Skip to main content

The effect of real-time fiscal policy on sovereign interest rates in OECD countries

Abstract

The aim of this study is to investigate the effect of real-time projections of fiscal policy stances on government bonds long-term interest rates using a panel of 20 OECD countries between 1992 and 2008. To deal with endogeneity arising from forecasts of fiscal balances the paper exploits instrumental variables and GMM estimators together with the variation in real-time primary balances. The study shows how a static specification that does not include the one-period lag of the interest rate is prone to serial correlation and to downward bias in standard errors. To correct the bias, a dynamic specification with the lagged interest rates used as explanatory variable should be used due to the intrinsic persistent behavior of the interest rates. Results show that when the persistency of the interest rates is taken into account, it corrects the bias in standard errors of the estimates, and the correlation between fiscal policy variables and sovereign rates disappears: the inertia of the behavior of interest rates is the only variable affecting the relation.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Notes

  1. For the U.S. the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) provide such long-term independent projections (up to ten year ahead). For other countries the situation is more demanding since no long-term projections exist, hence researchers have adopted near-term projections (up to two year ahead) of the OECD, and, in the case of European countries the near-term projections of the European Commission Note that the data availability is one of the main obstacles in attempting comparisons of empirical results between U.S. and other countries.

  2. For a VAR detailed survey, see Gale and Orszag (2003; 2004).

  3. All Ardagna et al. (2007) data are revised and are from the OECD Economic Outlook n.73 2003.

  4. However, the choice of including the mid-year June edition of forecasts is susceptible to criticism. Indeed government future budgetary plans are discussed after June, usually in September-October, and therefore OECD forecasts of fiscal stances for the following year will be most presumably recalculated and updated in the December’s edition, once the new fiscal policy framework is approved.

  5. Indeed, the change in the long-term interest rate as the dependent variable is simply a stricter restriction (the coefficient of the lagged long-term interest rates is assumed to be 1) on the estimation equation than the inclusion of the lagged long-term interest rate among regressors where the long-term interest rates is allowed to enter with a coefficient different from 1.

  6. The countries are: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Germany, Denmark, Spain, Finland, France, Great Britain, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Norway, Netherland, New Zeeland, Portugal, Sweden and U.S.

  7. The analysis adopts the GDP deflator as a proxy for inflation. The reason is that long-time series (from the 1992) of the projections of inflation are not available in the OECD December Economic Outlooks.

  8. The short term interest rates as explanatory variable could lead to underestimate the impact of government expenditure on long-term interest rate mainly due to the feedback effect that fiscal policy could have on short-term interest rates through the monetary policy reaction function (Canzoneri et al. 2002. However, when fiscal variables are regressed on short-term interest rate no significant effect at 10 % confidence level is found suggesting little evidence of fiscal policy effect on short term rates.

  9. In a variant of the baseline static regression also primary balances are used as regressors to the end to estimate the autonomous effect of government fiscal balances.

  10. This result is in line with the empirical evidence on OECD countries (Ardagna et al. 2007; Reinhart and Sack 2000).

  11. The latter could be interpreted as a symptom of a-cyclical monetary policy notwithstanding the fact that the dependent variable is the long-term interest rate and not the short-term rate.

  12. For instance, Ziliak (1997) and Wooldrige (2001) demonstrated that the adoption of Anderson-Hsiao (AH) and Arellano-Bond (AB) estimators within a macro dataset could strongly bias the results.

  13. A similar conclusion was pushed forward also by Barth et al. (1991) which emphasized that most of the empirical literature on fiscal policy effects on long-term interest rates becomes futile if the lagged dependent variable is introduced in reduced form regressions.

  14. A note of caution is however necessary. The twice lagged dependent variable can be used as instrument for ∆IRL i,t-1 only if the error term does not have a serial correlation of second order. When there is a second order serial correlation the twice lagged dependent variable will be still correlated with the error term and therefore the estimates will be biased. As such, in the case of second order serial correlation within the difference equation, the third lag of the dependent variable becomes the first valid instrument.

References

  • Afonso A (2009) “Long-term government bond yields and economic forecasts: evidence for the EU”, applied economic letters

  • Anderson TW, Hsiao C (1981) Estimation of dynamic models with error components. J Am Stat Assoc 76:589–606

  • Ardagna S, Francesco C, Lane T (2007) “Fiscal discipline and the cost of public debt service: some estimates from OECD countries.” The B.E. J Macroecon 7: (1) article 28.

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi BH (2005) “Econometric analysis of panel data”, John Wiley and Sons, 3rd Edition

  • Barro RJ (1974) Are government bonds net worth?”. J Polit Econ 82(6):1095–1117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R, Sala-i-Martin X (1990) World real interest rates. NBER Macroeconomic Annuals, NBER, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barth JR, Iden G, Russek FS, Wohar M (1991) The Effects of Federal Budget Deficits on Interest Rates and the Composition of Domestic Output. In: Penner RG (ed) The great fiscal experiment. Urban Institute Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim BD (1989) A neoclassical perspective on budget deficits. J Econ Perspect 3(No. 2):55–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canzoneri MB, Cumby RE, Diba B (2002) “Should the European central bank and the federal reserve be concerned about fiscal policy?” In, re- thinking stabilization policy; Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

  • Elmendorf DW, Mankiw NG (1999) “Government Debt.” Chapter 25 in John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science 1999

  • Engen EM, Hubbard RG (2004) Federal government debt and interest rates. NBER Macroecon Annu 2004:83–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans P (1987) Interest rates and expected future budget deficits in the United States. J Polit Econ 95(1987):34–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faini R (2006) Fiscal policy and interest rates in Europe. Econ Policy 21(2006):443–489

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein MS (1986) “Budget deficits, tax rules, and real interest rates.” NBER Working Paper No. 1970, July 1986

  • Feldstein MS, Horioka C (1980) Domestic savings and international capital flows. Econ J 90(1980):314–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gale WG, Orszag PR (2003) “The economic effects of long-term fiscal discipline.” tax policy center, urban institute and Brookings institution, December 2002

  • Gale WG, Orszag PR (2004) Budget deficits, national saving and interest rates. Papers on Economic Activity, Brooking

    Google Scholar 

  • Green WH (2009) “Econometric analysis”, Pearson international, 6th Edition

  • Judson RA, Owen AL (1999) Estimating dynamic panel data models: a guide for macroeconomists. Econ Lett 65:9–15

  • Keynes JM (1936) “The general theory”, London, New York

  • Kiviet JF (1995) On bias, inconsistency, and efficiency of various estimators in dynamic panel data models”. J Econ 68:53–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laubach T (2009) “New evidence on the interest rate effects of budget deficits and debt”, J Eur Econ Assoc

  • Obstfeld M, Taylor A (2004) “Global capital markets: integration, crisis and growth”, Cambridge University Press

  • Reinhart V, Sack B (2000) “The economic consequences of disappearing government debt”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2

  • Seater J (1993) Ricardian equivalence. J Econ Lit 31(Issue 1):142–190

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldrige JM (2001) Application of generalized method of moment estimation. J Econ Perspect 15(4):87–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziliak JP (1997) Efficient estimation with panel data when instruments are predetermined: an empirical comparison of moment-condition estimators. J Bus Econ Stat 15:419–431

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Prof. Massimo Giuliodori for his intellectual support and insight during the preparation of this paper, the participants at the INFER conference of the University of Coimbra and the anonymous referees therein, Mara Pirovano and one anonymous referee for their constructive comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ernest Dautovic.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Dautovic, E. The effect of real-time fiscal policy on sovereign interest rates in OECD countries. Int Econ Econ Policy 14, 167–185 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-015-0334-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-015-0334-y

Keywords

  • Real-time fiscal policy
  • Primary fiscal balance
  • Government debt
  • Long-term interest rate
  • OECD projections
  • Dynamic panel data

JEL Classification

  • C2
  • E6
  • H6
  • G1