E. J., Hershey, J., Meszaros, J., & Kunreuther, H. (1993). Framing, probability distortions, and insurance decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 7(1), 35–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E. J., Shu, S. B., Dellaert, B. C. G., Fox, C., Goldstein, D. G., Häubl, G., et al. (2012). Beyond nudges: Tools of a choice architecture. Marketing Letters, 1–18.

  • Kahneman, D. (2003). A psychological perspective on economics. The American Economic Review, 93(2), 162–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kempton, W. (1991). Public understanding of global warming. Society & Natural Resources, 4(4), 331–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunreuther, H., Meyer, R. J., & Michel-Kerjan, E. (2013a). Overcoming decision biases to reduce losses from natural catastrophes. In E. Shafir (ed.), Behavioral foundations of policy, (pp. 398–416). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

  • Kunreuther, H., Pauly, M. V., & McMorrow, S. (2013b). Insurance and behavioral economics: improving decisions in the most misunderstood industry. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 443–478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leighty, W., & Meier, A. (2010). Short‐term Electricity Conservation in Juneau, Alaska: A Study of Household Activities. Proceedings of the 2010 Summer Study on Energy Efficiency in Buildings. Washington, DC: ACEEE, eec.ucdavis.edu/aceee/2010/data/papers/2131.pdf.

  • Loewenstein, G. F., Weber, E. U., Hsee, C. K., & Welch, N. (2001). Risk as feelings. Psychological Bulletin, 127(2), 267–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzoff, M. A., & Moore, M. K. (1999). Persons and representation: Why infant imitation is important for theories of human development. In J. Nadel & G. Butterworth (Eds.), Imitation in infancy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, E., Baker, J., Broad, K., Czajkowski, J. & Orlove, B. (2013). “The dynamics of hurricane risk perception: Real-Time Evidence from the 2012 Atlantic Hurricane Season”. Wharton Risk Center Working Paper #2013–07.

  • Mills, B.F., and Schleich, J. (2008). Why don’t households see the light? Explaining the diffusion of compact fluorescent lamps. Working paper sustainability and innovation, No, S1/2008, http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:de:0011-n-84564.

  • Michel-Kerjan, E., Lemoyne De Forges, S., & Kunreuther, H. (2012). Policy tenure under the U.S. National Flood Insurance Program (NFIP). Risk Analysis, 32(4), 644–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery, H. (1989). From cognition to action: The search for dominance in decision making. In H. Montgomery & O. Svenson (Eds.), Process and structure in human decision making (pp. 23–49). New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palm, R. (1995). Earthquake insurance: A longitudinal study of California homeowners. Westview Press.

  • Patt, A. & Weber, E. U. (2013). Perceiving and communicating climate change uncertainty. WIREs: Climate Change. Doi 10.1002/wcc.259.

  • Peters, E., & Slovic, P. (2000). The springs of action: Affective and analytical information processing in choice. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 26(12), 1465–1475.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. (2008). Green defaults: Information presentation and pro-environmental behaviour. Journal of Environmental Psychology, 28(1), 63–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds, T. W., Bostrom, A., Read, D., & Morgan, M. G. (2010). Now what do people know about global climate change? Survey studies of educated laypeople. Risk Analysis, 30(10), 1520–1538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1957). Models of man. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P. (1987). Perception of risk. Science, 236, 280–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P., Fischhoff, B., & Lichtenstein, S. (1978). Accident probabilities and seat belt usage: A psychological perspective. Accident Analysis & Prevention, 10, 281–285.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solomon, S., Plattner, G.-K., Knutti, R., & Friedlingstein, P. (2009). Irreversible climate change due to carbon dioxide emissions. Proceedings of the national academy of sciences, 106(6), 1704–1709.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence, A., Poortinga, W., Butler, C., & Pidgeon, N. F. (2011). Perceptions of climate change and willingness to save energy related to flood experience. Nature Climate Change, 1(1), 46–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sterman, J. D., & Sweeney, L. B. (2007). Understanding public complacency about climate change: adults’ mental models of climate change violate conservation of matter. Climatic Change, 80(3), 213–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. (1999). Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12, 183–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R., & Sunstein, C. (2008). Nudge: the gentle power of choice architecture. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: a reference-dependent model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1039–1061.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, E. U. (2006). Experience-based and description-based perceptions of long-term risk: Why global warming does not scare us (yet). Climatic Change, 77(1), 103–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, E., & Johnson, E. (2009). Mindful judgment and decision making. Annual Review of Psychology, 60, 53–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, E. U., & Lindemann, P. G. (2007). From intuition to analysis: Making decisions with our head, our heart, or by the book. In H. Plessner, C. Betsch, & T. Betsch (Eds.), Intuition in judgment and decision making (pp. 191–208). Mahwah: Lawrence Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, E. U., Johnson, E. J., Milch, K., Chang, H., Brodscholl, J., & Goldstein, D. (2007). Asymmetric discounting in intertemporal choice: A query theory account. Psychological Science, 18, 516–523.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, E. U., & Stern, P. (2011). The American public’s understanding of climate change. American Psychologist, 66, 315–328. doi:10.1037/a0023253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein, N. D., Kolb, K., & Goldstein, B. D. (1996). Using time intervals between expected events to communicate risk magnitudes. Risk Analysis, 16(3), 305–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Support for this research comes from the National Science Foundation (SES-1061882 and SES-1062039); the Center for Climate and Energy Decision Making through a cooperative agreement between the National Science Foundation and Carnegie Mellon University (SES-0949710); the Center for Risk and Economic Analysis of Terrorism Events (CREATE) at the University of Southern California; the Center for Research on Environmental Decisions (CRED; NSF Cooperative Agreement SES-0345840 to Columbia University), and the Wharton Risk Management and Decision Processes Center. We thank the referees for helpful comments and Carol Heller for editorial assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Elke U. Weber.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kunreuther, H., Weber, E.U. Aiding Decision Making to Reduce the Impacts of Climate Change. J Consum Policy 37, 397–411 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-013-9251-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-013-9251-z

Keywords

Navigation