Skip to main content
Log in

On the extraordinary scholarly life and times of Gordon Tullock

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Gordon Tullock, who passed away at the age of 92 on November 3, 2014, ranks justly near the top of the list of the “founding fathers” of the public choice research program. Most widely known in the academy as coauthor of The Calculus of Consent (Buchanan and Tullock 1962), Professor Tullock was not named, unfairly in our joint opinion, as co-recipient of James Buchanan’s 1986 Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences. A good case nevertheless can be made that Gordon earned Nobel laurels on his own account for groundbreaking contributions to the literatures on, among other topics of scholarly study, rent seeking, autocracy, bureaucracy, war and revolution, law and economics and bio-economics. This essay celebrates Gordon Tullock’s major influences on the field of public choice, including his launching of Public Choice, the journal for which both of us have served as editors, and his impacts on scholars working at the many and obviously fruitful intersections of economics and political science.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also the four remembrances of Gordon by, respectively, Clark and Lee (2015), Congleton (2015), Tideman (2015), and Yandle (2015), all published in March 2015 as volume 162, numbers 3–4, of Public Choice. In a private communication with the first-named author of this essay, David Theroux, founder and president of the Independent Institute, described Gordon as “kind and generous”. We share that assessment.

  2. A PDF version of Gordon’s c.v., current as of October 2000 (containing Gordon’s own summary of his career beginning with his appointment to the US Foreign Service) can be downloaded from the website of George Mason University Law School here: publicchoice.info/TullockTales/VitaGT.pdf.

  3. At the end of his postdoctoral fellowship at UVA, Gordon was appointed in fall 1959 to the tenure-track faculty of the University of South Carolina, where he remained until 1962. He returned to UVA as an associate professor that fall; the denial of Gordon’s promotion to full professor there apparently was partly spiteful—he apparently had alienated members of UVA’s political science department by berating them during luncheons at Charlottesville’s Colonnade Club.

  4. The University of Virginia thereby earned the dubious distinction of forcing out two members of its economics faculty who later became Nobel laureates, James Buchanan and Ronald Coase. A second mass movement of the Center to George Mason University in Fairfax, VA, took place circa 1983.

  5. To be precise, joint coeditors for the “rest of the world” (i.e., beyond Western Europe), which at the time and for all practical purposes comprised Canada and the United States. See Rowley (1991a) and Shughart (2014) for more details on the transition.

  6. Such disappointment persists even in an age of online processing of manuscripts from initial submission to final editorial decision. The main bottleneck in the system befalls authors and editors when at least one external referee agrees to review a paper, but then misses the deadline for sending in his or her report.

  7. He solicited the advice of other scholars only rarely, usually by walking down the hallway to ask the opinion as to a paper’s publishability of one of his colleagues in the Center for Study of Public Choice (Shughart 2014, p. 232).

  8. It is in recognition of Gordon Tullock’s penchant for fostering the careers of “bright young assistant professors” that Springer, the current publisher of Public Choice, now funds the honorarium for a prize awarded annually to the author(s) of the best paper published in the journal every year by a younger scholar or scholars, the winner having been selected by the editors of Public Choice and announced at the annual meeting of the Public Choice Society, convened at various locations traditionally in March.

  9. The editors of Public Choice thus choose their successors in the same way as the presidency of the Public Choice Society customarily changes hands. The sole exception to the Society’s norm transpired in 2006 when its rank-and-file members, at the suggestion of then-president Steven Brams, voted for the president who served the next two-year term. Voter turnout was abysmally low in that election (Brams et al. 2006). Given his familiarity with Anthony Downs’s (1957) model of instrumental voting, low voter turnout would not have been a surprise to Gordon Tullock, who was delighted to proclaim to students and colleagues that he never voted, perhaps with an eye on demonstrating his own economic rationality. (Graffiti in the men’s bathroom of the Center for Study of Public Choice on the George Mason University campus proclaims “Tullock votes!” The Society’s traditional practice was restored when its “democratically” elected president appointed his successor. Both institutions conceivably are reflected in Gordon’s longstanding scholarly interest in dictatorships and monarchies (see below).

  10. The field fathered by James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock therefore sometimes is referred to as Virginia Political Economy (VPE), to distinguish it from important offshoots at the “Rochester [New York] School”, most closely associated with the work of political scientist William Riker and his students, and at the “Bloomington [Indiana] School” connected with the workshop established there by the late Vincent and Elinor Ostrom, the last also a Nobel laureate in her own right.

  11. See on the latter theme, see Buchanan (1964) and Shughart and Thomas (2014).

  12. Although the public choice research program is by now fully integrated into the literatures of economics and political science (referred to customarily in the latter field as “rational choice” theories), Public Choice still receives a large volume of submissions from authors who fail to take the field’s assumptions and analytical methods to heart.

  13. A pure monopolist, by definition, is the only seller of a good or service having no close substitutes, as judged by prospective buyers. We are hard-pressed to think of an actual commercial enterprise, now or in the past, that fits the textbook definition. Neither Standard Oil of New Jersey, Microsoft Corp., nor Google, to name a few purported monopolists, ever controlled 100 % of any relevant antitrust market.

  14. Other examples include most of the salaries of college football coaches, superstar athletes and headline entertainers, who earn rents because their talents are scarce and their supplies cannot readily be increased or, given current biotechnologies, cloned.

  15. Rents likewise can arise in a perfectly competitive industry, but under constant cost conditions, only in the short run. Because of easy entry into and exit from such industries, rents (above-normal economic profits) or losses cannot persist in the long run. The crucial distinctions between profit-seeking and rent-seeking behavior, including their very different social welfare implications, are discussed in Buchanan (1980).

  16. Game-theoretic models of oligopolistic markets, models that have much in common with Tullock’s (1980a) analysis of rent seeking, also usually assume that the number of players (firms) is fixed ex ante. See Higgins et al. (1985) for an extension of the Tullock rent-seeking contest that allows players to enter until the available rent is fully dissipated (in potential entrants’ ex ante expectations) and for some further analysis of the exponent r in the equation below.

  17. The same 50 % chance of winning could also be “purchased” if each player bids $50, but such outlays are inefficient in the sense that it would be irrational to double one’s bid and still expect to win only half of the available rent.

  18. The extent of rent dissipation, D, in Tullock’s model is determined by \(D = \frac{Nx}{V} = \frac{N - 1}{N},\) where N > 1 is the number of contestants; x is player i’s bid and V is the value of the contested rent. Setting \(r = \infty\) leads to an “all-pay auction” (Hillman and Samet 1987; Hillman and Riley 1989) in which rents are fully dissipated (i.e., D = 1) whenever \(N \ge 2\).

  19. See, for example, Tollison (1982), Congleton et al. (2008), Hillman (2013), Shughart and Thomas (2015) and Congleton and Hillman (2015) for summaries of the relevant theoretical and empirical literatures.

  20. Because medallions represent transferrable property rights with very long useful lives, they have much in common with perpetuities, a type of bond (a “consol”) having no term to maturity. Let A be the annual payment (coupon) received by the bondholder and i the market rate of interest; the bond’s present market value at any point in time is \(P = \frac{A}{i}\). If A is thought of as the taxicab operator’s annual rent, that stream of rents is fully capitalized in the medallion’s market price.

  21. The academic database JSTOR lists 61,125 search results for “rent seeking”; EconLit counts 662 occurrences of “rent seeking” in the titles and texts of scholarly books and articles since 1969.

  22. Buchanan’s Appendix 1 is titled “Marginal Notes on Political Philosophy” (Buchanan and Tullock 1962, pp. 307–322).

  23. Journal editors nowadays can only dream about such short turnaround times! On logrolling, see also Tullock (1970).

  24. The 2005 Liberty Fund volume combines selections from The Social Dilemma and Tullock’s equally insightful Autocracy (Tullock [1987] 2005), published originally by Martinus Nijhoff/Kluwer Academic Publishers and summarized further below.

  25. Republished in 2005 as vol. 6 of Rowley (2004–2010).

  26. Niskanen had resigned from Ford as a result of a dispute with top company managers following his principled refusal to support governmental imposition of import restrictions on foreign automobile manufacturers.

  27. Bureaucratic failures can—and often do—lead to pleas for bigger budgets. On the other hand, as Morris Fiorina (1977) observes, bureaucratic sluggishness, the “red tape” associated with formal, one-size-fits-all rules and procedures, and outright ineptitude supply the Members of Congress with a convenient scapegoat when their constituents complain.

  28. It was for that reason that the post of customs collector for the Port of New York was for many years a much sought-after plum. Likely as a result of his earlier experiences in that position, including removal from the job by President Rutherford B. Hayes, President Chester A. Arthur became a staunch advocate of civil service reform, ultimately signing the Pendleton Act in 1883, which required appointments to federal jobs to be based on merit. Source: http://www.history.com/topics/chester-a-arthur; last accessed May 9, 2015.

  29. See Wilson (1989) for a political scientist’s modern analysis of bureaucracy, inspired in part by the contributions of Tullock and other public choice scholars who followed his lead.

  30. For simplicity’s sake, we use the term “autocrat” to refer to any head of government not elected to that post by popular vote. Constitutional monarchies exercising mainly ceremonial functions, such as England’s Queen Elizabeth II and the future successors to her throne, obviously represent exceptions to our terminology. It is worth noting in that regard that some members of the Scottish National Party want to call England’s current queen “Elizabeth I”, since the original Queen Elizabeth ruled prior to the union of England, Wales and Scotland in 1707.

  31. Such ideas call to mind Hayek (1944, pp. 134–152), in a chapter of The Road to Serfdom titled “Why the Worst Get on Top”. See Coats et al. (2015) for application of the same framework to explain why corrupt politicians tend rise to the top in democratic polities.

  32. Selections from both volumes are reproduced in Tullock (2005). Also see Tullock (1997).

  33. The term “peers” refers to lords and other nobles of the British realm, whose guilt or innocence was thought to be beyond the ken of mere commoners. See Allen (2012).

  34. Tullock (1994) summarizes most of that line of research, but also see Tullock (1971c). Tullock’s many writings in the area of bioeconomics are reprinted in vol. 9 of Rowley (2004–2010), under the title Economics without Borders.

References

  • Allen, D. W. (2012). The institutional revolution: Measurement and the economic emergence of the modern world. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. ([1951] 1963). Social choice and individual values (2nd ed.). New Haven: Yale University Press.

  • Becker, G. S. (1974). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brady, G., & Tollison, R. D. (1991). Gordon Tullock: Creative maverick of public choice. Public Choice, 71(3), 141–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams, S. J., Hansen, M. W., & Orrison, M. E. (2006). Dead heat: The 2006 Public Choice Society election. Public Choice, 128(3–4), 361–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1964). What should economists do? Southern Economic Journal, 30, 213–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1980). Rent seeking and profit seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 3–15). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1987). The qualities of a natural economist. In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), Democracy and public choice: Essays in honor of Gordon Tullock (pp. 9–19). Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1968). The “dead hand” of monopoly. Antitrust Law and Economic Review, 1, 85–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, J. R., & Lee, D. R. (2015). In remembrance of Gordon Tullock. Public Choice, 162(3–4), 225–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. N. (1959). The Federal Communications Commission (1957). Journal of Law and Economics, 2, 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coats, R. M., Karahan, G., & Shughart, W. F. II (2015). Why the worst get on top: Corruption in democracies. Unpublished working paper, Utah State University.

  • Congleton, R. D. (2015). Thanks to Gordon Tullock. Public Choice, 162(3–4), 229–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D., & Hillman, A. L. (Eds.). (2015). Companion to the political economy of rent seeking (pp. 167–186). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D., Hillman, A. L., & Konrad, K. A. (Eds.). (2008). Forty years of research on rent seeking, 2 vols. Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1967). Inside bureaucracy. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faith, R. L., Leavens, D. L., & Tollison, R. D. (1982). Antitrust pork barrel. Journal of Law and Economics, 25, 329–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. P. (1977). Congress: Keystone of the Washington establishment. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1996). The winner-take-all society: Why the few at the top get so much more than the rest of us. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harberger, A. C. (1954). Monopoly and resource allocation. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 44, 77–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1944). The road to serfdom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Higgins, R. S., Shughart, W. F, I. I., & Tollison, R. D. (1985). Free entry and efficient rent seeking. Public Choice, 46, 247–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L. (2013). Rent seeking. In M. Reksulak, L. Razzolini, & W. F. Shughart II (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (2nd ed., pp. 307–330). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L., & Riley, J. G. (1989). Politically contestable rents and transfers. Economics and Politics, 1, 17–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L., & Samet, D. (1987). Dissipation of contestable rents by small numbers of players. Public Choice, 54, 63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (2001). The dark side of the force: Economic foundations of conflict theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64, 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J. T. (1986). The political economy of swarming in honeybees: Voting-with-the wings, decision-making costs, and the unanimity rule. Public Choice, 51, 25–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J. T. (2013). The bioeconomics of scout bees voting-with-the-wings using less-than-unanimity voting rule: Can bees count, quorum sense, etc. In D. R. Lee (Ed.), Public choice, past and present: The legacy of James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock (pp. 89–99). New York: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J. T., & Tullock, G. (2003). Why ants do but honeybees do not construct satellite nests. Journal of Bionomics, 5, 151–164.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. D., & Schwartz, T. (1984). Congressional oversight overlooked: Police patrols versus fire alarms. American Journal of Political Science, 28, 165–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie, R. B., & Tullock, G. (2012). The new world of economics: A remake of a classic for new generations of economics students. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mundell, R. A. (1962). Review of Jansenn’s free trade, protection, and customs union. American Economic Review, 52(3), 621–622.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1968). Non-market decision making: The peculiar economics of bureaucracy. American Economic Review, 58(2), 293–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1975). Bureaucrats and politicians. Journal of Law and Economics, 18, 617–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (2001). Bureaucracy. In W. F. Shughart II & L. Razzolini (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 258–270). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1975). The social costs of monopoly and regulation. Journal of Political Economy, 83, 807–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C. K. (1991a). A changing of the guard. Public Choice, 71(3), 201–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C. K. (1991b). Gordon Tullock: Entrepreneur of public choice. Public Choice, 71(3), 149–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C. K. (ed.). (2004–2010). The selected works of Gordon Tullock (10 vols.). Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.

  • Rowley, C. K., & Houser, D. (2012). The life and times of Gordon Tullock. Public Choice, 152, 3–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F, I. I. (1999). The reformer’s dilemma. Public Finance Review, 27, 561–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F, I. I. (2014). Supplying private goods and collective goods at Public Choice. In M. Szenberg & L. Ramrattan (Eds.), Secrets of economics editors (pp. 231–248). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F, I. I., & Thomas, D. W. (2014). What did economists do? Euvoluntary, voluntary, and coercive institutions for collective action. Southern Economic Journal, 80(4), 926–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F, I. I., & Thomas, D. W. (2015). Regulatory rent seeking. In R. D. Congleton & A. L. Hillman (Eds.), Companion to the political economy of rent seeking (pp. 167–186). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, R. T. (2011). Beyond politics: The roots of government failure, rev. and updated ed. Oakland, CA: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tideman, T. N. (2015). Remembering Gordon Tullock. Public Choice, 162(3–4), 235–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tideman, T. N., & Tullock, G. (1976). A new and superior process for making social choices. Journal of Political Economy, 84, 1145–1159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R. D. (1982). Rent seeking: A survey. Kyklos, 35(4), 575–602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R. D. (1995). Gordon Tullock’s contributions to the theory of public choice. Economic Inquiry, 33, 335–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1956). Paper money: A cycle in Cathy. Economic History Review, 9(May), 393–407.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1959). Some problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy, 67, 571–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1964). The social rate of discount and the optimal rate of investment: Comment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 78(May), 331–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1965). The politics of bureaucracy. Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1966). The organization of inquiry. New York: Lanham.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967a). The general irrelevance of the general impossibility theorem. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 81(June), 256–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967b). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5, 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1969). An economic approach to crime. Social Science Quarterly, 50(June), 59–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1970). A simple algebraic logrolling model. American Economic Review, 60(3), 419–426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971a). Public decisions or public goods. Journal of Political Economy, 79(July/August), 913–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971b). The charity of the uncharitable. Western Economic Journal, 9, 379–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971c). The coal tit as a careful shopper. American Naturalist, 105, 77–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1975). The transitional gains trap. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 6(2), 671–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980a). Efficient rent seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980b). Trials on trial: The pure theory of legal procedure. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1983). Economics of income distribution. Hingham, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1984). How to do well by doing good. In D. C. Collander (Ed.), Neoclassical political economy (pp. 229–239). Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1987). The logic of the law. Fairfax, VA: George Mason University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1991). Recollections of an editor. Public Choice, 71(3), 129–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1994). The economics of non-human societies. Tucson, AZ: Pallus Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1997). The case against the common law. In A. J. Owens & C. K. Rowley (Eds.), The blackstone commentaries (Vol. 1). Fairfax, VA: The Locke Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2001). Monarchies, hereditary and nonhereditary. In W. F. Shughart II & L. Razzolini (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 140–156). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2005). Law and economics. In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (Vol. 9). Liberty Fund: Indianapolis, IN.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. ([1965] 2005). Bureaucracy. In Rowley, C. K. (ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (vol. 6). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Tullock, G. ([1974] 2005). The social dilemma: The economics of war and revolution. In Rowley, C. K. (ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (vol. 7). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Tullock, G. ([1987] 2005). Autocracy. In Rowley, C. K. (ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (vol. 7). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. ([1944] 1953). The theory of games and economic behavior (3rd ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

  • Weber, M. ([1922] 1978). Economy and society (2 vols.). Berkeley: University of California Press.

  • Weingast, B. R., & Moran, M. J. (1983). Bureaucratic discretion or congressional control? Regulatory policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 765–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, W. (1887). The study of administration. Political Science Quarterly, 2(2), 197–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. Q. (1989). Bureaucracy: What government agencies do and why they do it. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Yandle, B. (2015). Gordon Tullock: Gone but surely not forgotten. Public Choice, 162(3–4), 239–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Presented at a conference on “The Scholarship and Impact of Gordon Tullock”, George Mason University, Arlington, Virginia, 2–3 October 2015. We benefitted from comments on an earlier draft by Roger Congleton (conference organizer), Charles Goetz and Dwight Lee, as well as those of conference participants, especially Arye Hillman, Nic Tideman and Stefan Voigt, all of whom might serve as convenient scapegoats, but nevertheless are excused of responsibility for any errors remaining herein.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to William F. Shughart II.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Shughart, W.F., Tollison, R.D. On the extraordinary scholarly life and times of Gordon Tullock. Const Polit Econ 27, 227–247 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-016-9208-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-016-9208-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation