Advertisement

Constitutional Political Economy

, Volume 19, Issue 4, pp 313–355 | Cite as

The origins and evolution of democracy: an exercise in history from a constitutional economics approach

  • Sebastian Coll
Original Paper

Abstract

In this article the conditions for the rise and fall of representative regimes are explored. High citizen mobility and unexploited opportunities for investment create the need of reassuring factor owners against the tax hunger of the State. This may lead to the emergence of representative institutions of government, a process that reverts when those conditions disappear. Factors that facilitate or restrain the mobility of citizenry are identified, mainly in the domain of military technology. Thus, a number of interrelations between production and war technologies, political development and economic performance are revealed, giving rise to an interpretation of historical evolution.

Keywords

Historical origins of parliaments and democracy Evolution of political institutions Historical evolution 

JEL Classification

N40 H20 H21 H30 

References

  1. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  2. Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, LXII, 777–795.Google Scholar
  3. Ali, A. M., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Political regimes, economic freedom, institutions and growth. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice (PFPC)/Economia delle scelte pubbliche, XIX, 3–21.Google Scholar
  4. Ali, A. M., & Crain, W. M. (2002). Institutional distortions, economic freedom, and growth. Cato Journal, 21, 415–426.Google Scholar
  5. Altheim, F. (1952). Niedergang der Alten Welt. Eine Untersuchung der Ursachen. Frankfurt.Google Scholar
  6. Baechler, J., Hall, J. A., & Mann, M. (Eds.). (1989). Europe and the rise of capitalism. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  7. Bates, R. H. (1987). The centralization of African societies. In Essays on the political economy of rural Africa (pp. 21–57). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  8. Beard, C. A. (1965 [1913]). An economic interpretation of the Constitution of the United States. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  9. Bernholz, P., & Vaubel, R. (Eds.). (2004). Political competition, innovation and growth in the history of Asian civilizations. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  10. Birdsell, J. B. (1973). A basic demographic unit. Current Anthropology, XIV, 337–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Blum, U., & Dudley, L. H. (1989). A structural approach to structural change: The making of the French hexagon. Journal of Economic History, XLIX, 657–675.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Carneiro, R. (1970). A theory of the origin of the state. Science, 169, 733–738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Childe, V. G. (1936). Man makes itself. New York: New American Library, Mentor Books.Google Scholar
  15. Choi, K. (1983). A statistical test of Olson’s model. In Mueller (Ed.), pp. 57–78.Google Scholar
  16. Claessen, H. J. M., & Skalnik, P. (Eds.). (1978). The early state. The Hague: Mouton.Google Scholar
  17. Coates, D., & Heckelman, J. C. (2003a). Absolute and relative effects of interest groups on the economy. In Coates & Heckelman (Eds.), Collective choice: Essays in honour of Mancur Olson. Berlin: Springer Verlag.Google Scholar
  18. Coates, D., & Heckelman, J. C. (2003b). Interest groups and investment: A further test of Olson hypothesis. Public Choice, 117, 333–340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Dawson, J. W. (2006). Regulation, investment, and growth across countries. Cato Journal, 26, 489–509.Google Scholar
  20. De la Fuente, A. (1997). Fiscal policy and growth in the OECD. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Discussion Paper no. 1775.Google Scholar
  21. Domar, E. (1970). The causes of slavery and serfdom: A hypothesis. Journal of Economic History, XXX, 18–32.Google Scholar
  22. Doucouliagos, C., & Ulubasoglu, M. A. (2006). Economic freedom and economic growth: Does specification make a difference? European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 60–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  24. Drake, P. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1998a). The origins of liberty. In Drake & McCubbins (Eds.), pp. 3–12.Google Scholar
  25. Drake, P. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (Eds.). (1998b). The origins of liberty: Political and economic liberalization in the modern world. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  26. Dudley, L. H. (1990). Structural change and interdependent bureaucracies: Was Rome’s failure economic or military? Explorations in Economic History, 27, 232–248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Dudley, L. H. (1991). The word and the sword. How techniques of information and violence have shaped our world. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  28. Dudley, L. H. (1997). Communications and economic growth. European Economic Review, 43, 595–619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Farr, W. K., Lord, R. A., & Wolfenbarger, J. L. (1998). Economic freedom, political freedom, and economic wellbeing: A causality analysis. Cato Journal, 18, 247–262.Google Scholar
  30. Fleck, R. K., & Hanssen, F. A. (2002). The origins of democracy: A model with application to ancient Greece. Unpublished paper. Abstract available at www2.montana.edu/ahansen/Papers/papers.htm.
  31. Fölster, S., & Henrekson, M. (1999). Growth and the public sector: A critique of the critics. European Journal of Political Economy, 15, 337–358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Friedman, D. (1977). A theory of the size and shape of nations. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 59–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Greif, A., Milgrom, P., & Weingast, B. (1994). Coordination, commitment and enforcement. The case of the merchant guild. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 745–777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Gwartney, J. D., Holcombe, R. G., & Lawson, R. A. (2004). Economic freedom, institutional quality, and cross-country differences in income and growth. Cato Journal, 24, 205–233.Google Scholar
  35. Heckelman, J. C. (2000). Consistent estimates of the impact of special interest groups on economic growth. Public Choice, 104, 319–327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Heller, W. B., Keefer, P., & McCubbins, M. D. (1998). Political structure and economic liberalization. Conditions and cases from the developing world. In Drake & McCubbins (Eds.), pp. 146–178.Google Scholar
  37. Hickson, C. R., & Thompson, E. E. (1991). A new theory of guilds and european economic development. Explorations in Economic History, 28, 127–168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Holcombe, R. G. (2002). From liberty to democracy: The transformation of American government. Ann Arbor, MI: Michigan University Press.Google Scholar
  39. Hylland, A., & Zeckhauser, R. (1979). A mechanism for selecting public goods when preferences must be elicited. Harvard University. John Fitzgerald Kennedy School of Government. Discussion Paper No. 70D.Google Scholar
  40. Jones, E. L. (1988). The European miracle: Environment, economies and geopolitics in the history of Europe and Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  41. Knack, S. (2003). Groups, growth and trust: Cross-country evidence on the Olson and Putnam hypotheses. Public Choice, 117, 341–335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 473–491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1980). Dynamic optimal taxation, rational expectations and optimal control. Journal of Economic Dynamic and Control, 2, 79–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Latzko, D. A. (1993). The concept of military economies of scale. Explorations in Economic History, 30, 470–484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. McGuire, R. A. (2003). To form a more perfect union: A new economic interpretation of the United States constitution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  46. McGuire, R. A., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule. The invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, XXXIV, 72–96.Google Scholar
  47. McNeill, W. H. (1963). The rise of the west: A history of the human community. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  48. McNeill, W. H. (1976). Plagues and peoples. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  49. Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–927.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1983). Test of a rational theory of the size of government. Public Choice, 41, 403–418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Mueller, D. C. (Ed.). (1983). The political economy of growth. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  52. Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Niskanen, W. A. (2003). Autocratic, democratic, and optimal government: Fiscal choice and economic outcomes. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  54. North, D. C. (1966). Growth and welfare in the American past. A new economic history. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
  55. North, D. C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
  56. North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of the western world. A new economic history (900–1700). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  57. North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, XLIX, 803–832. Also reprinted in Drake & McCubbins (Eds.) (1998), pp. 16–47.Google Scholar
  58. Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  59. Olson, M. (1983). The political economy of comparative growth rates. In Mueller (Ed.), pp. 7–52.Google Scholar
  60. Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Oppenheimer, F. (1926). The state: Its history and development viewed sociologically. New York: Vanguard Press.Google Scholar
  62. Plümper, T., & Martin, C. W. (2003). Democracy, government spending, and economic growth: A political-economic explanation of the Barro-effect. Public Choice, 117, 27–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1993). Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 51–70.Google Scholar
  64. Reid, J. D. (1978). Economic burden: Spark to the American revolution? Journal of Economic History, XXXVIII, 81–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Rogowski, R. (1998). Democracy, capital, skill, and country size. Effects of asset mobility and regime monopoly on the odds of democratic rule. In Drake & McCubbins (Eds.), pp. 48–69.Google Scholar
  66. Sánchez Molinero, J. M. (2000). The origins of the state: From reciprocity to coercive power. Constitutional Political Economy, 11, 231–253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Service, E. (1975). Origins of the state and civilization. The process of cultural evolution. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
  68. Schofield, R. (2004). Taxation under the early Tudors, 1485–1547. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  69. Sirowy, L., & Inkeles, A. (1990). The effects of democracy on economic growth and inequality: A review. Studies in Comparative International Development, 25, 126–157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Spencer, H. (1967). The evolution of society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  71. Tang, E. W. Y., & Hedley, R. A. (1998). Distributional coalitions, state strength, and economic growth: Toward a comprehensive theory of economic development. Public Choice, 96, 295–323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Tavares, J., & Wacziarg, T. (2001). How democracy affects growth. European Economic Review, 45, 1341–1378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Thiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 418–424.Google Scholar
  74. Tideman, T. N. (1997). Voting and the revelation of preferences for public activities. In D. C. Mueller (Ed.), Perspectives on public choice. A handbook (pp. 226–244). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  75. Tideman, T. N., & Tullock, G. (1976). A new and superior process for making social choices. Journal of Political Economy, 84, 1145–1159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Tsasavage, D. (2003). Public debt and the birth of the democratic state: France and Great Britain, 1688–1789. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  77. Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma. The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg, VA: Center for the Study of Public Choice.Google Scholar
  78. Tullock, G. (1987a). Autocracy. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  79. Tullock, G. (1987b). Autocracia. Revista del Instituto de Estudios Económicos, (2), 27–45.Google Scholar
  80. Tullock, G. (1989). The economics of the special privilege and rent seeking. Boston: Kluwer Economic Publishers.Google Scholar
  81. Weede, E. (2006). Economic freedom and development: New calculations and interpretations. Cato Journal, 26, 511–524.Google Scholar
  82. Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: An economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84, 849–872.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  84. Wittfogel, K. A. (1957). Oriental despotism. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  85. Wu, W., & Davis, O. A. (1999). The two freedoms, economic growth and development: An empirical study. Public Choice, 100, 39–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science + Business Media, LLC 2008

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of CantabriaSantanderSpain

Personalised recommendations